Nominal Gdp Targeting: an Optimal Rule for the West African Economic and Monetary Union?

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Nominal Gdp Targeting: an Optimal Rule for the West African Economic and Monetary Union? c COPYRIGHT by Moon Oulatta 2018 ALL RIGHTS RESERVED ii NOMINAL GDP TARGETING: AN OPTIMAL RULE FOR THE WEST AFRICAN ECONOMIC AND MONETARY UNION? by Moon Oulatta ABSTRACT This dissertation investigates the prospect of adopting a flexible exchange rate regime with the nominal gross domestic product (GDP) as the intermediate target for the conduct of monetary policy for the members of the West African Economic and Monetary Union (WAEMU). In the first chapter, we begin by assessing the choice of exchange rate regime based on three criteria: exchange rate volatility, exposure to real shocks, and institutional capacities. The current peg with the euro remains the de facto political choice for the WAEMU, but also a reliable option for ensuring monetary policy discipline and allaying risks of currency convertibility. However, we argue that exchange rate flexibility is increasingly becoming more viable due to the overall improvement in the central bank's operational and statistical capacities, the high degree of exposure to terms of trade shocks, and the recent change in the WAEMU's trade patterns away from Europe. Therefore, given the case for exchange rate flexibility, we examine the pros and cons of three types of flexible exchange rate regime: inflation targeting, monetary aggregate targeting, and nominal GDP targeting. The main conclusion is that while all three types of flexible exchange rate regime would provide a firm commitment to a nominal anchor, monetary aggregate targeting would be the most practical option to pursue, because monetary aggregate data are highly observable, prone to almost no revisions, and price stability would be guaranteed by preventing excessive money growth. Alternatively, given the poor growth performance realized in the last decade and increasing vulnerability to supply shocks (for example, falling commodity prices and drastic droughts), we argue that under the right circumstances (for example, when the economy is operating far below potential output), choosing a flexible exchange rate regime that allows monetary authorities to prioritize both employment and price stability such as nominal GDP targeting would be most desirable as compared to adopting a flexible exchange rate regime in which the intermediate target of monetary policy is to keep a monetary aggregate or the inflation rate iii on target. A commitment to stabilize nominal GDP would force the monetary authorities to prioritize employment in the short run without giving up on achieving price stability in the long run. In the second chapter, we examine the stabilizing properties of using nominal GDP as the inter- mediate target as compared to using the inflation rate, a monetary aggregate, or the exchange rate. We provide a contribution to Bhandari and Frankel's (2015) model by imposing a cost for data uncertainty into the central bank quadratic loss functions, especially under inflation targeting and nominal GDP targeting. First, we show that no precommitment to a nominal anchor leads to a suboptimal outcome. Then, we derive the optimal conditions to determine whether a precommitment to a nominal GDP target would minimize the variability of real output, inflation, and the nominal exchange rate more efficiently than a precommitment to an inflation target, a monetary aggregate target, or an exchange rate target. We draw three main conclusions from the result of the simulations. First, the exchange rate is the least optimal among the choices of nominal anchors considered for the WAEMU. Second, nominal GDP targeting minimizes the central bank's quadratic loss function in an open economy setting given some parameter values for nominal GDP data uncertainty. Third, monetary aggregate targeting is slightly more robust than inflation targeting and exchange rate targeting. In conclusion, the main policy recom- mendation is that the central bank should prioritize nominal GDP among the choices of nominal anchors. However, in the event of large nominal GDP data revisions or poor data quality, then the secondary option should be to commit to a monetary aggregate target. In the third chapter, we devise a strategy for implementing nominal GDP targeting for the WAEMU by taking into consideration the existing practical concerns of data revisions and the unavailability of quarterly estimates of aggregate nominal GDP. Given the macroeconomic structure of the WAEMU and the magnitude of the estimated shocks affecting the economy, we demonstrate that a monetary aggregate instrument is superior to an interest rate instrument for the WAEMU. Hence, we propose a money-based rule similar to McCallum's (1987) rule, where the central bank is to announce an annual target for nominal GDP growth and use the