<p>Price Discrimination: Monopolist’s Charging More than One Price</p><p>- Single-price monopoly: monopolist is constrained to charge the same price to all buyers.</p><p>- Price discrimination usually allows the monopolist to do better.</p><p>(turn some consumer surplus into profit)</p><p> i.e. push the price closer to a consumer’s willingness-to-pay (WTP)</p><p>WTP? height of the demand curve, maximum consumer would pay for a particular unit of the good.</p><p>1 - Why not price discriminate all the time?</p><p>(a) resale problem: those who buy low might resell to those who are charged a high price (arbitrage)</p><p>- resale undercuts monopolist: can re-establish a single price.</p><p>(consider: airline ticket restrictions, services vs. goods)</p><p>(see handout from McAfee: lists factors affecting resale)</p><p>(b) information problem: can the monopolist identify those willing to pay a high price?</p><p>- those willing to pay most have no incentive to reveal this. </p><p>- can a monopolist find some way to identify them? if so price discrimination becomes more likely. </p><p>Types of price discrimination:</p><p>Perfect price discrimination: charge a different price for each (first-degree price discrim.) unit sold.</p><p>Second degree price discrimination: different price for different units bought by the same customer.</p><p>Third-degree price discrimination: different price for different groups of customers. </p><p>(we will model each of these and give examples below)</p><p>------</p><p>2 Perfect Price Discrimination: (First-degree price discrimination)</p><p>- Monopolist knows the maximum that each buyer is willing-to-pay (WTP) for each unit of the good. </p><p> i.e., knows the height of the demand curve at each quantity.</p><p>- assume there is no resale problem.</p><p>- Perfect price discrimination: different prices for each unit sold.</p><p>- charge each consumer the maximum they are willing to pay for each unit of the good bought.</p><p>- As before the monopolist will maximize profits by producing up to the point where MR=MC.</p><p>- but the MR curve is now the same as the demand curve!</p><p>- a different price is charged for each unit sold.</p><p>- so: MR = Price </p><p>- the perfectly price discriminating monopolist need not cut the price charged to “infra-marginal” buyers to sell more output.</p><p>(infra-marginal buyers : buyers not at the margin)</p><p>3 - What will the monopolist do?</p><p>- produce up to the point where: </p><p>MR = MC</p><p>Price of the last unit sold = MC (QPPD in diagram)</p><p>- charge each consumer the maximum that they will pay. </p><p>- this allows the monopolist to expropriate all of the consumer surplus. (all surplus is producer surplus!)</p><p>- profit is as large as it can possibly be in this market.</p><p>- output is higher than in the single-price case: </p><p>- no reason to restrict output </p><p>- selling more does not require price cuts for infra-marginal buyers.</p><p>4 - Outcome is efficient! -- achieves maximum surplus</p><p>- same output level of perfect competition. </p><p>- But all surplus goes to the monopolist as producer surplus. </p><p>- Hard to perfectly price discriminate in practice: </p><p>- monopolist needs a lot of information. </p><p>- Any possibilities? </p><p>- One-to-one bargaining: bargain over price, can a skilled seller extract the maximum possible price?</p><p>- maybe sometimes for : used cars, street vendors, flea markets.</p><p>- Top US universities? individualized tuition: price as tuition minus individualized assistance. </p><p>- how close can they get?</p><p>5 - Is information technology pushing us in this direction?</p><p>- Internet retailers: gather information on past purchasing behaviour and tailor the price offered to past behaviour.</p><p>- Grocery store discount cards: collect information on buying patterns (tailor prices to customers via coupons sent out). </p><p>- Google ad auctions -- is it close to this?</p><p>- Consumer reaction: unfair! (early Amazon case).</p><p>6 A Monopolist with Multiple Markets: (Third-degree Price Discrimination)</p><p>- Monopolist price discriminates between consumers but not between units of a good bought by a particular consumer.