Policy Brief 16-1: the US Phillips Curve: Back to the 60S?

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Policy Brief 16-1: the US Phillips Curve: Back to the 60S? Policy Brief NUMBER PB16-1 JANUARY 2016 Each of the last three conclusions presents challenges for The US Phillips Curve: the conduct of monetary policy. Wisdom gained from the expe- Back to the 60s? rience of the 1960s and later will be needed. A BRIEF LITERATURE REVIEW Olivier Blanchard Th is Policy Brief extends Blanchard, Cerutti, and Summers Olivier Blanchard joined the Peterson Institute for International (2015), where we examined the evolution of the relation between Economics as the fi rst C. Fred Bergsten Senior Fellow in October 2015. In infl ation and unemployment for 20 advanced economies. Th at 2008, he took a leave of absence to be the economic counselor and director paper builds in turn on chapter 3 in the IMF World Economic of the Research Department of the International Monetary Fund. He remains Robert M. Solow Professor of Economics emeritus at MIT. Outlook (2013) on the same topic. Our conclusions mostly coin- cide with the empirical conclusions of the two closest papers we © Peterson Institute for International Economics. All rights reserved. know of on this topic, Ball and Mazumder (2011) and Kiley (2015) (which includes a review of other papers). Th e behavior of infl ation since the global fi nancial crisis appears puzzling to many. To cite Paul Krugman (2015): “If infl ation AN ECONOMETRIC EXERCISE had responded to the Great Recession and aftermath the way it did in previous slumps, we would be deep in defl ation by now: Since the estimation of the US Phillips curve by Paul Samuelson we aren’t.” and Robert Solow, macroeconomists have learned, often pain- With this in mind, this Policy Brief ree xamines the behavior fully, that while low unemployment creates infl ation pressure, of infl ation and unemployment. It reaches four conclusions: the form of the relation can change and has changed over time. Low unemployment still pushes infl ation up; high unem- To examine its evolution, we estimated the following specifi ca- ployment pushes it down. Put another way, the US Phillips tion in Blanchard, Cerutti, and Summers (2015): curve is alive. (I wish I could say “alive and well,” but it * e would be an overstatement: Th e relation has never been STtttt ()uu OS tt (1)* OS tt1 PSH tmtt (1) very tight.) e SDESKttttt * 1 (2) Infl ation expectations, however, have become steadily more anchored, leading to a relation between the unemployment where t is headline consumer price infl ation (defi ned as quar- * rate and the level of infl ation rather than the change in infl a- terly infl ation, annualized), ut is the unemployment rate, ut is e tion. In this sense, the relation resembles more the Phillips the natural rate, t is long-term infl ation expectations, *t–1 is curve of the 1960s than the accelerationist Phillips curve of the average of the last four quarterly infl ation rates, mt is import the later period. price infl ation relative to headline infl ation, and the parameters , , , , , and the natural rate u * follow constrained Th e slope of the Phillips curve, i.e., the eff ect of the unem- t t t t t t random walks. ployment rate on infl ation given expected infl ation, has Th e fi rst equation specifi es the Phillips curve. Infl ation substantially declined. But the decline dates back to the depends on both expected long-term infl ation and past infl a- 1980s rather than to the crisis. Th ere is no evidence of a tion. Th e coeffi cient on past infl ation refl ects the dependence of further decline during the crisis. short-term infl ation expectations on past infl ation as well as the Th e standard error of the residual in the relation is large, direct eff ects of past infl ation on current infl ation. Infl ation also especially in comparison to the low level of infl ation. depends on the deviation of the unemployment rate from the 1750 Massachusetts Avenue, NW Washington, DC 20036 Tel: (202) 328-9000 Fax: (202) 328-5432 www.piie.com NUMBER PB16-1 JANUARY 2016 natural rate, as well as on the relative price of imports. Th e second Th e main results are presented in the three fi gures below. equation (which was not estimated in the Blanchard, Cerutti, and (For lack of space, results on the evolution of the natural rate Summers paper) captures the dependence of long-term expected are not presented here. Th e data suggest a slow decline in the infl ation on lagged infl ation. To capture the evolution of the two natural rate by about 1 percentage point since the early 1980s.) relations