monetary base as the operational target. Given the discovery of a robust empirical link between aggregate nominal GDP and aggregate nominal trade (value of exports plus imports) and the availability of trade data on a high frequency with minor revisions, we propose to rely on quarterly estimates of nominal trade as a means to solve the existing data issues coming from large revisions and low frequency data. The proposal to rely on nominal trade as a means to approximate trends in nominal GDP emanates from the fact that nominal trade shocks explain about close to 85 percent of variation in nominal GDP growth every year and trade data can be made available on a quarterly basis. Therefore, relying on quarterly estimates of nominal trade iv would allow the central bank to detect and respond to nominal GDP fluctuations more accurately and on a timely basis. v ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS I want to show my sincere gratitude to the United States Department of Education. Doctor Park has built a strong foundation for me. I learned a great deal of advanced mathematical concepts from him. I am deeply graceful to Doctor Park. Doctor Blecker introduced me to advanced macroeconomics. I would be half of the student I am today without his teachings. One of the most important things I have learned from Doctor Blecker is the essence of perfection. I want to sincerely thank Doctor Blecker. Doctor Mathy has influenced me in every possible way and assisted me in all stages of the dissertation process. I want to thank my greatest inspiration, my father, Colonel Major Pierre Oulatta, a United States Army Command and General Staff college graduate and President of the National Security Committee of Cote d'Ivoire. I want to thank my mother, Maimouna Ciss´e,the Executive director of Great Mind Counseling and Wellness Center. I want to thank my God Jesus Christ for protecting me against all the odds and giving me the strength and the capacity to succeed in my program. I want to thank Jean Claude Nascimento for providing useful guidance. I want to thank Senior Economist Tidiane Kinda for his gracious help. I want to thank his excellence Mr. Sansan Hien, the director of policy forecasting and economic statistics at the Ministry of Economy and Finances of Cote d'Ivoire. I want to thank the director of research at American University (CTRL) Assen Assenov. I want to thank the hard-working people at the Center for Environmental Data Analysis (CEDA) for providing quality rainfall data. I want to thank my closest friends who supported me throughout the program, most all Robert Vainshtein and Alpha Barry. I want to officially dedicate this dissertation to the people Cote d'Ivoire and all the members of the West African Economic and Monetary Union, whom I love deeply. vi TABLE OF CONTENTS ABSTRACT . ii ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS . .v LIST OF TABLES . ix LIST OF FIGURES . xi CHAPTER 1. The Choice of Exchange Rate Regime for the WAEMU . .1 1.1 Introduction . .1 1.2 The West African Economic and Monetary Union . .6 1.2.1 The Institutional Background . .6 1.2.2 The Current Monetary Policy Framework . .7 1.2.3 Is the WAEMU an Optimal Currency Area? . 10 1.2.4 The Institutional Capacities of the BCEAO . 12 1.3 The Choice of Exchange Rate Regime . 14 1.3.1 Exchange Rate Volatility . 14 1.3.2 Real Shocks . 18 1.3.3 Institutional Capacities . 23 1.3.4 Which Exchange Rate Regime is Appropriate for the WAEMU? . 25 1.4 Alternative Types of Flexible Exchange Rate Regimes . 27 1.4.1 Monetary Aggregate Targeting . 27 1.4.2 Inflation Targeting . 30 1.4.3 Nominal GDP Targeting . 31 1.4.4 Which Flexible Exchange Rate Regime is Appropriate? . 33 2. The Stabilizing Properties of a Nominal GDP Rule . 37 vii 2.1 Introduction . 37 2.2 Literature Review . 38 2.3 Theoretical Framework . 39 2.3.1 The Closed Economy Framework . 40 2.3.2 The Open Economy Framework . 45 2.4 Simple AS-AD Model . 49 2.4.1 The Aggregate Supply Side . 50 2.4.2 The Aggregate Demand Side . 52 2.4.3 Comparative Statics . 54 2.4.4 Estimating Structural Parameters . 56 2.4.5 Data . 56 2.4.6 Empirical Results . 66 2.5 Case Studies . 74 2.5.1 Calibration Process . 74 2.5.2 Optimal Conditions . 76 2.5.3 Simulation Results . 77 2.6 Conclusion . 81 3. Implementing Nominal GDP Targeting for the WAEMU . 82 3.1 Introduction . 82 3.2 The Optimal Choice of Monetary Policy Instruments . 88 3.2.1 The Money Supply Instrument . 89 3.2.2 The Interest Rate Instrument . 90 3.2.3 Calibration Process . 91 3.2.4 Data . 92 3.2.5 Estimating the IS Equation . 92 3.2.6 Estimating the LM Equation . 93 3.2.7 Robustness check . 95 3.2.8 Which Instrument is Optimal? . 98 viii 3.3 The Importance of Relying on Nominal Trade Data for Implementing Nominal GDP Targeting . 100 3.3.1 Nominal Trade: Data Generating Process . 100 3.3.2 Nominal Trade: Data Composition . 101 3.3.3 Nominal Trade as a Proxy or Intermediate Target for Implementing Nominal GDP Targeting .