</p><p>- Say the monopolist can separate customers into two markets with different demand curves, i.e. groups with differences in WTP:</p><p>- so: has partly overcome the information problem;</p><p>- assume that customers cannot resell between the two markets.</p><p>- The firm faces two demand curves (D1 and D2) and two marginal revenue curves (MR1 and MR2).</p><p>- As before one set of cost curves: it is the same firm producing output for both markets.</p><p>- Firm decides how much to sell and what price to charge in each market.</p><p>- Consider first unit of output the firm might produce:</p><p>- Profitable to produce it as long as MR > MC in at least one market.</p><p>- Sell it in the market with the highest MR.</p><p>- Similar decision for all subsequent units: </p><p>- Produce more as long as MR >MC and sell each unit in the market with the highest MR.</p><p>- This creates a tendency to keep MR1 = MR2 if selling in both markets.</p><p>- Consequence? MR curve for the combined market is the horizontal </p><p> sum (over quantities) of MR1 and MR2.</p><p>7 - Produce total output at the point where the horizontal sum of MR1 and MR2 equals MC. </p><p>- output in market 1 is where:</p><p>MR1 = MC (MC determined where the combined MR curve =MC)</p><p>- output in market 2 is where:</p><p>MR2 = MC (MC determined where the combined MR curve =MC) e.g. </p><p>8 (Combined MR = MC at Q1*+Q2* prices will be P1* and P2*)</p><p>(see another version: text Fig. 12-13)</p><p>- Notice that if MC intersected MR1+MR2 on its first segment (so output below Q11) -- the monopolist would only sell in market 1. </p><p>- Market 2 would never generate revenues sufficient to cover MC.</p><p>(Calculus version for those interested: </p><p>Profit = P1∙ Q1 + P2 ∙Q2 – TC(Q1+Q2) with P1=P1(Q1), P2=P2(Q2)</p><p> where: P1 and P2 are prices in markets 1 and 2 and these depend on Q1 and Q2 (quantities sold in each market) respectively, TC() is the level of total cost which depends on total output produced: Q1 +Q2.</p><p>First order conditions for a profit maximum are then: </p><p>∂ Profit/∂Q1 = P1 + Q1∙∂ P1/∂Q1 - ∂TC/∂Q1 = 0 i.e. MR1 – MC = 0 </p><p>∂ Profit/∂Q2 = P2 + Q2∙∂ P2/∂Q2 - ∂TC/∂Q2 = 0 i.e. MR2 – MC = 0</p><p> so: MR1 = MR2 = MC when profits are maximized)</p><p>9 Example: Two Markets with Different Demand Curves</p><p>Market 1 demand: P1= 27.5-2.5Q1 so MR1=27.5 - 5Q1 Market 2 demand: P2= 40- 5Q2so MR2=40 - 10Q2</p><p>Marginal cost: MC = 1∙ (Q1+Q2) note: it depends on total output. </p><p>Algebraic solution?</p><p>Assuming it is worthwhile to produce in both markets the discussion </p><p> above tells you that: MR1 = MR2 = MC when the monopolist is maximizing profits. </p><p>So you could set: MR1= MR2 : 27.5 - 5Q1 =40 - 10Q2 (or 4Q2-2Q1 = 5)</p><p>Then use either MR1=MC or MR2=MC, lets use the latter: 40 - 10Q2 = (Q1 +Q2) (or 40-11Q2 = Q1)</p><p>Now you have 2 linear eqns in two unknowns Q1 and Q2. Solve!</p><p> e.g. use the last condition to replace Q1 in: 4Q2-2Q1 = 5 then solve for Q2. (Q2=3.27)</p><p> now find Q1 by substituting Q2=3.27 into: 27.5 - 5Q1 =40 - 10Q2 you get Q1=4.04</p><p>Now that you have Q1 and Q2 you can find P1 and P2 (just substitute the solutions to the quantities into the demand curves).</p><p>This gives: P1 = 27.5-2.5 (4.04) = 17.4 P2 = 40 -2.5 (3.27) = 23.65</p><p>10 - An alternative solution? solve for the combined MR curve in the above example then set combined MR=MC – you can then solve for Q1+Q2, once this is know you can calculate MR1 and MR2 and then Q1, Q2 then P1, P2. </p><p>- Combined MR is discontinuous: as long as MR>27.5 sells only in Market 2. - initially combined MR = 40-10Q </p><p>- When selling in both markets must sum MR1 and MR2 over quantities to get the combined MR curve.