Understanding the Trade Imbalance and Employment Decline in U.S. Manufacturing

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Understanding the Trade Imbalance and Employment Decline in U.S. Manufacturing 2018 n Number 15 ECONOMIC Synopses https://doi.org/10.20955/es.2018.15 Understanding the Trade Imbalance and Employment Decline in U.S. Manufacturing Brian Reinbold, Research Associate Yi Wen, Assistant Vice President and Economist Why Does the U.S. Always Seem to Run a Trade Deficit? Figure 1 The answer to this question lies in economic develop- U.S. Trade Balance ment that occurred in the early 1970s. The United States— Percent of GDP the largest and most powerful economy after World War 2 II—abandoned the gold standard in 1971, which led to 1 0 the collapse of the Bretton Woods system. As a result, the 1 U.S. dollar became the most widely used currency world- 2 wide and the most popular foreign reserve along with U.S. 3 4 government securities. In fact, foreign holdings of U.S. Current Account Balance 5 Treasury securities started to increase in the early 1970s. Goods Balance More than 40 years later, by 2014, these holdings surpassed Services Balance 7 $6 trillion, rising from about 3 percent of total U.S. govern- 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 ment debt in 1970 to around 30 percent in recent years. SOURCE: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Haver Analytics, and authors’ calculations. Figure 2 Rising productivity caused labor-intensive U.S. Goods Trade Balance with Other Economies goods-producing firms to relocate abroad. Billions of Dollars 100 0 Many countries can issue debt in their own currency. –100 Why is the United States so different? First, it all goes back –200 to the Bretton Woods agreement in 1944 that selected the –300 1 –400 U.S. dollar as a global reserve currency. The chief feature –500 Canada & Mexico of the Bretton Woods system was the obligation of each –600 China country to adopt a monetary policy that maintained its –700 East Asia & Pacic –800 external exchange rates by tying its currency to gold. The World –900 United States, which controlled two-thirds of the world’s 1991 1995 1999 2003 2007 2011 2015 gold, insisted that the Bretton Woods system rest on both SOURCE: World Bank World Integrated Trade Solution and United Nations Comtrade gold and the U.S. dollar. Second, since the collapse of the Database. Bretton Woods system, much of international trade (such NOTE: East Asia & Pacic includes China. as oil) has been priced in U.S. dollars, fueling demand for the currency. the U.S. trade balance started to show persistent and grow- The collapse of the Bretton Woods system and the con- ing deficits—still seen today (Figure 1). tinued worldwide use of the U.S. dollar as both a medium Under the national accounting identity, national savings of exchange and a store of value have given the United (i.e., total output minus consumption and government States the ability to purchase goods from the world market spending) equals investment plus net exports. Trade deficits simply by printing money or issuing debt. As a result, the (negative net exports) therefore imply insufficient national United States is more likely to run trade deficits. Indeed, saving to finance national investment. So the U.S. gap just a few years after the Bretton Woods system ended, between saving and investment started to widen around Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis | research.stlouisfed.org ECONOMIC Synopses Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis | research.stlouisfed.org 2 Figure 3 Are Trade Deficits Responsible for the Decline of U.S. U.S. Labor Productivity in Goods, Services, and Construction Manufacturing Employment? Value Added per Worker (1960 = 100) Agriculture was the major employment sector in all 800 countries before the Industrial Revolution. But nowadays Goods Labor Productivity 700 the sector employs less than 2 percent of the total U.S. labor Services Labor Productivity 600 3 Construction Labor Productivity force. This drop in employment is due to the dramatic 500 increase in labor productivity in agriculture—fewer workers 400 can grow the same amount of food. This productivity 300 increase has freed up workers to move into the manufac- 200 turing sector since the mid-nineteenth century. 100 A similar phenomenon happened after WWII in the 0 manufacturing sector. Figure 3 shows that labor produc- 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 tivity in the goods manufacturing sector rose faster than SOURCE: Kehoe, Ruhl, and Steinberg (2018). in any other sector in the United States after WWII. This rapidly rising productivity freed up manufacturing labor the early 1970s, with the total gap (total cumulative trade to move to the service sector and caused labor-intensive deficit) rising to around $11 trillion in 2017.2 Foreign coun- goods-producing firms to relocate abroad. This process tries fund this debt by trading goods for U.S. securities, inevitably reduced U.S. manufacturing employment. Indeed, making the United States the largest debtor in the world. using a calibrated dynamic stochastic general equilibrium In other words, the United States is able to consume more model, economists Timothy Kehoe, Kim Ruhl, and Joseph goods than it produces and finance its investments by Steinberg (2018) show that the rapidly rising labor produc- borrowing from foreign countries. tivity in the goods manufacturing sector produced 85 per- cent of the employment reduction in that sector, while the Who Are the Major U.S. Creditors? rising U.S. trade deficit