Recommended publications
  • O Robert Mundell Και Το Βραβείο Nobel Στα Οικονομικά
    SAE./No.178/April 2021 Studies in Applied Economics ROBERT MUNDELL, 1932-2021: AHEAD OF HIS TIME Miranda Xafa Johns Hopkins Institute for Applied Economics, Global Health, and the Study of Business Enterprise Robert Mundell, 1932-2021: Ahead of his Time By Miranda Xafa About the Series The Studies in Applied Economics series is under the general direction of Professor Steve H. Hanke, Founder and Co-Director of the Johns Hopkins Institute for Applied Economics, Global Health, and the Study of Business Enterprise ([email protected]). About the Author Miranda Xafa started her career at the International Monetary Fund in Washington in 1980 and moved on to senior positions in government and in the financial sector. In 1991-93 she served as chief economic advisor to Prime Minister Constantin Mitsotakis in Athens, and subsequently worked as a financial market strategist at Salomon Brothers and Citigroup in London. After serving as a member of the IMF’s Executive Board in 2004-09, she is now a senior scholar at the Centre for International Governance Innovation (CIGI). She holds a Ph.D. in Economics from the University of Pennsylvania and has taught economics at the University of Pennsylvania and Princeton University. 1 I met Bob Mundell in Washington in 1982, when I was already working at the International Monetary Fund, at a conference on the international monetary system. My first impression was the absolute confidence with which he expressed his views. When one of the participants in his panel claimed that the data did not confirm his views, he responded: "If the data do not confirm my views, then the data are wrong." I had the chance to follow his life and career, and to participate in the conferences he organized and chaired in the last two decades in his beloved Palazzo Mundell in Tuscany where he lived.
    [Show full text]
  • Monetary Policy and Open Market Operations in 1983
    Monetary Policy And Open Market Operations In 1983 Monetary policy in 1983 sought to provide for a sus- and the continued decline in inflation contributed to tained expansion in economic activity within a framework greater interest rate stability than in other recent years. of continuing progress against inflation. Given the The Committee in 1983 had to deal with institutional background of substantial economic and institutional changes that affected the monetary aggregatesand their change, this involved careful balancing of the need for relationships to ultimate economic variables to an sufficient liquidity to foster the moderate recovery which uncertaindegree. Already during 1982, income velocities appearedto be emerging at the year's outset, along with had deviated substantially from past patterns. Ongoing the continuing need to maintain monetary discipline. The financial innovation, deregulation, and economic change measurement of liquidity itself was difficult in the light suggested that velocity patterns in 1983 were likely to of marked changes in the composition of M-1 and M-2 continue to diverge significantly from past experience. and uncertainty about their relationships to economic The Committee concluded that the relation between activity. money and credit and the economy would have to As the year progressed, the economic recovery sur- remain under review in 1983. The Committee continued passed expectationswhile the pace of inflation remained to specify growth ranges for money and credit as subdued. Wage increases continued to moderate, required by the Full Employment and Balanced Growth reducing cost pressures appreciably, while productivity (Humphrey-Hawkins) Act. But it sought to achieve its continued the rebound that had begun in 1982.
