The Sources and Sustainability of China's Economic Growth

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Sources and Sustainability of China's Economic Growth 10269-01_Jefferson-rev.qxd 1/29/07 10:56 AM Page 1 GARY H. JEFFERSON Brandeis University ALBERT G. Z. HU National University of Singapore JIAN SU Peking University The Sources and Sustainability of China’s Economic Growth IN 1978, AT THE outset of its economic reform, China was the world’s tenth- largest economy, with a GDP of about $150 billion, or less than 6 percent of U.S. GDP at the time. By 2005, however, China’s economy, at $2.2 trillion, had grown to become the fourth largest in the world, behind only the United States at $12.5 trillion, Japan at $4.5 trillion, and Germany at $2.8 trillion. The above figures, which come from the World Bank, evaluate GDP at current exchange rates and do not take account of differences in the pur- chasing power of currencies. When measured instead at purchasing power parity (PPP), China is already the world’s second-largest economy, with almost $9 trillion in output, nearly three quarters that of the United States. It has been suggested that, at current growth rates, China’s GDP stated in PPP terms could exceed that of the United States as early as 2010.1 When China’s GDP converted at current exchange rates does match that of the United States, assuming that China’s population remains four times the U.S. population, Chinese income per capita will then be but one quar- ter that of the United States. By comparison, the purchasing power of the average Chinese resident will substantially exceed one quarter that of the average U.S. resident, perhaps rising to the vicinity of one half. The authors appreciate their research collaboration with China’s National Bureau of Statis- tics and specifically with its staff members Liu Yaodong and Qian Jinchang, who helped with data formatting and offered guidance on aspects of the research presented in this paper. We also appreciate the excellent research assistance of Sun Xiaole and Zhao Yan, doctoral candidates at the International Business School at Brandeis University. We acknowledge the support pro- vided by the National Science Foundation (award no. SES-0519902) that helped support the research assistance provided to this project. Finally, comments provided by Barry Bosworth and Gustav Ranis during the panel session were most helpful for revising the paper. 1. See, for example, Holz (2006, p. 41). 1 10269-01_Jefferson-rev.qxd 1/29/07 10:56 AM Page 2 2 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2:2006 What changes will have to occur within China’s productive sectors for China’s GDP to match and ultimately surpass that of the United States? Today even China’s coastal industry, the country’s most techno- logically advanced region and sector, lags substantially behind the world technology frontier. Meanwhile a well-known feature of China’s rapid economic transformation is the unequal advance, in terms of technolog- ical change and productivity, of different regions and sectors across this large and populous country. The regions and sectors that lag behind China’s coastal industry also exhibit large disparities in productivity among themselves. These large international and internal productivity gaps represent both advantages and disadvantages for China’s ability to sustain high rates of GDP growth. The key advantage is that both the international gap and the internal gaps continue to provide multiple channels through which catch-up can proceed. A well-known disadvantage of the internal gaps is that the accompanying large differences in income threaten social stabil- ity. A further disadvantage of large internal productivity differences, to the extent they prove persistent, is that much of the burden of China’s catch-up with the United States will fall on coastal industry. That is, if productivi- ties in the regions and sectors outside China’s coastal industry remain far below one quarter that of the United States, then coastal industry will have to achieve productivity levels well above one quarter that of the United States. Coastal industry will have to continue as the locomotive pulling the rest of the economy forward. Indeed, if China is to meet its ambitious goal of output parity with the United States, productivity in coastal indus- try may have to closely approach or even exceed U.S. productivity. Yet the history of other successful developing countries suggests that, as it does so, China’s productivity growth is likely to slow substantially, in turn slowing the country’s overall economic growth. A number of questions emerge from this overview and frame the analy- sis in this paper: Within China, how much does China’s coastal industry lag behind the global frontier? How much do China’s other regions and sectors lag behind coastal industry? Is there evidence of catch-up or con- vergence of these regions and sectors with coastal industry? If so, what are the sources