with the rest of the world explains 4 Initially, the countries facing postwar recovery, such as only the remaining 15 percent. Germany and Japan, were the counterparties to the U.S. Conclusion trade deficits and thus the primary U.S. creditors, but that designation gradually shifted to the emerging Asian Tigers Economic analysis suggests that a trade war with China by the early 1980s. Indeed, of the total U.S. goods trade can neither stop the decline in American manufacturing deficit, the East Asian and Pacific region alone accounted employment nor eliminate the U.S. trade deficit, but it for more than 80 percent in 1991 (Figure 2). could significantly reduce the welfare of American con- However, the Asian contribution to the U.S. goods trade sumers by making U.S. imports of Chinese goods more deficit has been steadily declining since 1991 and now expensive. Moreover, it could cause the United States to stands at around 65 percent, despite China’s rise as the lose its global leadership in free trade and globalization largest U.S. creditor—that is, the largest holder of U.S. and facilitate China’s rise as a world leader in trade and dollars and government securities. commerce. A better approach may be for policymakers to In other words, the rise of China since the late 1980s design policies that can ensure fair redistribution of the and especially early 2000s after joining the World Trade gains from free trade among American citizens and to Organization has not increased Asia’s trade surplus with reform the education system to prepare students for future the United States, but China has replaced other Asian econo- jobs that require knowledge of automation and artificial n mies as the primary U.S. creditor. That is, even though intelligence. China’s share of the total U.S. goods trade deficit has been increasing rapidly, from around 15 percent in 1991 to 45 percent around 2016, it has not increased Asia’s share of that deficit. ECONOMIC Synopses Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis | research.stlouisfed.org 3 Notes References 1 The Bretton Woods agreement decided the following: The U.S. dollar was Bureau of Labor Statistics. “Employment by Major Industry Sector.” Last established as an international reserve currency, the U.S. dollar was backed modified date: October 24, 2017; https://www.bls.gov/emp/ep_table_201.htm. by gold at a price of $35 per ounce, and any country could exchange dollars for gold (see Ghizoni, 2013). Ghizoni, Sandra Kollen. “Creation of the Bretton Woods System.” Federal Reserve History. Written as of November 22, 2013; 2 This idea follows from the national accounting identity that GDP is the sum https://www.federalreservehistory.org/essays/bretton_woods_created. of consumption, investment, government spending, and net exports. Gross savings is defined as GDP minus consumption and government spending. Kehoe, Timothy J.; Ruhl, Kim J. and Steinberg, Joseph B. “Global Imbalances Then by rearranging the national accounting identity with the definition of and Structural Change in the United States.” Journal of Political Economy, 2018, gross savings, we can see that net exports is savings minus investment. There- 126(21). fore, a nation runs a trade deficit when savings is less than investment and runs a trade surplus when savings is greater than investment. 3 See Bureau of Labor Statistics (2017). 4 See Kehoe, Ruhl, and Steinberg (2018). Posted on May 25, 2018 ISSN 2573-2420 © 2018, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Views expressed do not necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal Reserve System..
Recommended publications
  • Global Imbalances and the Asian Economies: Implications for Regional Cooperation
    Working Paper Series on Regional Economic Integration No. 4 Global Imbalances and the Asian Economies: Implications for Regional Cooperation by Barry Eichengreen August 2006 Office of Regional Economic Integration The ADB Working Paper Series on Regional Economic Integration focuses on topics relating to regional cooperation and integration in the areas of infrastructure and software, trade and investment, money and finance, and regional public goods. The Series is a quick-disseminating, informal publication that seeks to provide information, generate discussion, and elicit comments. Working papers published under this Series may subsequently be published elsewhere. Key words: Asia economies, global imbalances, international economics, economic integration, regional cooperation. JEL Classifications: F0, F4. Disclaimer: The views expressed in this paper are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views and policies of the Asian Development Bank or its Board of Governors or the governments they represent. The Asian Development Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this publication and accepts no responsibility for any consequence of their use. Use of the term “country” does not imply any judgment by the authors or the Asian Development Bank as to the legal or other status of any territorial entity. Global Imbalances and the Asian Economies: Implications for Regional Cooperation Barry Eichengreen University of California, Berkeley Revised, May 2006 Abstract: This paper asks how Asia should prepare for the disorderly correction of global imbalances. It recommends tightening monetary policy and allowing Asian currencies to appreciate as a way of achieving a better balance between internal and external demand. Leaving the overall level of demand unchanged requires that this monetary tightening be complemented by some relaxation of fiscal policy.