    [Show full text]
  • A Century of Central Banking: What Have We Learned? Jerry L
    A Century of Central Banking: What Have We Learned? Jerry L. Jordan All of us who are interested in the century-long experience of cen- tral banking in the United States owe a great debt to Allan Meltzer. His several-years-long efforts gave us over 2,000 pages of careful doc- umentation of decisionmaking in the Federal Reserve for the first 75 years (Meltzer 2003, 2010a, 2010b). The first score of years trans- formed a lender-of-last-resort, payments processor, and issuer of uni- form national currency into a full-fledged central bank with discretionary authority to manage a fiat currency. Even in the mid-1930s, then Senator Carter Glass declared that we did not have a central bank in the United States. However, legis- lation in 1933 and 1935 had institutionalized the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), which had previously been an informal coordinating committee. In an interview several years before his death, Milton Friedman was asked about any regrets in his long career. He replied that he wished he had paid more attention early on to what Jim Buchanan had been saying about the behavior of politicians and bureaucrats (Friedman 2003). Any discussion about any institution of govern- ment can be fruitful only in the context of the public-choice ele- ments of decisionmaking by individuals who occupy policymaking positions. For the past century, the economic theories of Cato Journal, Vol. 34, No. 2 (Spring/Summer 2014). Copyright © Cato Institute. All rights reserved. Jerry L. Jordan is former President of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
    [Show full text]
  • Multi0page.Pdf
    Africa Region Working Paper Series ( Number16 16 2 7 (f 0 Public Disclosure Authorized Choice of ExchangeRate, Regimes for DevelopingCountries Fahrettin Yagci Public Disclosure Authorized April2001 Public Disclosure Authorized 0 0>.L 0C Public Disclosure Authorized Choice Of Exchange Rate Regimes For Developing Countries April 2001 Africa Region Working Paper Series No. 16 Abstract The choice of an appropriate exchange rate regime for developing countries has been at the center of the debate in international finance for a long time. What are the costs and benefits of various exchange rate regimes? What are the determinants of the choice of an exchange rate regime and how would country circumstances affect the choice? Does macroeconomic performance differ under alternative regimes? How would an exchange rate adjustment affect trade flows? The steady increase in magnitude and variability of international capital flows has intensified the debate in the past few years as each of the major currency crises in the 1990s has in some way involved a fixed exchange rate and sudden reversal of capital inflows. New questions include: Are pegged regimes inherently crisis-prone? Which regimes would be better suited to deal with increasingly global and unstable capital markets? While the debate continues, there are areas where some consensus is emerging, and there are valuable lessons from earlier experience for developing countries. This note provides a review of the main issues in selecting an appropriate regime, examines where the debate now stands, and summarizes the consensus reached and lessons learned from recent experience. Authors' Affiliation and Sponsorship Fahrettin Yagci Lead Economist, AFTM1, The World Bank E-mail: [email protected] THE WORKINGPAPER SERIES The Africa Region WorkingPaper Seriesexpedites dissemination of appliedresearch and policy studies with potential for improvingeconomic performance and social conditions in Sub-SaharanAfrica.
    [Show full text]
  • Sweden's Monetary Internationalization Under the Silver
    Sweden’s Monetary Internationalization under the Silver and Gold Standards, 1834 – 1913 Anders Ögren∗ EHFF – Institute for Research in Economic and Business History at the Stockholm School of Economics and HTÉ EconomiX at Université de Paris X – Nanterre Keywords: Balance of Payments; Central Bank Reserves; Foreign Debt; Gold Standard; Monetary Base; Monetary Discipline; Monetary Policy; Money Supply; Silver Standard ABSTRACT The central bank’s possibility to sustain the specie standard was largely affected by both the financial development and its internationalization. The increased foreign debt denominated in foreign currencies forced the central bank to engage in more disciplinary monetary policy. The developed banking system worked in two ways: 1) increased public wealth in the banking system allowed a more relaxed discipline but 2) the commercial banks’ supply of liquidity through note issuance allowed the central bank to strengthen monetary discipline. The international economy developed as a credit economy and this international credit economy led to more flexible monetary policy. This affected the working of the adjustment mechanism where domestic prices simultaneously followed changes in the domestic money supply and in international prices. Thus the international integration made both prices and money supply grow in harmony over the borders. JEL: E42; E50; F33; N13; N23 ∗ E-mail: [email protected]. I worked on this paper during my time as a visiting researcher at the Stern School of Business, New York University. Consequently I am very grateful to my host Richard Sylla and all my colleagues there, in particular Robert E. Wright. I would also like to thank Ludovic Desmedt, Richard S.
    [Show full text]
  • Impact of Cost-Push and Monetary Factors on GDP Deflator: Empirical Evidence from the Economy of Pakistan
    www.sciedu.ca/ijfr International Journal of Financial Research Vol. 2, No. 1; March 2011 Impact of Cost-Push and Monetary Factors on GDP Deflator: Empirical Evidence from the Economy of Pakistan Zahoor Hussain Javed (Corresponding author) Department of Economics, GC University Allama Iqbal Road, Faisalabad, Pakistan Tel: +92-300-650-1785 E-mail: [email protected] Muhammad Farooq Assistant Professor, Department of Sociology, GC University Faisalabad, Pakistan. E-mail:[email protected] Maqsood Hussain Assistant Professor of Agricultural, University of Agricultural Faisalabad, Pakistan. Abdur-Rehman Shezad Lecture in Rural Sociology, University of Agricultural Faisalabad, Pakistan Safder Iqbal Lecturer in Economics, GC University Faisalabad, Pakistan. Shama Akram (Note 1) Department of Economics, GC University Faisalabad, Pakistan Received: August 30, 2010 Accepted: February 11, 2011 doi:10.5430/ijfr.v2n1p57 Abstract The central objective of this paper is to find the validity of cost-push and monetary factors on GDP deflator through empirical analysis. The empirical analysis has been conducted by using the technique of Ordinary Least Square using annual data for the period from 1971-72 to 2006-07. Before applying OLS the stationarity of the data was checked by Augmented Dickey Fuller (ADF) test. Regression analysis proves that both cost-push and monetary factors are influenced on wholesale price index. The monetary variables have significant impact on GDP deflator.. There is no single remedy to control the raise of wholesale price index. Government should adopt multipurpose strategy such as improvement in tax and revenue structure, improving fiscal and monetary discipline, removing supply side disruptions, eradication of anti-competitive market practice.