of such change? If instead there are growing disparities, what are the causes? To what extent can one expect that, as China’s coastal industry closes in on the global technology frontier, the productivity growth of China’s own technology frontier will slow? 10269-01_Jefferson-rev.qxd 1/29/07 10:56 AM Page 3 Gary H. Jefferson, Albert G. Z. Hu, and Jian Su 3 We investigate these questions using panels of industry and firm- level data. However, any research agenda that seeks to assess a country’s medium- to long-term economic growth prospects has to take into account that country’s capacity for institutional adaptation, since institutions shape the incentives and prospects for such growth. This is particularly true for China, which remains engaged in two transitions simultaneously: from a centrally planned to a market economy, and from a less to a more devel- oped country. Therefore we also speculate as to what institutional reforms will most directly bear on China’s ability to close its international and internal productivity gaps. These reforms depend on the ability of China’s political system to formulate and enforce the rules that reassign and clar- ify the property rights needed to sustain investment in technology devel- opment and to facilitate the flow of resources to the regions and sectors offering high returns. During the past quarter century of reform, and largely to the surprise of most observers, China’s economic performance has demonstrated con- siderable resilience. In addition to successfully weathering the Asian financial crises of the late 1990s, China has substantially restructured its state enterprise sector and opened itself to the international economy, including by having adopted World Trade Organization (WTO) rules. For two decades now China has sustained an annual average rate of growth of GDP about 6 percentage points higher than that of the United States (about 9 percent versus 3 percent). If China can sustain that growth advantage into the future, then, assuming no change in exchange rates, its GDP unadjusted for PPP will catch up to that of the United States in twenty-five to thirty years. When China’s GDP does catch up to U.S. GDP, that fact will be of more than symbolic importance. Having established an economic system that is as large, if not as efficient, as that of the United States, China’s consumption of natural resources, its participation in the international trading and financial systems, its contribution to global technological advance, and its influence in international relations and conflict man- agement are likely to approach and in some cases exceed those of the United States. The paper is organized as follows. The next section describes the basic model, partly inspired by Edward Denison’s work, that we use to organize our analysis of China’s catch-up prospects. We next examine the magnitude of the relevant productivity gaps, and we focus on the Chinese 10269-01_Jefferson-rev.qxd 1/29/07 10:56 AM Page 4 4 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2:2006 economy’s dynamic catch-up processes for reducing both the international and the internal gaps. We then combine our empirical findings to discuss the prospects and challenges for China’s GDP to catch up with that of the United States during the next twenty-five to thirty years. As already sug- gested, any analysis of China’s catch-up prospects over such a horizon must take into account the role of institutions, including both the con- straints they set and the opportunities they offer for shaping the pace at which the relevant productivity gaps are reduced. Finally, we focus on the political economy of China’s economic growth, and we draw various con- clusions from our analysis, including some policy implications. The Basic Model: Two Productivity Gaps In his study of the process by which living standards in the major non- U.S. industrial economies narrowed the gap with, and ultimately caught up to, those in the United States, Denison identified several sources of this catch-up, three of which he viewed as key: resource reallocation, scale economies, and movement toward the international technological frontier (table 1).2 In his study of China’s long-run performance, Angus Maddison cites these same three sources of long-run growth: Countries in this situation of relative backwardness and distance from the technological frontier have a capacity for fast growth if they mobilise and allocate physical and human capital effectively, adapt foreign technology to their factor proportions and utilise the opportunities for specialisation which come from integration into the world economy.3 A close examination of Denison’s results suggests the following lessons: —Within the current group of advanced industrial countries (members of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, or OECD), labor productivity in the initially poorer countries grew faster than it did in the richer countries—a necessary condition for catch-up.
