Flight to Quality, Flight to Liquidity, and the Pricing of Risk

Flight to Quality, Flight to Liquidity, and the Pricing of Risk

Flight to Quality, Flight to Liquidity, and the Pricing of Risk Dimitri Vayanos MIT and NBER February 2003 Introduction 1 INTRODUCTION Liquidity premia seem to vary substantially over time. • Clean experiments: • { T-notes vs. T-bills. (Amihud and Mendelson (1991), Ka- mara (1994), Strebulaev (2002)) { Off- vs. on-the run bonds. (Krishnamurthy (2002)) { Refcorp vs. government bonds. (Longstaff (2002)) { Municipal vs. government bonds. (Chalmers, Kadlec, and Mozumdar (2002)) Effects can be quite strong. • { Variation in spread equals 4-6 times average spread. { Variation in relative prices can be up to 15%. { Flight to liquidity. Effects could be stronger for other asset classes. • { Corporate bonds. { Emerging market bonds. { Stocks. Introduction 2 Why Do Liquidity Premia Vary? Liquidity premia seem to be high when • { Interest-rate volatility is high. (Kamara (1994)) { Consumer confidence is low. (Longstaff (2002)) { Money flows away from equity funds, into money market funds. (Longstaff (2002)) { Stock market goes down. (Chalmers, Kadlec, and Mozum- dar (2002)) Variation in liquidity premia seems to be correlated across mar- • kets. { On-the-run premium is correlated with commercial-paper spread. (Krishnamurthy (2002)) Introduction 3 Questions Questions: • { What is economic mechanism driving variation in liquidity premia? { How is risk associated to changes in liquidity premia priced? Answers could be important for understanding • { An important component of asset price volatility. { An important component of pricing of asset risk. (Espe- cially for illiquid assets.) Introduction 4 This Paper Proposes a theory of time-varying liquidity premia. • Explores its asset-pricing implications. • Dynamic multi-asset equilibrium model. • Introduction 5 Main Assumptions Transaction costs. Exogenous, constant over time, different across assets. • Illiquid assets High TC. • ≡ Time-variation in liquidity premia will not caused by TC. • { Seems realistic: Variation in bid-ask spreads is often small relative to that in liquidity premia. Off-the-run bonds. ∗ Refcorp bonds. (Longstaff (2002)) ∗ Introduction 6 Main Assumptions (cont'd) Stochastic volatility. Asset payoffs have stochastic volatility. • Volatility will drive liquidity premia. • Seems realistic. • { Empirical evidence. { Anecdotal evidence: Traders value liquidity more at times of \uncertainty." Delegated money management. Portfolio decisions are made by fund managers. • When return falls below a threshold, fund is liquidated. • High volatility High liquidation probability Short invest- • ) ) ment horizons High liquidity premia. ) Introduction 7 Results / Empirical Implications Liquidity premia ( price differentials between assets which are • ≡ identical except for TC) increase with volatility. { Flight to liquidity. Market's effective risk aversion ( expected return per unit of • ≡ variance) increases with volatility. { Flight to quality. { Risk aversion varies not because of stochastic utility func- tions, but because of concern of liquidation. Betas depend on volatility. • { Betas of illiquid assets increase with volatility. Correlations depend on volatility. • { Correlations between similar assets increase with volatility. Unconditional two-factor CAPM (factors = market, volatility) • does not price assets correctly. { Understates risk of illiquid assets. Implications for price of volatility