    [Show full text]
  • Debt, Money and Mephistopheles: How Do We Get out of This Mess?
    DEBT, MONEY AND MEPHISTOPHELES: HOW DO WE GET OUT OF THIS MESS? ADAIR TURNER CASS BUSINESS SCHOOL 6th February 2013 It is five and a half years since the financial crisis began in summer 2007 and four and a half years since its dramatic intensification in autumn 2008. It was clear from autumn 2008 that the economic impact would be large. But only slowly have we realised just how large: all official forecasts in spring 2009 suggested a far faster economic recovery than was actually achieved in the four major developed economies – the US, Japan, the Eurozone and the UK. UK GDP is now around 12% below where it would have been if we had continued the pre-2007 trend growth rate: and latest forecasts suggest that the UK will not return to 2007 levels of GDP per capita until 2016 or 2017. In terms of the growth of prosperity this is truly a lost decade. This huge harm reflects the scale of pre-crisis financial folly – above all the growth of excessive leverage - and the severe difficulties created by post-crisis deleveraging. And failure to foresee either the crisis or the length of the subsequent recession reflected an intellectual failure within mainstream economics – an inadequate focus on the links between financial stability and macroeconomic stability, and on the crucial role which leverage levels and cycles play in macroeconomic developments. We are still crawling only very slowly out of a very bad mess. And still only slowly gaining better understanding of the factors which got us there and which constrain our recovery.
    [Show full text]
  • Monetary Policy in the Great Depression and Beyond: the Sources of the Fed’S Inflation Bias
    Upjohn Institute Press Monetary Policy in the Great Depression and Beyond: The Sources of the Fed’s Inflation Bias David C. Wheelock Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Chapter 5 (pp. 127-170) in: The Economics of the Great Depression Mark Wheeler, ed. Kalamazoo, MI: W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research, 1998 DOI: 10.17848/9780585322049.ch5 Copyright ©1998. W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research. All rights reserved. 5 Monetary Policy in the Great Depression and Beyond The Sources of the Fed©s Inflation Bias David C. Wheelock Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis On August 15, 1971, President Nixon announced his "New Eco nomic Policy." Nixon's plan included two features that reflected on the state of American monetary policy. First, to combat inflation, Nixon imposed wage and price controls; and, second, in response to Amer ica's long-running and worsening international payments deficit, Nixon suspended convertibility of the dollar into gold. Both policies were intended to be temporary. Wage and price controls were tempo rary, but the gold window appears to be permanently shut, and the dol lar has floated against other currencies since 1973. The imposition of wage and price controls and suspension of dollar convertibility reflected the failure of U.S. monetary policy to control inflation under the prevailing international monetary regime—the Bret- ton Woods System. Although Bretton Woods was at its heart a gold standard, it did not impose the same level of discipline on monetary policy that the pre-war gold standard had. Under the classical gold standard, market-driven gold outflows would limit inflationary money supply growth and provide long-run price stability.
    [Show full text]
  • Reserves, Money Supply and Prices: the International Adjustment Mechanism in Sweden Under the Silver and Gold Standards, 1834 - 1913
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Ögren, Anders Working Paper Reserves, money supply and prices: The international adjustment mechanism in Sweden under the silver and gold standards, 1834 - 1913 SSE/EFI Working Paper Series in Economics and Finance, No. 544 Provided in Cooperation with: EFI - The Economic Research Institute, Stockholm School of Economics Suggested Citation: Ögren, Anders (2003) : Reserves, money supply and prices: The international adjustment mechanism in Sweden under the silver and gold standards, 1834 - 1913, SSE/EFI Working Paper Series in Economics and Finance, No. 544, Stockholm School of Economics, The Economic Research Institute (EFI), Stockholm This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/56265 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence.