Recommended publications
  • Shanghai, China's Capital of Modernity
    SHANGHAI, CHINA’S CAPITAL OF MODERNITY: THE PRODUCTION OF SPACE AND URBAN EXPERIENCE OF WORLD EXPO 2010 by GARY PUI FUNG WONG A thesis submitted to The University of Birmingham for the degree of DOCTOR OF PHILOSOHPY School of Government and Society Department of Political Science and International Studies The University of Birmingham February 2014 University of Birmingham Research Archive e-theses repository This unpublished thesis/dissertation is copyright of the author and/or third parties. The intellectual property rights of the author or third parties in respect of this work are as defined by The Copyright Designs and Patents Act 1988 or as modified by any successor legislation. Any use made of information contained in this thesis/dissertation must be in accordance with that legislation and must be properly acknowledged. Further distribution or reproduction in any format is prohibited without the permission of the copyright holder. ABSTRACT This thesis examines Shanghai’s urbanisation by applying Henri Lefebvre’s theories of the production of space and everyday life. A review of Lefebvre’s theories indicates that each mode of production produces its own space. Capitalism is perpetuated by producing new space and commodifying everyday life. Applying Lefebvre’s regressive-progressive method as a methodological framework, this thesis periodises Shanghai’s history to the ‘semi-feudal, semi-colonial era’, ‘socialist reform era’ and ‘post-socialist reform era’. The Shanghai World Exposition 2010 was chosen as a case study to exemplify how urbanisation shaped urban experience. Empirical data was collected through semi-structured interviews. This thesis argues that Shanghai developed a ‘state-led/-participation mode of production’.
    [Show full text]
  • Englischer Diplomat, Commissioner Chinese Maritime Customs Biographie 1901 James Acheson Ist Konsul Des Englischen Konsulats in Qiongzhou
    Report Title - p. 1 of 348 Report Title Acheson, James (um 1901) : Englischer Diplomat, Commissioner Chinese Maritime Customs Biographie 1901 James Acheson ist Konsul des englischen Konsulats in Qiongzhou. [Qing1] Aglen, Francis Arthur = Aglen, Francis Arthur Sir (Scarborough, Yorkshire 1869-1932 Spital Perthshire) : Beamter Biographie 1888 Francis Arthur Aglen kommt in Beijing an. [ODNB] 1888-1894 Francis Arthur Aglen ist als Assistent für den Chinese Maritime Customs Service in Beijing, Xiamen (Fujian), Guangzhou (Guangdong) und Tianjin tätig. [CMC1,ODNB] 1894-1896 Francis Arthur Aglen ist Stellvertretender Kommissar des Inspektorats des Chinese Maritime Customs Service in Beijing. [CMC1] 1899-1903 Francis Arthur Aglen ist Kommissar des Chinese Maritime Customs Service in Nanjing. [ODNB,CMC1] 1900 Francis Arthur Aglen ist General-Inspektor des Chinese Maritime Customs Service in Shanghai. [ODNB] 1904-1906 Francis Arthur Aglen ist Chefsekretär des Chinese Maritime Customs Service in Beijing. [CMC1] 1907-1910 Francis Arthur Aglen ist Kommissar des Chinese Maritime Customs Service in Hankou (Hubei). [CMC1] 1910-1927 Francis Arthur Aglen ist zuerst Stellvertretender General-Inspektor, dann General-Inspektor des Chinese Maritime Customs Service in Beijing. [ODNB,CMC1] Almack, William (1811-1843) : Englischer Teehändler Bibliographie : Autor 1837 Almack, William. A journey to China from London in a sailing vessel in 1837. [Reise auf der Anna Robinson, Opiumkrieg, Shanghai, Hong Kong]. [Manuskript Cambridge University Library]. Alton, John Maurice d' (Liverpool vor 1883) : Inspektor Chinese Maritime Customs Biographie 1883 John Maurice d'Alton kommt in China an und dient in der chinesischen Navy im chinesisch-französischen Krieg. [Who2] 1885-1921 John Maurice d'Alton ist Chef Inspektor des Chinese Maritime Customs Service in Nanjing.