    [Show full text]
  • Global Imbalances Paper
    Global Imbalances: past, present and future Marcello de Cecco Scuola Normale Superiore di Pisa and LUISS Introduction After the inception and, hopefully, the passing of the most dangerous phase of the international financial crisis, economists have returned to the long favoured subject of global imbalances. Because of the outbreak of the crisis it had been momentarily set aside after it had been very fashionable since at least the late sixties and even more in the decades after the oil crisis and the demise of the Bretton Woods system. The issue had continued to be hotly debated also in the early years of the new millennnium. In what follows I shall try to look at global imbalances first in a historical perspective, in order to understand how we got where we are. I will then turn my attention to causal links between the formation of global imbalances and the outbreak of the international financial crisis. I will also consider the likelihood that global imbalances, after showing, because of the crisis, a sizeable decrease in size, may go up again in the near future. Within this context I will also analyse the problem of current account imbalances inside a monetary union, and the consequences for the union and for the rest of the international economic and financial system. “External positions of systemically important economies that reflect distortions or entail risks for the global economy” This is the definition of global balances economists Bracke, Bussiere, Fidora and Straub suggest in their 2006 ECB Occasional paper. It is an eminently acceptable one, as it underlines the principal features of global imbalances.
    [Show full text]
  • Mark Carney: the Evolution of the International Monetary System
    Mark Carney: The evolution of the international monetary system Remarks by Mr Mark Carney, Governor of the Bank of Canada, to the Foreign Policy Association, New York, 19 November 2009. * * * In response to the worst financial crisis since the 1930s, policy-makers around the globe are providing unprecedented stimulus to support economic recovery and are pursuing a radical set of reforms to build a more resilient financial system. However, even this heavy agenda may not ensure strong, sustainable, and balanced growth over the medium term. We must also consider whether to reform the basic framework that underpins global commerce: the international monetary system. My purpose this evening is to help focus the current debate. While there were many causes of the crisis, its intensity and scope reflected unprecedented disequilibria. Large and unsustainable current account imbalances across major economic areas were integral to the buildup of vulnerabilities in many asset markets. In recent years, the international monetary system failed to promote timely and orderly economic adjustment. This failure has ample precedents. Over the past century, different international monetary regimes have struggled to adjust to structural changes, including the integration of emerging economies into the global economy. In all cases, systemic countries failed to adapt domestic policies in a manner consistent with the monetary system of the day. As a result, adjustment was delayed, vulnerabilities grew, and the reckoning, when it came, was disruptive for all. Policy-makers must learn these lessons from history. The G-20 commitment to promote strong, sustainable, and balanced growth in global demand – launched two weeks ago in St.
    [Show full text]
  • Global Imbalances, National Rebalancing, and the Political Economy of Recovery
    WORKING PAPER Global Imbalances, National Rebalancing, and the Political Economy of Recovery Jeffry A. Frieden October 2009 This publication is part of CFR’s International Institutions and Global Governance program and has been made possible by the generous support of the Robina Foundation. The Council on Foreign Relations (CFR) is an independent, nonpartisan membership organization, think tank, and publisher dedicated to being a resource for its members, government officials, busi- ness executives, journalists, educators and students, civic and religious leaders, and other interested citizens in order to help them better understand the world and the foreign policy choices facing the United States and other countries. Founded in 1921, CFR carries out its mission by maintaining a diverse membership, with special programs to promote interest and develop expertise in the next generation of foreign policy leaders; convening meetings at its headquarters in New York and in Washington, DC, and other cities where senior government officials, members of Congress, global leaders, and prominent thinkers come together with CFR members to discuss and debate major in- ternational issues; supporting a Studies Program that fosters independent research, enabling CFR scholars to produce articles, reports, and books and hold roundtables that analyze foreign policy is- sues and make concrete policy recommendations; publishing Foreign Affairs, the preeminent journal on international affairs and U.S. foreign policy; sponsoring Independent Task Forces that produce reports with both findings and policy prescriptions on the most important foreign policy topics; and providing up-to-date information and analysis about world events and American foreign policy on its website, CFR.org.
