How to Get the Snowball Rolling and Extend the Franchise: Voting on the Great Reform Act of 1832

How to Get the Snowball Rolling and Extend the Franchise: Voting on the Great Reform Act of 1832

How to Get the Snowball Rolling and Extend the Franchise: Voting on the Great Reform Act of 1832* Toke S. Aidta Faculty of Economics and Jesus College, University of Cambridge Raphaël Franckb Department of Economics, Bar Ilan University Abstract This paper suggests a new approach to analyze the causes of franchise extension. Based on a new dataset, it provides a detailed econometric study of the Great Reform Act of 1832 in the United Kingdom. The econometric analysis yields four main results. First, modernization theory only receives mixed support. Second, the reform enjoyed some measure of popular support. Third, the threat of revolution had an asymmetric impact on the voting behavior of the pro-reform Whigs and the anti-reform Tories. While the threat might have convinced reluctant reformers among the Whig politicians – and among their patrons – to support the bill, it seems to have hardened the resistance to reform among the Tories. Fourth, ideology played a critical role. However, it also appears that self-interest and political expedience explained the votes of many Members of Parliament. Keywords: Franchise extension; democratization; The Great Reform Act. JEL Classification: D7, H1. * We thank Hans Pitlik and participants at the 2008 EPCS meeting in Jena for helpful comments. The usual disclaimer applies. a Faculty of Economics, Austin Robinson Building, Sidgwick Avenue, CB39DD Cambridge, U.K. Email: [email protected]. b Bar Ilan University, Department of Economics, 52900 Ramat Gan, Israel. Email: [email protected]. 1 1. Introduction To this day, the passing in 1832 by the British Parliament of a bill, which subsequently became known as the Great Reform Act, is seen as a watershed. The immediate consequences of this reform were to redistribute parliamentary seats from the small “rotten boroughs”1 to the large and fast growing industrial cities, as well as to extend the franchise to “respectable” segments of the middle class. But in the long run, the Great Reform Act was the pivotal event that got the snowball rolling: it was the first of five major reforms that gradually transformed the political system in the United Kingdom. In the 1830 general election, no more than three per cent of the adult male population could cast their vote while the bulk of the 658 Members of Parliament (MPs) were returned in uncontested elections. Less than 100 years later, in 1928, all men and women aged 21 and above could vote in contested elections. In the intertwining years, the franchise had gradually been extended by the Second Reform Act of 1867, the Third Reform Act of 1884, and the Fourth Reform Act of 1918. In addition, the secret ballot had been introduced in 1872, plural votes discontinued, and a uniform system of districting adopted (see among others Machin, 2001). Broadly speaking, the historical narrative suggests two rationales for the success of the Great Reform Act.2 One emphasizes extra-parliamentarian pressures and points to evidence such as the riots in several towns in the autumn of 1831, talks of armed uprising, and the flood of petitions to Parliament from all parts of the country in support of reform. Another emphasizes changes in the balance of power within Parliament. These 1 Rotten boroughs were also known as “nomination” or “pocket” boroughs. 2 See Brock (1973) and Cannon (1973) among others. See also Evans (2000) for a concise exposition. 2 changes included the fall of the anti-reform Tory government in 1830 which allowed a pro-reform Whig government to take office for the first time since 1806. But beyond the historical narrative, economists and political scientists alike have developed formal theories that seek to explain the willingness of ruling elites to share power with groups whose goals they may oppose. They have emphasized modernization theory, i.e., the role of economic growth and social progress (Moore, 1966), the role of ideology (Tilly, 2004), mass conscription armies (Janowitz, 1976), or the broader context of constitutional bargaining (Congleton, 2004, 2007). Some prominent scholars, e.g., Justman and Gradstein (1999), Acemoglu and Robinson (2000; 2005) and Boix (2003), have argued that external pressures, which are often conceptualized as a threat of revolution, forced the elites to share power. Seen in this perspective, granting voting rights to previously disenfranchised groups was a lesser evil for the ruling elite. Others have suggested that the extension of the suffrage was a consequence of economic changes that made democracy more profitable for the ruling elite. This might be the case if property rights are better protected under democracy (Gradstein, 2007), if democracy enhances human capital accumulation (Bourguignon and Verdier, 2000) or if a significant fraction of the elite can benefit from greater provision of public services under democratic governments (Lizzeri and Persico, 2004). All of these theories offer convincing interpretations of specific historical episodes and can be supported by detailed historical case studies. Some of them have also been subjected to econometric testing.3 These tests, which focus on the consequences of 3 See among others Meltzer and Richard (1983), Hettich and Winer (1988), Lindert (1994), Husted and Kenny (1997), Kenny and Lott (1999), Persson and Tabellini (2003), Aidt et al. (2006) and Aidt and Jensen (2008a, 2008b). 