    [Show full text]
  • China's Economic Growth: Implications to the ASEAN (An Integrative Report)
    Philippine APEC PASCN Study Center Network PASCN Discussion Paper No. 2001-01 China's Economic Growth: Implications to the ASEAN (An Integrative Report) Ellen H. Palanca The PASCN Discussion Paper Series constitutes studies that are preliminary and subject to further revisions and review. They are being circulated in a limited number of copies only for purposes of soliciting comments and suggestions for further refinements. The views and opinions expressed are those of the author(s) and do not neces- sarily reflect those of the Network. Not for quotation without permission from the author(s). P HILIPPINE APEC PASCN S TUDY C ENTER N ETWORK PASCN Discussion Paper No. 2001-01 China’s Economic Growth: Implications to the ASEAN (An Integrative Report) Ellen H. Palanca Ateneo de Manila University September 2001 The PASCN Discussion Paper Series constitutes studies that are preliminary and subject to further revisions and review. They are being circulated in a limited number of copies only for purposes of soliciting comments and suggestions for further refinements. The views and opinions expressed are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect those of the Network. Not for quotation without permission from the author(s). For comments, suggestions or further inquiries, please contact: The PASCN Secretariat Philippine Institute for Development Studies NEDA sa Makati Building, 106 Amorsolo Street Legaspi Village, Makati City, Philippines Tel. Nos. 893-9588 and 892-5817 ABSTRACT The rise of China’s economy in the last couple of decades can be attributed to the favorable initial conditions, the market-oriented economic reforms, and good macroeconomic management in the nineties.
    [Show full text]
  • How Effective Is the Renminbi Devaluation on China's Trade
    How Effective is the Renminbi Devaluation on China’s Trade Balance Zhaoyong Zhang, Edith Cowan University and Kiyotaka Sato, Yokohama National University Working Paper Series Vol. 2008-16 June 2008 The views expressed in this publication are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect those of the Institute. No part of this article may be used reproduced in any manner whatsoever without written permission except in the case of brief quotations embodied in articles and reviews. For information, please write to the Centre. The International Centre for the Study of East Asian Development, Kitakyushu HOW EFFECTIVE IS THE RENMINBI DEVALUATION ON CHINA’S TRADE BALANCE∗† Zhaoyong Zhang Edith Cowan University Kiyotaka Sato Yokohama National University Abstract The objective of this study is to contribute to the current discussion on the Renminbi (RMB) exchange rate by providing new evidence on China’s exchange rate policy and the impacts of RMB devaluation/revaluation on China’s output and trade balance. For a rigorous empirical examination, this research constructs a vector autoregression (VAR) model and employs the most recent econometric techniques to identify if the Chinese economic system has become responsive to the changes in the exchange rate after about three decades reform. More specifically, we use a structural VAR technique to estimate impulse response functions and variance decompositions for China’s output and trade balance, and to determine how the fundamental macroeconomic shocks contribute to the fluctuations in the real exchange rate, and how output and trade account respond to the identified various shocks. This study will contribute to our better understanding of how far and how fast China’s reforms have transformed the economy to a market-oriented economy, and also the recent discussion on China’s exchange rate policy.
    [Show full text]
  • Measuring and Interpreting World Economic Performance 1500-2001
    Measuring and Interpreting World Economic Performance 1500-2001 By Angus Maddison © Macro-measurement started in the seventeenth century, but did not emerge as a basic analytical tool for policy analysts and economic historians until the 1940s. In the past 60 years there has been an explosion in the sophistication of policy analysis and the interpretation of history. The explosion started in 1940 with two seminal works: Keynes’ How to Pay for the War which demonstrated its usefulness as a tool of macroeconomic management, and Colin Clark’s Conditions of Economic Progress which demonstrated its value in interpreting economic history. Dissemination and development of techniques of macro-measurement was a major objective of the founding fathers of the International Association for Research in Income and Wealth (IARIW). The initiative came from Simon Kuznets (1901-85), the pioneer of quantitative economic history. Milton Gilbert (1909-79) and Richard Stone (1913-1991) were strategic partners with enormous international leverage in creating and diffusing standard procedures for construction of comparable national accounts by official statistical offices. In the past half-century, I have followed the Kuznetsian approach, augmenting the historical accounts and broadening their geographic scope with my own research, using it to interpret economic performance with a similar analytical toolkit and the same emphasis on transparent description of source material, encouraging graduate students to follow the same path, and creating networks of scholars active in this brand of quantitative economic history. Now we have fairly comprehensive coverage for the whole of the capitalist epoch from 1820 onwards. There are of course gaps in the evidence and scope for improving its quality, but the new challenge, which I have taken up in recent years, is to push the quantitative record further back in time.