over time, the slope of the Phillips curve, the coeffi cients Figure 1 shows the evolution of , the weight of long-term on long-term infl ation expectations in the Phillips curve and on expectations in the Phillips curve. It shows how, after going lagged infl ation in the expectation equation, the intercept of the down in the 1970s, it has steadily gone up since the mid-1980s, expectation equation, and the natural rate of unemployment, are and is now close to one. Equivalently, the weight of past infl a- allowed to follow random walks. (Estimation is done using quar- tion, (1 – ), has steadily decreased over time. terly data since 1960. Data sources, and details of estimation for Figure 2 shows the evolution of t , the coeffi cient refl ecting the fi rst equation, are given in Blanchard, Cerutti, and Summers.) the eff ect of past infl ation on long-term expected infl ation. After Figure 1 The anchoring of expectations (λ) 1.0 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 1961 1965 1969 1973 1977 1981 1985 1989 1993 1997 2001 2005 2009 2013 Note: Dotted blue lines show +/–1 standard deviation. Source: Blanchard, Cerutti, and Summers (2015). Figure 2 The anchoring of long-term expectations (β) 0.30 0.25 0.20 0.15 0.10 0.05 0 –0.05 1961 1965 1969 1973 1977 1981 1985 1989 1993 1997 2001 2005 2009 2013 Note: Dotted blue lines show +/–1 standard deviation. Source: Data are from figure 1. 2 NUMBER PB16-1 JANUARY 2016 Figure 3 The decrease in the slope of the Phillips curve (θ) 1.2 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 1961 1965 1969 1973 1977 1981 1985 1989 1993 1997 2001 2005 2009 2013 Note: Dotted blue lines show +/–1 standard deviation. Source: Blanchard, Cerutti, and Summers (2015). increasing in the 1970s, it decreased in the 1980s, and has been the condition that keeping infl ation constant delivers the best close to zero since the late 1980s. unemployment rate policy can deliver. Figures 1 and 2 together suggest that infl ation now depends Results vary slightly, depending on the exact choice of mostly on long-term expected infl ation rather than past infl a- variables and the exact specifi cation. Some specifi cations, using tion, and that long-term expected infl ation in turn depends little diff erent measures of infl ation, give a slightly larger slope, a on past infl ation. Th is implies that the Phillips curve relation is slightly higher value for (see Ball and Mazumder 2011 and now close to a level-level relation, with the level of the infl ation Kiley 2015). But the three evolutions shown in the previous rate relative to stable long-term expected infl ation depending fi gures appear robust. Th ey have important implications for the on the level of the unemployment rate. conduct of monetary policy. Figure 3 shows the evolution of t , the slope of the Phillips curve. Th e slope increased from the 1960s until the late 1970s, THE END OF THE ACCELERATIONIST CURSE? then steadily decreased until the late 1980s and has remained roughly constant and low since then. Perhaps surprisingly, given One of the most dramatic implications of the accelerationist the relevance of an eff ective zero lower bound on nominal wage Phillips curve is that every boom must be followed by an equal decreases (Daly and Hobijn 2014), there is no evidence that the size bust. Or, more accurately, if infl ation is going to remain slope has decreased further in the crisis. Given expected infl a- constant in the long run, any negative unemployment gap must tion, a decrease in the unemployment rate led to an increase eventually be off set by an equal sum of positive unemployment in infl ation of 0.7 percent in the mid-1970s. Th e eff ect is now gaps later: closer to 0.2 percent. Various explanations have been off ered T for this evolution. Th e most convincing is that, as the level ()[()uu ()0] uu SStt 10 T S T S¦ (3) of infl ation has decreased, wages and prices are changed less 0 often, leading to a smaller response of infl ation to labor market Th is implication disappears when (1 – ), the coeffi cient conditions. (In the Calvo formalization of price stickiness, for on lagged infl ation, is less than one, and a fortiori when, as example, the slope coeffi cient is roughly proportional to p2, appears to be the case today, (1 – ) is close to zero. In this case, where p is the probability that a price will be changed in a given a boom will be associated with higher infl ation, but infl ation period.) will decrease as unemployment returns to the natural rate, and Th e last relevant result is that the fi t of the relation remains there is no need for the boom to be followed by a bust.
