"The Macroeconomics of Happiness." (Pdf)

"The Macroeconomics of Happiness." (Pdf)

The Macroeconomics of Happiness Author(s): Rafael Di Tella, Robert J. MacCulloch and Andrew J. Oswald Source: The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 85, No. 4 (Nov., 2003), pp. 809-827 Published by: The MIT Press Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/3211807 Accessed: 25-11-2019 16:44 UTC JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at https://about.jstor.org/terms The MIT Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Review of Economics and Statistics This content downloaded from 206.253.207.235 on Mon, 25 Nov 2019 16:44:09 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms THE MACROECONOMICS OF HAPPINESS Rafael Di Tella, Robert J. MacCulloch, and Andrew J. Oswald* Abstract-We show that macroeconomic movements have omitted strong from effects economists' standard calculations of the cost on the happiness of nations. First, we find that there are clear microeco- of cyclical downturns. nomic patterns in the psychological well-being levels of a quarter of a million randomly sampled Europeans and Americans from In thespite 1970s of a longto tradition studying aggregate economic the 1990s. Happiness equations are monotonically increasing fluctuations, in income, there is disagreement among economists about and have similar structure in different countries. Second, movements in the seriousness of their effects. One view, associated with reported well-being are correlated with changes in macroeconomic vari- ables such as gross domestic product. This holds true after Keynes, controlling argues forthat recessions are expensive disruptions to the personal characteristics of respondents, country fixed the economiceffects, yearorganization of society. Recessions involve dummies, and country-specific time trends. Third, the paper establishes that recessions create psychic losses that extend beyond considerable the fall in losses-underutilization GDP of invested capacity, and rise in the number of people unemployed. These emotional losses are costs large. to those who lose their jobs, and distribu- Fourth, the welfare state appears to be a compensating tional force: unfairness. higher Adifferent view is adopted by real-business- unemployment benefits are associated with higher national well-being. cycle theorists. They argue that Keynesians overestimate the costs of business cycles: downturns follow booms, and I. Introduction business cycles do not affect the average level of economic activity. Given that individuals are optimizing, recessions NEWSPAPERS regularly report changes in macroeco- are desirable adjustments to productivity shocks. This nomic variables. It is also known that economic vari- means that the costs of business cycles are small-perhaps ables predict voters' actions and political outcomes (Frey only 0.1% of total consumption in the United States (Lucas, and Schneider, 1978). These facts suggest that aggregate 1987).3 Consequently, these economists have turned their economic forces matter to people. Yet comparatively little attention is to economic growth and away from fluctuations. known empirically about how human well-being is influ- Our paper derives a measure of the costs of an economic enced by macroeconomic fluctuations.1 When asked to eval- downturn that can be used in such debates. In doing so, the uate the cost of a business cycle downturn, most economists paper employs data of a kind more commonly found in the measure the small drop in gross domestic product. psychology literature. Collected in standard economic and This paper adopts a different approach. It begins withsocial surveys, the data provide self-reported measures of international data on the reported well-being levels of hun- well-being, such as responses to questions about how happy dreds of thousands of individuals. The paper's first finding and satisfied individual respondents are with their lives. We is that there are strong microeconomic patterns in the data, begin by showing that life-satisfaction regression equa- and that these patterns are similar in a number of countries. tions-where individuals' subjective well-being levels are Happiness data behave in a predictable way. We then showregressed on the personal characteristics of the respon- that, after controlling for the characteristics of people anddents-have a broadly common structure across countries. countries, macroeconomic forces have marked and statisti- A large set of personal characteristics has approximately the cally robust effects on reported well-being. GDP affects same a influence on reported happiness, regardless of where country's happiness. Furthermore, pure psychic costs from well-being questions are being asked. This regularity sug- recessions appear to be large. As well as the losses from gests a that happiness data contain potentially interesting fall in GDP, and the direct costs of recession to those falling information. unemployed, a typical business cycle downturn of one year's length would