    [Show full text]
  • Global Imbalances, Financial Crisis and Economic Recovery
    Global Imbalances, Financial Crisis and Economic Recovery Wonhyuk Lim Director and Vice President, Department of Competition Policy, Korea Development Institute (KDI) lobal current account imbalances, expressed as the bigger the disruption would be. The dynam- percent of world GDP, have narrowed consid- ics leading to the crisis was conceptualized as fol- Gerably since 2006. According to the IMF, how- lows: the build-up of current account deficits by ever, the quality of this adjustment leaves much to be the U.S. would shake investor confidence and lead desired. Most of the adjustment took place during to a sudden stop of capital inflows, which in turn the global financial crisis of 2008-09, reflecting lower would precipitate a large and swift fall of the U.S. demand in economies with external deficit. Whereas dollar and a steep rise in the U.S. interest rate and exchange rate adjustment played some role, policy risk premium. The resulting disruptions could lead adjustment contributed “disappointingly little”.1 to a deep recession.2 To resolve global imbalances, Hence the IMF prescribed a broadly unchanged it was recommended that countries with current set of policies to further reduce global imbalances: account surplus increase consumption and coun- 1) the two major surplus countries, China and Ger- tries with current account deficit increase national many, need more consumption and investment, savings, with requisite structural reforms. Policy respectively, 2) the major deficit economies, includ- recommendations also included exchange rate ad- ing the U.S., need to boost national savings through justment to correct “fundamental misalignment”.3 fiscal consolidation, 3) other deficit economies also need structural reforms to rebuild competitiveness.
    [Show full text]
  • The Size of Foreign Exchange Reserves
    The size of foreign exchange reserves Yavuz Arslan and Carlos Cantú Abstract This paper assesses the determinants of foreign exchange (FX) reserves in emerging market economies (EMEs). First, it reviews the drivers behind reserve accumulation and the metrics used to evaluate reserve adequacy. We argue that precautionary motives, at least until early 2000s, were the main drivers of reserves accumulation for most of the countries. However, more recently, goals related to monetary and exchange rate policies also play significant roles. Next, the paper evaluates the costs of holding reserves, both at the domestic and global levels. In particular, we highlight the low rate of return on reserves assets and valuation risks that EMEs face. We also discuss the possible role of higher reserves in reducing US long term interest rates. Finally, the paper discusses some supportive and alternative policies such as macroprudential policies and swap agreements, which could alleviate reliance on reserve accumulation. Keywords: Foreign exchange reserves, reserve adequacy, precautionary demand, export competitiveness JEL classifications: F3, F31, F36, F41 BIS Papers No 104 1 1. Introduction The foreign exchange (FX) reserves of emerging market economies (EMEs) have surged since the early 1990s. On average, the level reached almost 30% of GDP in 2018 from about 5% in 1990 (Graph 1). At the same time, cross-country differences are significant (Graph 1, right-hand panel). Even after the slowdown since 2010, Asian EMEs and oil exporters, notably Algeria and Saudi Arabia, hold the largest stocks relative to GDP. This paper discusses the determinants of the size of EME FX reserves. It first reviews the reasons for reserve accumulation.
    [Show full text]
  • Causes and Consequences of Global Imbalances: Perspective from Developing Asia
    ADB Economics Working Paper Series Causes and Consequences of Global Imbalances: Perspective from Developing Asia Charles Adams and Donghyun Park No. 157 | April 2009 ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 157 Causes and Consequences of Global Imbalances: Perspective from Developing Asia Charles Adams and Donghyun Park April 2009 Donghyun Park is Senior Economist, Macroeconomics and Finance Research Division, Economics and Research Department, Asian Development Bank, and Charles Adams is Visiting Professor, Lee Kuan Yew School of Public Policy, National University of Singapore. The authors wish to thank Ms. Gemma Estrada of Economics and Research Department, Asian Development Bank, for her excellent research assistance. Asian Development Bank 6 ADB Avenue, Mandaluyong City 1550 Metro Manila, Philippines www.adb.org/economics ©2008 by Asian Development Bank April 2009 ISSN 1655-5252 Publication Stock No.: The views expressed in this paper are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views or policies of the Asian Development Bank. The ADB Economics Working Paper Series is a forum for stimulating discussion and eliciting feedback on ongoing and recently completed research and policy studies undertaken by the Asian Development Bank (ADB) staff, consultants, or resource persons. The series deals with key economic and development problems, particularly those facing the Asia and Pacific region; as well as conceptual, analytical, or methodological issues relating to project/program economic analysis, and statistical data and measurement. The series aims to enhance the knowledge on Asia’s development and policy challenges; strengthen analytical rigor and quality of ADB’s country partnership strategies, and its subregional and country operations; and improve the quality and availability of statistical data and development indicators for monitoring development effectiveness.