factor. • Model 8 MODEL Infinite horizon, discrete time. Time between periods is h. • Assets. Riskless asset, return rh. r is exogenous. • N risky assets. • Volatility v evolves according to • t v = v + γ(v v )h + σ v hη : t+h t − t t t+h p Asset n pays dividend δ h. δ evolves according to • n;t n;t δ = δ +κ(δ δ )h+ v h (φ ζ + η + ξ ) : n;t+h n;t − n;t t n t+h n t+h n;t+h p { ζt+h: systematic shock, independent of ηt+h. { ξn;t+h: idiosyncratic shock. Supply S . • n Transaction costs per share . • n Price (average of bid and ask) p . • n;t Model 9 Fund Management and Liquidation Each investor \manages" a fund of size W . • t Performance-based liquidation: • { In each period, a fund can be \monitored" by its owners with probability µh. { Fund is liquidated if W W < Lph, for L > 0. t+h − t − Random liquidation: • { In each period, a fund can be liquidated with probability λh, regardless of performance. At liquidation: • { Investment in each asset is sold in the market. { Manager can find employment in a new fund, whose size is equal to old fund's liquidation value. Model 10 Fund Managers Infinitely lived, continuum, mass one. • Manager decides how much to allocate in each asset. • Exogenous management fee (aW + b)h. • t Exogenous withdrawal by fund's owners (aW^ + ^b)h. • t Assumptions: a > 0, a + a^ = r=(1 + rh). • Manager maximizes • 1 E exp ( αc βkh) : − − t+kh − Xk=0 Consumption is derived from fee. • Manager can save/borrow in riskless asset. • Equilibrium 11 EQUILIBRIUM Basic Properties Managers buy and hold the market portfolio. • Price of asset n is • 1 κh p = q (v ) + − (δ δ): n;t n t r + κ n;t − Value function of a manager is • exp [ A[W + zw + Z(v )]] ; − − t t t where A αa, z r=[(1 + rh)a], and w are manager's ≡ ≡ t private savings. When h goes to zero, functions q (v) and Z(v) can • f n gn=1;::;N be characterized by a system of N + 1 ODEs. { ODEs are derived from Bellman equation. { They are second order. Equilibrium 12 Preliminaries Notation: • { φ N S φ , M ≡ n=1 n n { N S , M ≡ Pn=1 n n { q (v) N S q (v), M ≡P n=1 n n { N S . M ≡ nP=1 n n Number ofPassets N becomes large, while N S stays fixed. • n=1 n { Sn goes to zero. P { Idiosyncratic shocks do not matter. No Performance-Based Liquidation 13 NO PERFORMANCE-BASED LIQUIDATION ODEs for q (v) and Z(v) have linear solution: • f n gn=1;::;N { q (v) = q q v. n n0 − n1 { q (v) = q q v. M M0 − M1 { Z(v) = Z0 + Z1v. Properties: • { qM1 > 0: Market goes down when volatility increases. { @qn0=@n < 0: Liquidity premia are positive. { @qn1=@n = 0: Liquidity premia are independent of volatil- ity. No Performance-Based Liquidation 14 CAPM ODE for q (v) can be written as • n Et(Rn;t+h) = ACovt(Rn;t+h; RM;t+h) + AZ0(vt)Covt(Rn;t+h; Rv;t+h) + [r + 2λ exp(2AM )] nh; where { Rn;t+h: excess return on asset n. { RM;t+h: excess return on market portfolio. { Rv;t+h: excess return on volatility portfolio. { Excess returns are per share, and between t and t + h. Conditional two-factor CAPM, adjusted for transaction costs. • Linear solution Z0(v ) = Z . • ) t 1 Taking expectations, we find • E(Rn;t+h) = ACov(Rn;t+h; RM;t+h) + AZ1Cov(Rn;t+h; Rv;t+h) + [r + 2λ exp(2AM )] nh; i.e., unconditional two-factor CAPM, adjusted for transaction costs. No Performance-Based Liquidation 15 Volatility Factor Recent research has considered a volatility/liquidity factor. • Pastor and Stambaugh (2001) • { Liquidity factor Price reversals. ≡ Acharya and Pedersen (2002) • { Liquidity factor Aggregate price impact. ≡ Liquidity factor: • { Negative risk