    [Show full text]
  • An Analysis of the Appreciation of the Chinese Currency and Influences on China's Economy
    University of Denver Digital Commons @ DU Electronic Theses and Dissertations Graduate Studies 1-1-2014 An Analysis of the Appreciation of the Chinese Currency and Influences on China's Economy Lina Ma University of Denver Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.du.edu/etd Part of the Asian Studies Commons, Economic Theory Commons, and the International Economics Commons Recommended Citation Ma, Lina, "An Analysis of the Appreciation of the Chinese Currency and Influences on China's Economy" (2014). Electronic Theses and Dissertations. 408. https://digitalcommons.du.edu/etd/408 This Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the Graduate Studies at Digital Commons @ DU. It has been accepted for inclusion in Electronic Theses and Dissertations by an authorized administrator of Digital Commons @ DU. For more information, please contact [email protected],[email protected]. An Analysis of the Appreciation of the Chinese Currency and Influences on China’s Economy A Thesis Presented to the Faculty of Social Sciences University of Denver In Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree Master of Arts By Lina Ma November 2014 Advisor: Tracy Mott Author: Lina Ma Title: An Analysis of the Appreciation of the Chinese Currency and Influences on China’s Economy Advisor: Tracy Mott Degree Date: November 2014 ABSTRACT In recent years, China’s economy development has had more and more impact on the global economy. The Chinese currency continued to appreciate since 2005, which has had both positive and negative results on Chinese’s economy. The Chinese government uses the monetary policy to control the inflation pressure, which could work counter to Chinese exchange rate policy.
    [Show full text]
  • Chinese Direct Investment in Europe : Economic Opportunities and Political Challenges
    Chapter prepared for Ka Zeng ed., Handbook of the International Political Economy of China, Edward Elgar, forthcoming 2018 Chinese Direct Investment in Europe : Economic Opportunities and Political Challenges Sophie Meunier Princeton University [email protected] Abstract: Over the past decade, China has become one of the largest senders of foreign direct investment (FDI) in the world, including in the European Union (EU). Why did this rapid surge happen and how did European countries react politically to this new phenomenon, which some have presented as unprecedented and even dangerous? After surveying the recent evolution of Chinese FDI in Europe, this chapter analyzes the match between Chinese demand for European assets and European supply of assets after the outbreak of the euro crisis. The last section considers the political challenges raised in Europe by the rapid and ubiquitous rise of Chinese FDI and some of the policy responses to these challenges. Keywords: China; euro crisis; EU; European Union; FDI; investment 1 Chinese outward investment into the European Union (EU) has increased very rapidly over the past decade. From a non-existent player fifteen years ago, China has now become one of the largest senders of foreign direct investment (FDI) flows in the world. In Europe, China has seemingly become an ubiquitous investor from airports to ports, hotels to automobiles, and English to Italian football clubs. This surge of Chinese investment has been particularly noticeable because it occurred in a context of decreasing investment worldwide in the wake of the United States (U.S.) financial crisis and it has been widely covered in the media, often through sensationalistic headlines.