</p><p>How? Solve MR1 = 27.5 -5Q1 for Q1= (27.5-MR1)/5</p><p>Solve MR2 = 40-10Q2 for Q2= (40-MR2)/10</p><p>Now: MR1=MR2=MR along this segment. So add Q1+Q2:</p><p>Q1+Q2= ( 95-3 MR) /10</p><p>Solve for MR to get combined MR: </p><p>MR = [95-10 (Q1+Q2)]/3</p><p>(combined D-curve can be found the same way: sum across quantities at a given P)</p><p> then when maximizing profit: MR=MC</p><p>[95-10 (Q1+Q2)]/3 = Q1+Q2 so Q1+Q2=7.31 (as above)</p><p>- Possible outcomes in the two market model: </p><p>- Produce in both markets (as in the example)</p><p>- Produce only for one market (possible if MC is always above MR in one of the markets)</p><p>- Don’t produce at all (e.g. always have MC>40 in the example above).</p><p>11 - Note that the price charged will be higher in the market with least elastic demand.</p><p> define: P1 as price in market 1 and P2 as price in market 2</p><p>1 as the price elasticity of demand in market 1</p><p>2 as the price elasticity of demand in market 2.</p><p> when producing for both markets:</p><p>MR1 = MR2</p><p>P1 ( 1 + 1/ 1 ) = P2 ( 1 + 1/ 2 )</p><p>P1 = ( 1 + 1/ 2 )</p><p>P2 ( 1 + 1/ 1 )</p><p> e.g. if 2 =-2 and 1 =-3 then </p><p>P1/P2 = .5 / .67 < 1 so P1 < P2 </p><p>- Profit maximization: two-price monopolist does better charging different prices in the two markets unless price elasticities of demand are the same.</p><p>- consider charging a single price instead of two different prices: </p><p>- lower the price in the high price market: means selling output </p><p> for which MR2 <MC.</p><p>- raising the price in the low price market means not selling </p><p> some output for which MR1 > MC. </p><p>- profits must be lower when a single price is charged !</p><p>- a monopolist will typically want to separate its markets.</p><p>12 - The approach used to look at a monopolist in two markets generalizes to monopolists operating in more than two markets. </p><p>- Examples of this type of price discrimination: </p><p>- Student discounts (students have lower income and lower WTP on average).</p><p>- Senior discounts (more time on average to shop for bargains? Maybe lower income on average: lower WTP)</p><p>- Airfares “Saturday-night stayover” rates and business travellers.</p><p>- Price differences by location: could reflect costs but in some cases may largely be price discrimination.</p><p>- Price of same pharmaceuticals in poor and rich countries. </p><p>(see also Harford chapter on the Assignment 2 for examples)</p><p>13 Hurdle Models and 3 rd Degree Price Discrimination: </p><p>- A “hurdle” is placed in the buyers way in order to try and separate those with a higher willingness to pay from those with a lower willingness to pay.</p><p>Those who overcome the hurdle pay a lower price.</p><p>Those who do not overcome the hurdle pay a higher price.</p><p>- Hurdle is a “trick” to overcomes information problem: gets customers to reveal if they have higher or lower WTP.</p><p>- Key idea: </p><p>- those most sensitive to price (most elastic demand) will overcome the hurdle and pay a lower price;</p><p>- those least sensitive to price will not overcome the hurdle and will pay a higher price.</p><p>- typical price discrimination result.</p><p>- the hurdle is an example of “screening”: uncovers info about buyer’s WTP.</p><p>14 - Hurdle examples:</p><p> coupons and rebates (cost of time and who uses them); </p><p> hardcover vs. paperback books (who is willing to wait for the paperback?), </p><p> video game prices (on release vs. later);</p><p> sale pricing (who will wait for bargains?).</p><p> quality differences: have “high quality- high price” and “lower quality – low price version” of the good. </p><p>- This could raise profits if those with high WTP are also more likely to prefer high quality. </p><p> e.g. Intel 486 vs. 486SX processors (SX a “damaged” version of 486) IBM laser printer example (added chip to slow down inferior model)</p><p>- Practical difficulty? How to identify true price discrimination from price differences due to real quality differences? </p><p>15 Direct and Indirect 3 rd degree Price Discrimination</p><p>- Direct price discrimination: different pricing on the basis of observable characteristics of the buyer e.g. age of buyer, location. </p><p>- Indirect price discrimination: - price based on behaviour or choices of buyers that allow sellers to infer something about WTP. </p><p>- sellers might be able to induce buyers reveal that they have high or low WTP. </p><p>- Hurdle model is an example of indirect price discrimination: those willing to jump the hurdle reveal info on their WTP.