    [Show full text]
  • Impact of the Covid-19 Crisis on Global Financial Imbalances
    Geopolitical, Social Security and Freedom Journal, Volume 3 Issue 2, 2020 Impact of the covid-19 crisis on global financial imbalances Valentina Fetiniuc International Institute of Management IMI-NOVA email: [email protected] Ivan Luchian International Institute of Management IMI-NOVA email: [email protected] DOI: 10.2478/gssfj-2020-0011 Abstract. Following the synthesis of theories related to the mechanisms of international financial crises, authors Kovalev and Paseko developed the Model of global imbalance synergy, which substantiates the idea of generating economic and financial crisis situations globally by manifesting the chain of different imbalances. The model starts from global monetary and demographic imbalances, which determine the imbalances between real and financial sector of global economy, as well as real and market values of transnational companies. Together they all lead to imbalances in the distribution of global wealth in industrially developed and developing countries, as well as imbalance between consumption and income in industrially developed countries. Studies in this area have demonstrated the viability and usefulness of this model. The current situation tends to make some clarifications in this model. First of all, it is about the onset of a pro-cyclical economic crisis in 2018, against the background of which in 2020 an economic crisis of a pandemic nature began. Secondly, the latter tends to exacerbate global imbalances, which may ultimately trigger a global financial crisis. The situation is exacerbated by global trade conflicts with negative consequences, continued currency clashes and inflated financial bubbles. This situation requires urgent remedial actions at the global level. Keywords : global imbalance, pandemic crisis, economic crisis, financial crisis 1.
    [Show full text]
  • Global Imbalances: a Job for the G20?
    Discussion Paper 18/2019 Global Imbalances: A Job for the G20? Roger A. Fischer Global imbalances: A job for the G20? Roger A. Fischer Bonn 2019 Discussion Paper / Deutsches Institut für Entwicklungspolitik ISSN (Print) 1860-0441 ISSN (Online) 2512-8698 Die deutsche Nationalbibliothek verzeichnet diese Publikation in der Deutschen Nationalbibliografie; detaillierte bibliografische Daten sind im Internet über http://dnb.d-nb.de abrufbar. The Deutsche Nationalbibliothek lists this publication in the Deutsche Nationalbibliografie; detailed bibliographic data is available in the Internet at http://dnb.d-nb.de. ISBN 978-3-96021-110-5 (printed edition) DOI:10.23661/dp18.2019 Printed on eco-friendly, certified paper Roger Fischer leads the G7/G20 division of Germany’s Federal Ministry for Economic Cooperation and Development (BMZ). This paper reflects only the author’s personal views and cannot be construed as indicating the positions of Germany’s Federal Government or any part thereof. Email: [email protected] Published with financial support from the Federal Ministry for Economic Cooperation and Development (BMZ). © Deutsches Institut für Entwicklungspolitik gGmbH Tulpenfeld 6, 53113 Bonn +49 (0)228 94927-0 +49 (0)228 94927-130 Email: [email protected] www.die-gdi.de Abstract Excessive imbalances between countries’ current accounts are significant for two very different reasons. First, they are objects of contention between the Group of Twenty (G20) countries, which use imbalances to try to force other countries to change their policies, and even to justify unilateral trade measures – thus making it harder for G20 members to reach consensus on other important issues. Second, imbalances are not always based on sound economic reasoning and excessive imbalances signal that the global economic system is malfunctioning: It cannot effectively transform available funds created by savings, credit or monetary expansion into consumption and productive investment.