    [Show full text]
  • Levels of Structural Change: an Analysis of China's Development
    Munich Personal RePEc Archive Levels of structural change: An analysis of China’s development push 1998-2014 Heinrich, Torsten and Yang, Jangho and Dai, Shuanping Oxford Martin Programme on Technological and Economic Change, Oxford Martin School, University of Oxford, Oxford OX1 3BD, UK;, Institute for New Economic Thinking at the Oxford Martin School, University of Oxford, Oxford OX1 3UQ, UK;, Department for Business Studies and Economics, University of Bremen, 28359 Bremen, Germany;, Department of Management Sciences, Faculty of Engineering, University of Waterloo, Waterloo, ON, N2L 3G1, Canada, School of Economics, Jilin University, 130012, Changchun, China, Centre for China Public Sector Economy Research Center, Jilin University, 130012, Changchun, China, IN-EAST Institute of East Asian Studies, Universität Duisburg-Essen, 47057 Duisburg, Germany; 4 May 2020 Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/103224/ MPRA Paper No. 103224, posted 30 Sep 2020 13:34 UTC Levels of structural change: An analysis of China’s development push 1998-2014 Torsten Heinrich1,2,3,†, Jangho Yang4,1,2,‡, and Shuanping Dai5,6,7,¶ 1Oxford Martin Programme on Technological and Economic Change, Oxford Martin School, University of Oxford, Oxford OX1 3BD, UK 2Institute for New Economic Thinking at the Oxford Martin School, University of Oxford, Oxford OX1 3UQ, UK 3Department for Business Studies and Economics, University of Bremen, 28359 Bremen, Germany 4Department of Management Sciences, Faculty of Engineering, University of Waterloo, Waterloo, ON, N2L 3G1, Canada 5School of Economics, Jilin University, 130012, Changchun, China 6Centre for China Public Sector Economy Research, Jilin University, 130012, Changchun, China 7IN-EAST Institute of East Asian Studies, Universität Duisburg-Essen, 47057 Duisburg, Germany – †[email protected][email protected][email protected] – September 30, 2020 Abstract We investigate structural change in the PR China during a period of particularly rapid growth 1998-2014.
    [Show full text]
  • Levels of Structural Change: an Analysis of China's Development
    Levels of structural change: An analysis of China’s development push 1998-2014 Torsten Heinrich1,2,3,y, Jangho Yang4,1,2,z, and Shuanping Dai5,6,7,{ 1Oxford Martin Programme on Technological and Economic Change, Oxford Martin School, University of Oxford, Oxford OX1 3BD, UK 2Institute for New Economic Thinking at the Oxford Martin School, University of Oxford, Oxford OX1 3UQ, UK 3Department for Business Studies and Economics, University of Bremen, 28359 Bremen, Germany 4Department of Management Sciences, Faculty of Engineering, University of Waterloo, Waterloo, ON, N2L 3G1, Canada 5School of Economics, Jilin University, 130012, Changchun, China 6Centre for China Public Sector Economy Research, Jilin University, 130012, Changchun, China 7IN-EAST Institute of East Asian Studies, Universität Duisburg-Essen, 47057 Duisburg, Germany – [email protected] [email protected] {[email protected] – October 1, 2020 Abstract We investigate structural change in the PR China during a period of particularly rapid growth 1998-2014. For this, we utilize sectoral data from the World Input-Output Database and firm-level data from the Chinese Industrial Enterprise Database. Starting with correlation laws known from the literature (Fabricant’s laws), we investigate which empirical regularities hold at the sectoral level and show that many of these correlations cannot be recovered at the firm level. For a more detailed analysis, we propose a multi-level framework, which is validated empirically. For this, we perform a robust regression, since various input variables at the firm-level as well as the residuals of exploratory OLS regressions are found to be heavy-tailed. We conclude that Fabricant’s laws and other regularities are primarily characteristics of the sectoral level which rely on aspects like infrastructure, technology level, innovation capabilities, and the knowledge base of the relevant labor force.