</p><p>- Variation in product attributes:</p><p>- can you add characteristics that appeal to higher WTP people?</p><p> e.g. fancy coffee, “luxury” versions of everyday goods; are green or fair-trade goods examples of this?</p><p> i.e. appeal to people who are less price sensitive due to high income or due to concern about other attributes of the good.</p><p>16 Second-Degree Price Discrimination:</p><p>- The monopolist charges a schedule of prices with the price on extra units declining as the consumer buys more.</p><p> e.g. charge $5 for each of the first two units bought, $3 for each of the next two and $1 for any purchases over five units.</p><p>- price discrimination on the units bought by a given consumer but not across consumers.</p><p>- This can allow the monopolist to take advantage of differences in willingness to pay for various units of the good, </p><p> i.e., take advantage of demand curves for individual buyers being downward sloping. </p><p>- Allows the monopolist to capture more consumer surplus than the single price case but not as much as the perfectly discriminating monopolist.</p><p>- Example in diagrams: </p><p>- Start with demand curve for one buyer (one of many identical buyers?)</p><p>- Single-price monopoly solution: MR=MC say gives P1, Q1.</p><p>- Would the monopolist be willing to sell more units (given it has </p><p> charged P1 and sold Q1)? </p><p>- Treat like a single-price monopoly problem with new demand curve </p><p> equal to old minus Q1. Set MR2=MC.</p><p>- Generally can raise profits by selling additional units at a lower price</p><p>(P2): see diagram.</p><p>17 - Can do even better than this if recognize interdependence of first stage and second stage.</p><p> i.e. set P1 recognizing that it affects size of left-over market at the second stage. </p><p>- Could imagine extending this: charge a third, fourth, fifth etc. price for still more units.</p><p>- how many prices in the schedule? if complex pricing is costless to administer then move toward perfect price discrimination! </p><p>18 Two-Part Tariff or Two-Part Pricing:</p><p>- “Disneyland Dilemma”! W. Oi Quarterly Journal of Economics 1971.</p><p>- Text discussion of this type of scheme: pp. 135-136.</p><p>- Key aspect: two-part pricing (1) Fixed charge; and (2) marginal charge. </p><p>- Imagine an amusement park operator facing a typical downward sloping demand curve for rides. </p><p>- like the usual monopolist sets price and output of rides so that MR = MC (call the price P*)</p><p>- Say that at the single-price monopoly outcome a typical consumer has a typical demand curve for rides (downward-sloping).</p><p>- indicate consumer surplus when price is P* as area “A+B”. </p><p>- The operator can do still better by also charging an admission fee in addition to its per ride price. </p><p> i.e., this is “two-part pricing” or a “two-part tariff”.</p><p>- How much would the admission fee be?</p><p>- given the price per ride of P* the maximum entrance fee is area A+B. </p><p>- notice that the monopolist gets all the surplus: fee turns consumer surplus into producer surplus. </p><p>19 - Model above assumed that P* was set as if a single-price monopolist. </p><p>- If the firm knows that it will also charge an entry fee at what level will it set the price P*? </p><p>- The firm will want the efficient outcome (P**=MC) as this maximizes total surplus (the fee allows it to take all surplus).</p><p>- Disneyland? P**=0 (roughly the MC of a ride), entry fee only.</p><p>- Other examples of this type of arrangement? </p><p>- Cell phone packages: often a fixed fee plus charges based on usage.</p><p>- Electricity pricing: often a fixed fee plus charges per KwH.</p><p>- Club pricing. </p><p>20 Efficiency and Monopoly:</p><p>- Single-price Monopolist (see above): </p><p>- at profit maximizing outcome: Price > MC</p><p>- what someone will pay for one more unit of the good is greater than the extra resource cost: some extra consumer and producer surplus could be created by raising output. </p><p>- the monopoly outcome is inefficient.