Recommended publications
  • Estimating the Effects of Fiscal Policy in OECD Countries
    Estimating the e®ects of ¯scal policy in OECD countries Roberto Perotti¤ This version: November 2004 Abstract This paper studies the e®ects of ¯scal policy on GDP, in°ation and interest rates in 5 OECD countries, using a structural Vector Autoregression approach. Its main results can be summarized as follows: 1) The e®ects of ¯scal policy on GDP tend to be small: government spending multipliers larger than 1 can be estimated only in the US in the pre-1980 period. 2) There is no evidence that tax cuts work faster or more e®ectively than spending increases. 3) The e®ects of government spending shocks and tax cuts on GDP and its components have become substantially weaker over time; in the post-1980 period these e®ects are mostly negative, particularly on private investment. 4) Only in the post-1980 period is there evidence of positive e®ects of government spending on long interest rates. In fact, when the real interest rate is held constant in the impulse responses, much of the decline in the response of GDP in the post-1980 period in the US and UK disappears. 5) Under plausible values of its price elasticity, government spending typically has small e®ects on in°ation. 6) Both the decline in the variance of the ¯scal shocks and the change in their transmission mechanism contribute to the decline in the variance of GDP after 1980. ¤IGIER - Universitµa Bocconi and Centre for Economic Policy Research. I thank Alberto Alesina, Olivier Blanchard, Fabio Canova, Zvi Eckstein, Jon Faust, Carlo Favero, Jordi Gal¶³, Daniel Gros, Bruce Hansen, Fumio Hayashi, Ilian Mihov, Chris Sims, Jim Stock and Mark Watson for helpful comments and suggestions.
    [Show full text]
  • Digitalisation and Monetary Policy
    Does the liquidity trap exist? Lhuissier, Mojon and Rubio-Ramirez AEA Congress, 4 January 2021 The views expressed here are mine and should not be attributed to the BIS Restricted “A liquidity trap may be defined as a situation in which conventional monetary policies have become impotent, because nominal interest rates are at or near zero: injecting monetary base into the economy has no effect, because base and bonds are viewed by the private sector as perfect substitutes” Paul Krugman (1998) Restricted 2 Outline 1. Motivation 2. Literature 3. Empirical analysis 4. Results 5. Discussion Restricted 3 1. Motivation: How low can long-term rates be? Central bank balance sheets1 Share of government bonds held by central banks2 % of GDP % of GDP % Restricted 4 1. Motivation: Is there a lack of monetary policy space? • Cutting down short rates and purchasing assets to cut long rates can go only so far and • the lack of “interest rate” space is very critical in several advanced economies • However, into the medium we still need to assess whether and how much MP can do when short-term rates are near the ZLB/ELB Restricted 5 Literature: The ZLB makes MP ineffective Japan . Krugman (1998) – Coenen and Wieland (2003) “John Hicks, in introducing both the IS-LM model and the liquidity trap, identified the assumption that monetary policy is ineffective, rather than the assumed downward inflexibility of prices, as the central difference between Mr. Keynes and the classics.” US and EA, before the facts . Early Fed attemps: Furher and Madigan (97); Orphanides and Williams & Reifschneider and Williams (2000) .