have to be compensated by giving each citizen-not just unemployed citizens-approximately II. Conceptual Issues $200 per year.2 This loss is over and above the GDP cost of From the outset, the paper has to face up to two concep- a year of recession. It is an indirect, or "fear," effect that is tual concerns. The first is caused by the approximately untrended nature of reported happiness [as noted by Richard Received for publication July 12, 2000. Revision accepted for publica- tion September 9, 2002. Easterlin (1974)]. For the usual unit-root reasons, we cannot * Harvard Business School, Princeton University, and University then of regress happiness on trended variables such as GDP. Warwick, respectively. This paper experiments with equations in which there are (i) For helpful comments, we thank James Stock (editor) as well as George Akerlof, Danny Blanchflower, Andrew Clark, Ben Friedman, Duncan year dummies, (ii) country-specific time trends, and (iii) Gallie, Sebastian Galiani, Julio Rotemberg, Hyun Shin, John Whalley, change-in-GDP and variables. The second conceptual problem seminar participants at Oxford, Harvard, and the 1997 NBER Behavioral is that variables such as GDP per capita, unemployment, and Macro Conference. The third author is grateful to the Economic and Social Research Council (macroeconomics program) for research support. The working paper version of this paper is "The Macroeconomics of Happi- 3 Even when market imperfections are introduced, the costs rise by only ness," Center for Economic Performance 19, (July 1997). a factor of 5, and they are significantly lower if borrowing is allowed: see 1 It is known that suicide rose markedly in the Great Depression, but Atkeson that and Phelan (1994). A different approach to measuring the costs of was probably too extreme an episode to allow any easy judgement. business cycles, using asset prices, is developed in Alvarez and Jermann 2 In 1985 U.S. dollars, which is the middle of our sample. (1999). The Review of Economics and Statistics, November 2003, 85(4): 809-827 ? 2003 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College and the Massachusetts Institute of Technology This content downloaded from 206.253.207.235 on Mon, 25 Nov 2019 16:44:09 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 810 THE REVIEW OF ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS inflation are not exogenous. These variables are influenced It is well known that individuals' answers to well-being by politicians' choices; their choices are shaped questions by reelec- can be influenced by order and framing effects tion probabilities; those probabilities in turn can dependwithin a onsurvey, and by the number of available answer the feeling of contentment among a country's categories citizens. (in A our main data set, there are only four). Apart further possible source of simultaneity is that happier from the people pragmatic defense that we are constrained by the may work harder and thus produce more output. data Itas iscollected, not some of these problems can be reduced by straightforward to find believable macroeconomic averaging instru- across large numbers of observations, and by the ments that can identify the well-being equation. Instead,inclusion theof country fixed effects in the macroeconomic paper experiments with different forms of lag structures, regressions. to Section IV describes our empirical strategy. attempt to see if movements in macroeconomic forces Section lead, V studies the relationship between well-being later on, to movements in well-being. data and national income per capita. The survey questions do not ask people whether they like economic booms. Traditionally, economists assume that it is sufficient to Instead, respondents are asked how happy they feel with pay attention to decisions. This is because people's choices their lives, and their collective answers can be shown- should reveal their preferences. More recently, however, it unknown to the respondents themselves-to move system- has been suggested that an alternative is to focus on expe- atically with their nation's GDP.4 In section VI we calculate rienced utility, a concept that emphasises the pleasures the effect of other macroeconomic variables,

View Full Text

Details

  • File Type
    pdf
  • Upload Time
    -
  • Content Languages
    English
  • Upload User
    Anonymous/Not logged-in
  • File Pages
    20 Page
  • File Size
    -

Download

Channel Download Status
Express Download Enable

Copyright

We respect the copyrights and intellectual property rights of all users. All uploaded documents are either original works of the uploader or authorized works of the rightful owners.

  • Not to be reproduced or distributed without explicit permission.
  • Not used for commercial purposes outside of approved use cases.
  • Not used to infringe on the rights of the original creators.
  • If you believe any content infringes your copyright, please contact us immediately.

Support

For help with questions, suggestions, or problems, please contact us