    [Show full text]
  • Global Imbalances: Build-Up, Unwinding and Financial Aspects
    Bulletin de la Banque de France 220/6 - NOVEMBER-DECEMBER 2018 Economy and international financing Global imbalances: build-up, unwinding and financial aspects The 2007-09 financial crisis led to major corrections in global current accounts. However, “global imbalances” persist, raising concerns among economic policymakers. This article focuses on two key aspects of these imbalances. The first part describes how they have evolved over the recent period and how their correction has proved costly, given the required major adjustments in real exchange rates. The second part of the article provides detailed statistics on the size and composition of net and gross international investment positions. Due to the large size of gross positions, the income account has become more important for current account dynamics, contributing to the persistence of global imbalances. Antoine Berthou JEL codes Microeconomic and Structural Analysis Directorate F14, F32 Matthieu Bussière Monetary and Financial Analysis Directorate Laurent Ferrara, Sophie Haincourt, Francesco Pappadà and Julia Schmidt Economic Affairs and International Cooperation Directorate This article has benefited from excellent research assistance by Muriel Métais. Global current account imbalances 449 billion dollars (% of world GDP) size of the US current account deficit in 2017 United States Euro area Brazil Japan China Oil exporters United Kingdom India Rest of the world % of GDP Forecasts 3.5 2.5 euro area current account surplus in 2017 2.0 1.5 1.0 3x-4x 0.5 increase in the gross international investment positions 0.0 of the main advanced economies since 1995 -0.5 -1.0 -1.5 -2.0 -2.5 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 Source: IMF (World Economic Outlook, October 2018).
    [Show full text]
  • 3 on the Causes of Global Imbalances and Their Persistence: Myths, Facts and Conjectures
    3 On the causes of global imbalances and their persistence: Myths, facts and conjectures Joshua Aizenman UCSC and NBER This article discusses several myths related to the sources, desirability and sustainability of global imbalances, and their future. Higher volatility of economic growth, higher and more volatile risk premium, and demographic transitions towards aging populations and lower fertility rates imply that past patterns of global imbalances became even less sustainable following the end of the illusive great moderation. Myth: The dollar standard (i.e., the dominance of the dollar as the global currency) necessitates growing global imbalances, where the US runs current-account defi cits.1 Large current-accounts run by the US are not new, the US ran sizeable defi cits from the onset of the Bretton Woods system, thereby funding the growing demand for the dollar as a reserves currency. Not really. To illustrate, Figure 1 plots the US current-account/GDP defi cit and private fl ows of capital during 1960-2009. The decade averages of the US current-account defi cits/GDP are reported below the curves. During the 1960s, at a time when the dollar was the undisputed global currency, the US current account position was on average close to zero (or running small surpluses). The US current-account defi cits started growing in the mid 1980s, a trend magnifi ed during the 1990s, with defi cits reaching a peak of 6% in 2006. The fi gure shows the fallacy of regarding global imbalances as a necessary requisite and consequence of the dollar role as global currency.
    [Show full text]
  • Gold and the International Monetary System Rapporteur: André Astrow
    Gold and the International Monetary System Rapporteur: André Astrow Gold and the International Monetary System A Report by the Chatham House Gold Taskforce Rapporteur: André Astrow ISBN 9781862032606 Chatham House, 10 St James’s Square, London SW1Y 4LE T: +44 (0)20 7957 5700 E: [email protected] www.chathamhouse.org F: +44 (0)20 7957 5710 www.chathamhouse.org Charity Registration Number: 208223 9 781862 032606 Gold and the International Monetary System A Report by the Chatham House Gold Taskforce Rapporteur: André Astrow February 2012 www.chathamhouse.org Chatham House has been the home of the Royal Institute of International Affairs for ninety years. Our mission is to be a world-leading source of independent analysis, informed debate and influential ideas on how to build a prosperous and secure world for all. © The Royal Institute of International Affairs, 2012 Chatham House (The Royal Institute of International Affairs) in London promotes the rigorous study of international questions and is independent of government and other vested interests. It is precluded by its Charter from having an institutional view. The opinions expressed in this publication are the responsibility of the authors. All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic or mechanical including photocopying, recording or any information storage or retrieval system, without the prior written permission of the copyright holder. Please direct all enquiries to the publishers. The Royal Institute of International Affairs Chatham House 10 St James’s Square London SW1Y 4LE T: +44 (0) 20 7957 5700 F: + 44 (0) 20 7957 5710 www.chathamhouse.org Charity Registration No.
    [Show full text]