premium. { Significant explanatory power. { In our model, aggregate price impact is proportional to volatility Volatility factor corresponds to PS-AP liquidity ) factor. Ang and Hodrick (2002) • { Volatility factor. No Performance-Based Liquidation 16 Volatility Risk Premium Z > 0 Volatility factor carries positive risk premium. • 1 ) { Holding market beta constant, investors prefer assets that pay off when volatility is low. { Opposite to empirical findings. Intuition: • { Holding wealth constant, investors are better off at times of high volatility. Performance-Based Liquidation 17 PERFORMANCE-BASED LIQUIDATION Liquidation condition is W W < Lph. • t+h − t − Probability of this event depends on tails of ζ and η . • t+h t+h Normal distribution is not tractable. • Power laws are, however, very tractable. • Performance-Based Liquidation 18 Power Laws Assume that lower tail of ζ and upper tail of η follow • t+h t+h power laws with exponent b, i.e., c Prob(ζ < y) ζ ; t+h − ∼ yb c Prob(η > y) η : t+h ∼ yb b = 2: Liquidation probability is • 2 2 vt φM M π(v ) = c + c + q0 (v )σ : t L2 ζ (r + κ)2 η r + κ M t " # Linear in vt. b = 4: Liquidation probability is • 2 4 4 vt φM M π(v ) = c + c + q0 (v )σ : t L4 ζ (r + κ)4 η r + κ M t " # Quadratic in vt. Equations are valid for L large relative to v . • t Performance-Based Liquidation 19 Asset Pricing Expected returns are given by • Et(Rn;t+h) = ACovt(Rn;t+h; RM;t+h) + AZ0(vt)Covt(Rn;t+h; Rv;t+h) @π(v ; x) exp(2A ) 1 +µ t M − h @x A n x=S + [r + 2 [λ + µπ(vt)] exp(2AM )] nh: Third term is \liquidation" risk premium. • Linear Liquidation Probability 20 LINEAR LIQUIDATION PROBABILITY Solution is still linear. • { q (v) = q q v n n0 − n1 { q (v) = q q v M M0 − M1 { Z(v) = Z0 + Z1v. New property: • { @qn1=@n > 0: Liquidity premia increase with volatility. Linear Liquidation Probability 21 CAPM Liquidation risk premium depends on covariance between asset • n, and market and volatility portfolios. Can incorporate liquidation risk premium into CAPM risk • ) premium. Conditional two-factor CAPM, with modified risk-aversion • ) coefficients: Et(Rn;t+h) = AM (vt)Covt(Rn;t+h; RM;t+h) +Av(vt)Covt(Rn;t+h; Rv;t+h) + [r + 2 [λ + µπ(vt)] exp(2AM )] nh: In linear case, modified risk-aversion coefficients A (v ) and • M t Av(vt) are constants. Taking expectations, we can derive unconditional two-factor • ) CAPM. Linear Liquidation Probability 22 Risk-Aversion Coefficients For market portfolio: • µ exp(2A ) 1 A A + 2 c M − : M ≡ L2 ζ A { Greater than without performance-based liquidation. For volatility portfolio: • µ exp(2A ) 1 A AZ +2 (c c ) q M M − : v ≡ 1 L2 ζ − η M1 − σ(r + κ) A { Can become negative if cη > cζ (volatility tails fatter than dividend tails).

View Full Text

Details

  • File Type
    pdf
  • Upload Time
    -
  • Content Languages
    English
  • Upload User
    Anonymous/Not logged-in
  • File Pages
    31 Page
  • File Size
    -

Download

Channel Download Status
Express Download Enable

Copyright

We respect the copyrights and intellectual property rights of all users. All uploaded documents are either original works of the uploader or authorized works of the rightful owners.

  • Not to be reproduced or distributed without explicit permission.
  • Not used for commercial purposes outside of approved use cases.
  • Not used to infringe on the rights of the original creators.
  • If you believe any content infringes your copyright, please contact us immediately.

Support

For help with questions, suggestions, or problems, please contact us