    [Show full text]
  • Monetary Policy and Sovereign Risk in Emerging Economies (Nk-Default)
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MONETARY POLICY AND SOVEREIGN RISK IN EMERGING ECONOMIES (NK-DEFAULT) Cristina Arellano Yan Bai Gabriel P. Mihalache Working Paper 26671 http://www.nber.org/papers/w26671 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 January 2020 We thank our discussants Luigi Bocola, Satyajit Chatterjee, Giancarlo Corsetti, Juan Carlos Hatchondo, Radek Paluszynski, and Vivian Yue for insightful comments and suggestions. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, the Federal Reserve System, or the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2020 by Cristina Arellano, Yan Bai, and Gabriel P. Mihalache. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Monetary Policy and Sovereign Risk in Emerging Economies (NK-Default) Cristina Arellano, Yan Bai, and Gabriel P. Mihalache NBER Working Paper No. 26671 January 2020 JEL No. E52,F34,F41 ABSTRACT This paper develops a New Keynesian model with sovereign default risk (NK-Default). We focus on the interaction between monetary policy, conducted according to an interest rate rule that targets inflation, and external defaultable debt issued by the government. Monetary policy and default risk interact since both affect domestic consumption, production, and inflation. We find that default risk amplifies monetary frictions and generates a tension for monetary policy, which increases the volatility of inflation and nominal rates.
    [Show full text]
  • English -.08 .33 (-.15) (.68) Relig
    WPS3786 Fiscal Decentralization and Fiscal Performance Anwar Shah Public Disclosure Authorized Abstract A resurgence of recent interest in fiscal federalism has been a source of concern among macro stabilization experts. They argue that a decentralized fiscal system poses a threat to macro stability as it is incompatible with prudent monetary and fiscal management. This paper addresses these concerns by taking a simple neo-institutional economics cum econometric analysis perspective. This analysis enables the paper to conclude that, contrary to a common misconception, fiscal decentralization is associated with improved fiscal performance and better functioning of internal common market Public Disclosure Authorized Fiscal policy coordination represents an important challenge for federal systems. In this context, fiscal rules and institutions provide a useful framework but not necessary a solution to this challenge. Fiscal rules binding on all levels can help sustain political commitment in countries having coalitions or fragmented regimes in power. Coordinating institutions help in the use of moral suasion to encourage a coordinated response. Industrialized countries experiences also show that unilaterally imposed federal controls and constraints on sub-national governments typically do not work. Instead, societal norms based on fiscal conservatism such as the Swiss referenda and political activism of the electorate play important roles. Ultimately capital markets and bond-rating agencies provide more effective discipline on fiscal policy. In this context, it is important not to backstop state and local debt and not to allow ownership of the banks by any level of government. Transparency of the budgetary process and institutions, accountability to the electorate and general availability of comparative data encourages fiscal discipline.
    [Show full text]
  • Nominal GDP Targeting for Developing Countries
    Nominal GDP Targeting for Developing Countries Pranjul Bhandari and Jeffrey Frankel* Harvard Kennedy School Jan. 5 Forthcoming, Research in Economics (Elsevier), September 2017 Abstract Interest in nominal GDP (NGDP) targeting has come in the context of large advanced economies. Developing countries are better suited for it, however, in light of big supply shocks and terms of trade shocks, such as monsoon rains and oil import price shocks in the case of India. Under annual inflation targeting (IT), the full impact of adverse supply shocks is felt as lost real GDP. NGDP targeting automatically accommodates such shocks, while retaining the advantage of anchoring expectations. We derive the condition under which NGDP targeting would dominate other regimes such as annual IT, to achieve objectives of output and price stability. We estimate key parameters for the case of India and conclude that the condition may indeed hold. JEL numbers: F41, E52 key words: central bank, developing, emerging markets, GDP, income, India, inflation, IT, monetary policy, monsoon, nominal, shock, supply, target, terms of trade * corresponding author: [email protected] Harvard University, 79 JFK St., Cambridge MA 02138 1 617 496-3834 1 Nominal GDP Targeting for Developing Countries India’s central bank has contemplated a move from its multi-indicator monetary policy approach, towards a simple credibility-enhancing nominal rule. It seems to favor a flexible inflation target, which it hopes will help lower inflation expectations that have been high and sticky since 2010.1 In the paper we evaluate nominal GDP (NGDP) as an alternative monetary policy target for a country like India, especially in the face of the large supply shocks that it faces.2 We outline a simple model to compare NGDP targeting with other nominal rules.
    [Show full text]