</p><p>- size of efficiency loss (deadweight loss, excess burden):</p><p>- area between height of demand curve and MC curve from output where MR=MC to where MC intersects demand curve.</p><p>- from an efficiency sense price is too high and output too low.</p><p>21 - Efficiency loss gives a justification for policies limiting monopoly power (anti-trust legislation: Canada: The Competition Act ).</p><p>- the political reason for regulation likely has more to do with the distributional consequences of monopoly. </p><p> i.e., high price and the transfer of consumer surplus to producers.</p><p>- Perfect price discrimination:</p><p>- no efficiency loss: monopolist produces up to where P = MC .</p><p>- distributional issue: all the surplus goes to the monopolist. </p><p>- Imperfect price discrimination:</p><p>- typically between the two extremes: smaller efficiency loss than single-price monopoly, larger than perfect discrimination case. </p><p>- Efficiency vs. equity:</p><p>- price discrimination enhances efficiency but seems inequitable.</p><p> i.e. different prices for different people. </p><p>- hurdle model: buyer pays a different price as they do not find it worthwhile to jump the hurdle (pays more by choice?)</p><p>22 Policy Response to Monopoly: </p><p>- A standard policy response to monopoly is to break it up or prevent it.</p><p>- Canada: Competition Bureau.</p><p> e.g. see Dec. 2010 waste services firm merger for example.</p><p>(http://www.competitionbureau.gc.ca/eic/site/cb-bc.nsf/eng/03324.html)</p><p>- What if it is a natural monopoly?</p><p>- with large economies of scale the market will always tend toward monopoly.</p><p>- the monopolist will produce where MR=MC</p><p>- there will be an efficiency loss. </p><p>- but given cost structure a competitive market cannot be created. </p><p>- Efficiency requires setting Price = MC.</p><p>- with a natural monopoly this will often involve making a loss.</p><p> e.g. consider cost structure: </p><p>Fixed cost and constant marginal cost:</p><p>TC = F + m Q F = fixed cost Q= output m = marginal cost</p><p>P = m then P < AC = (F/Q) + m (loss)</p><p>- with flat or falling MC setting price = MC (efficient outcome) will result in the firm making a loss. </p><p>23 - Some possible Policy Solutions? </p><p>- Public enterprise: </p><p>- government run monopolist. </p><p>- efficiency requires making a loss.</p><p>- how to cover this (taxes will create their own efficiency losses).</p><p>- incentive issues: will public enterprises be more badly run than private firms? </p><p> e.g. cost curves may be higher for public enterprises if they are less well run (another source of efficiency loss)</p><p>- see text discussion: pp. 421-423.</p><p>24 - Regulation:</p><p>- government regulates the private monopolist. </p><p> e.g., could control price: price ceiling could give efficiency could regulate rates of return (incentives here to inflate costs of investment)</p><p>- Contracting out: </p><p>- government specifies in detail what it wants provided and accepts bids from private firms to provide the good or service. </p><p>- Could avoid some of the problems of the public enterprise. </p><p>- “Detail”</p><p>Monopoly and Innovation: Some Considerations</p><p>- Does lack of competitive pressure discourage innovation? </p><p>(model of firm behaviour and this: if above is true the firm is not a profit maximizer)</p><p>- Does the existence of monopoly profits provide finance for innovation?</p><p>(role of financial markets: statement may be true if financial markets are inefficient and firm’s must finance expansion with own profits)</p><p>- Do monopoly profits provide other firms with an incentive to create alternatives to the monopoly good/service?</p><p>25 Should we care about monopoly?</p><p>- Concerns:</p><p>- Distribution and efficiency issues.</p><p>- Equity (fairness) issues and price discrimination. </p><p>- Possible innovation problems. </p><p>- Question of whether the government can do better? - regulation, public enterprise: better or not?</p><p>26</p>
Details
-
File Typepdf
-
Upload Time-
-
Content LanguagesEnglish
-
Upload UserAnonymous/Not logged-in
-
File Pages26 Page
-
File Size-