    [Show full text]
  • 2005 REPORT to CONGRESS of the U.S.-CHINA ECONOMIC and SECURITY REVIEW COMMISSION
    2005 REPORT TO CONGRESS of the U.S.-CHINA ECONOMIC AND SECURITY REVIEW COMMISSION ONE HUNDRED NINTH CONGRESS FIRST SESSION NOVEMBER 2005 Printed for the use of the U.S.-China Economic and Security Review Commission Available via the World Wide Web: http://www.uscc.gov 1 2005 REPORT TO CONGRESS of the U.S.-CHINA ECONOMIC AND SECURITY REVIEW COMMISSION ONE HUNDRED NINTH CONGRESS FIRST SESSION NOVEMBER 2005 Printed for the use of the U.S.-China Economic and Security Review Commission Available via the World Wide Web: http://www.uscc.gov U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE WASHINGTON : 2005 For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office Internet: bookstore.gpo.gov Phone: toll free (866) 512–1800; DC area (202) 512–1800 Fax: (202) 512–2250 Mail: Stop SSOP, Washington, DC 20402–0001 U.S.-CHINA ECONOMIC AND SECURITY REVIEW COMMISSION Hall of the States, Suite 602 444 North Capitol Street, NW Washington, DC 20001 Phone: (202) 624–1407 Fax: (202) 624–1406 E-mail: [email protected] www.uscc.gov COMMISSIONERS Hon. C. RICHARD D’AMATO, Chairman ROGER W. ROBINSON, Jr., Vice Chairman CAROLYN BARTHOLOMEW, Commissioner Hon. PATRICK A. MULLOY, Commissioner GEORGE BECKER, Commissioner Hon. WILLIAM A. REINSCH, Commissioner STEPHEN D. BRYEN, Commissioner Hon. FRED D. THOMPSON, Commissioner THOMAS DONNELLY, Commissioner MICHAEL R. WESSEL, Commissioner JUNE TEUFEL DREYER, Commissioner LARRY M. WORTZEL, Commissioner T. SCOTT BUNTON, Executive Director KATHLEEN J. MICHELS, Associate Director The Commission was created in October 2000 by the Floyd D. Spence Na- tional Defense Authorization Act for 2001 sec. 1238, Public Law 106– 398, 114 STAT.
    [Show full text]
  • International Report: China Report: China
    InternationalInternational Report: China Report: China China’s changing available in most Chinese cities, with air- about $6,300 per capita. Even at the offi- conditioning, cable television (includ- cial exchange rate, China’s GDP ($1.8 tril- economy ing programming in English), Internet lion) ranked seventh in the world, just Lawrence H. Leith access, and personal amenities such as ahead of Italy’s ($1.7 trillion) and just be- toothpaste, shampoo, and shower gel. hind France’s ($2.1 trillion). By compari- Similarly, a person visiting a major city son, U.S. GDP, second only to that of the By all accounts, the economy of China in China sees many of the same indica- European Union, rose to $12.8 trillion in has undergone profound changes over tions of commerce and economic activ- 2005 ($12.5 trillion in purchasing power the last several decades. The changes ity that he or she might discern in West- parity), or close to $42,000 per capita. began in the late 1970s, shortly after the ern cities: highrise buildings form the China’s economic reforms began in death of Mao Zedong, and they have skylines; commercial banks, real estate 1978, when many of its communes and been accelerating in recent years. Since offices, and other financial institutions collectives were dismantled and replaced 1978, when Mao’s successor, Deng fill the central business districts; large with a “responsibility system,” in which Xiaoping, introduced the first market- department stores, boutiques, grocery individual farmers were given greater oriented reforms, China has developed stores, and restaurants provide shop- choice over what they produce.
    [Show full text]
  • The Scope of Economic Activity in International Income Comparisons
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Problems in the International Comparison of Economic Accounts Volume Author/Editor: The Conference on Research in Income and Wealth Volume Publisher: Princeton University Press Volume ISBN: 0-870-14176-7 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/unkn57-2 Publication Date: 1957 Chapter Title: The Scope of Economic Activity in International Income Comparisons Chapter Author: Irving Kravis Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c2687 Chapter pages in book: (p. 349 - 400) 5.The Scope of Economic Activity in International Income Comparisons IRVING B. KRAVIS UNIVERSITY OF PENNSYLVANIA Summary THE PURPOSE of this paper is to find a concept of economic activity that will be useful in comparing national incomes in two situations distinguished by widely different social and economic institutions. Interest is focused on interspatial rather than intertemporal insti-. tutional differences and on income comparisons between developed and underdeveloped countries. The view is taken that such com- parisons should be limited to flows of goods obtained through eco- nomic activity in the two situations. This rules out possible com- parisons between the products of a common set of institutions (i.e. the market economy) or between a common list of products. However, it raises fundamental questions regarding the scope of economic activity under different institutional arrangements. Are institutional differences between the developed and under- developed countries so great as to preclude meaningful compari- sons? My analysis of the differences between the two types of economies suggests that significant income comparisons can be made.
    [Show full text]