3 suffrage reform rather than on its underlying causes, employ cross-country or cross-state variations in the franchise rules to identify the effects of democratization. This paper suggests a new approach to the study of franchise extension. Our approach is to investigate the underlying causes of democratization by studying the votes of the politicians who adopt suffrage reforms. This allows us to test the relevance of competing theories of democratization in new ways.4 The Great Reform Act of 1832 is well-suited for such an empirical approach because it was debated and voted on under the rules of the Unreformed Parliament. These rules had not been changed for almost 200 years prior to the reform and can therefore be taken as exogenous.5 Moreover, the Unreformed Parliament exhibited a very rich and varied set of institutions that allows us to construct new tests of four prominent theories of franchise extension. We can thus assess the causal role played by ideology, the threat of a revolution, and economic factors such as the rise of a middle class and economic prosperity, in the adoption of the Great Reform Act. For this purpose, we assembled a new dataset from a combination of primary and secondary sources that provides detailed information on the characteristics of each parliamentary constituency in England and Wales, as well as on the elected MPs.6 The econometric analysis yields four main results. First, modernization theory only receives mixed support. On the one hand, we find that economic prosperity in a 4 Schonhardt-Bailey (1998) adopts a similar approach in her study of industrial and agricultural interests in the German Parliament during the nineteenth-century. See also Schonhardt-Bailey (2006) on the repeal of the Corn Laws. 5 The challenge of finding exogenous variations in institutions has received substantial attention in some recent studies on democratization. On this issue, see, for instance, Acemoglu et al. (2001). 6 As a caveat, it must be noted that the lack of information about the characteristics of the Scottish and Irish boroughs and counties compels us to focus on the MPs elected in England and Wales only. Out of the 658 MPs returned to Parliament in 1830 and 1831, 513 were elected in England and Wales. 4 constituency increased, rather than decreased, the likelihood that an anti-reform MP was returned to Parliament. On the other hand, we do find some evidence that the economic changes that created more cohesive working and middle classes spurred the reform process. Second, the reform enjoyed some measure of popular support. In particular, we find that pro-reform MPs were more likely to be elected in constituencies with relatively large electorates and contested elections. Third, the threat of revolution had an asymmetric impact on the voting behavior of the pro-reform Whigs and the anti-reform Tories. While the threat might have convinced reluctant reformers among the Whig MPs – and among their patrons – to support the bill, it seems to have hardened the resistance to reform among the Tories. Fourth, ideology played a critical role. However, we also find evidence that self-interest and political expedience explained the votes of many MPs. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses the political system in the United Kingdom under the Unreformed Parliament and provides an overview of the events that led to the Great Reform Act. Section 3 sets out our hypotheses and econometric strategy. Section 4 discusses the empirical results. Section 5 concludes. The Appendix provides some additional estimations and outlines the content of the Great Reform Act. 2. The Unreformed Parliament and the Great Reform Act: Data and Historical Background In 1830, the electoral rules of the Unreformed Parliament were still virtually the same as in the past centuries. Despite the economic transformations caused by the industrial revolution, there had neither been any substantial redistribution of seats since the seventeenth century, nor any notable extension of the franchise. This had already 5 created by the end of the eighteenth century a large imbalance between the old and new population centers. The South of England, particularly Cornwall, was over-represented, while the large industrial cities in the Midlands and the North, such as Birmingham, Leeds and Manchester, did not elect any MP. The politics of the Unreformed Parliament was very different from that of modern parliamentary democracies. Firstly, the franchise rules, which governed who could vote, were not uniform throughout the country.

View Full Text

Details

  • File Type
    pdf
  • Upload Time
    -
  • Content Languages
    English
  • Upload User
    Anonymous/Not logged-in
  • File Pages
    66 Page
  • File Size
    -

Download

Channel Download Status
Express Download Enable

Copyright

We respect the copyrights and intellectual property rights of all users. All uploaded documents are either original works of the uploader or authorized works of the rightful owners.

  • Not to be reproduced or distributed without explicit permission.
  • Not used for commercial purposes outside of approved use cases.
  • Not used to infringe on the rights of the original creators.
  • If you believe any content infringes your copyright, please contact us immediately.

Support

For help with questions, suggestions, or problems, please contact us