    [Show full text]
  • Cities, Information, and Economic Growth
    Cities, Information, and Economic Growth Cities, Information, and Economic Growth Edward L. Glaeser Harvard University Great are the advantages which people following the same skilled trade get from near neighborhood to one another. The mysteries of the trade become no mysteries; but are, as it were, in the air. A. Marshall Principles of Economics For centuries economists have fervently sought to understand the forces behind economic progress. Smith (1776), Marx (1909), Marshall (1890), Young (1928), and Keynes (1936) all hotly pursued this topic. In the post-World War II period, economic theorists, develop- ment economists, macroeconomists, econometricians, economic historians, and growth economists have devoted considerable energy to thinking about the forces behind long- run growth rates. It would be impossible to claim that these economists have reached a consensus on the causes of growth, but it seems clear that the growth of economies does not involve the simple accumulation of capital and labor. Theoretical models of capital accumulation (based on Solow, 1956, for example) ultimately leave the growth rate as an unexplained outside parameter. Empirically the stunning range of cross-national experiences makes it clear that the forces driving growth are rich and varied. Instead of continuing to use simple capital accumulation models, economists (following Romer, 1986) have moved toward models in which the stock of knowledge, in the Nation and the world, plays a critical role in facilitating progress. The nature of intellectual capi- tal—mostly the presence of strong external effects—solves certain technical problems when explaining why global increasing returns, which are necessary to explain growth, can coexist with competition.
    [Show full text]
  • Globalization: What Did We Miss?
    Globalization: What Did We Miss? Paul Krugman March 2018 Concerns about possible adverse effects from globalization aren’t new. In particular, as U.S. income inequality began rising in the 1980s, many commentators were quick to link this new phenomenon to another new phenomenon: the rise of manufactured exports from a group of newly industrializing economies. Economists – trade economists, anyway – took these concerns seriously. After all, standard models of international trade do say that trade can have large effects on income distribution: the famous 1941 Stolper-Samuelson analysis of a two-good, two-factor economy showed how trading with a labor-abundant economy can reduce real wages, even if national income grows. There was every reason to believe that the same principle applied to the emergence of trade with low-wage economies exporting not raw materials but manufactured goods. And so during the 1990s a number of economists, myself included (Krugman 1995), tried to assess the role of Stolper-Samuelson-type effects in rising inequality. Inevitably given the standard framework, such analyses did in fact find some depressing effect of growing trade on the wages of less-educated workers in advanced countries. As a quantitative matter, however, they generally suggested that the effect was relatively modest, and not the central factor in the widening income gap. Meanwhile, the political salience of globalization seemed to decline as other issues came to the fore. So academic interest in the possible adverse effects of trade, while it never went away, waned. 1 In the past few years, however, worries about globalization have shot back to the top of the agenda, partly due to new research, partly due to the political shocks of Brexit and Trump.
    [Show full text]
  • Ten Nobel Laureates Say the Bush
    Hundreds of economists across the nation agree. Henry Aaron, The Brookings Institution; Katharine Abraham, University of Maryland; Frank Ackerman, Global Development and Environment Institute; William James Adams, University of Michigan; Earl W. Adams, Allegheny College; Irma Adelman, University of California – Berkeley; Moshe Adler, Fiscal Policy Institute; Behrooz Afraslabi, Allegheny College; Randy Albelda, University of Massachusetts – Boston; Polly R. Allen, University of Connecticut; Gar Alperovitz, University of Maryland; Alice H. Amsden, Massachusetts Institute of Technology; Robert M. Anderson, University of California; Ralph Andreano, University of Wisconsin; Laura M. Argys, University of Colorado – Denver; Robert K. Arnold, Center for Continuing Study of the California Economy; David Arsen, Michigan State University; Michael Ash, University of Massachusetts – Amherst; Alice Audie-Figueroa, International Union, UAW; Robert L. Axtell, The Brookings Institution; M.V. Lee Badgett, University of Massachusetts – Amherst; Ron Baiman, University of Illinois – Chicago; Dean Baker, Center for Economic and Policy Research; Drucilla K. Barker, Hollins University; David Barkin, Universidad Autonoma Metropolitana – Unidad Xochimilco; William A. Barnett, University of Kansas and Washington University; Timothy J. Bartik, Upjohn Institute; Bradley W. Bateman, Grinnell College; Francis M. Bator, Harvard University Kennedy School of Government; Sandy Baum, Skidmore College; William J. Baumol, New York University; Randolph T. Beard, Auburn University; Michael Behr; Michael H. Belzer, Wayne State University; Arthur Benavie, University of North Carolina – Chapel Hill; Peter Berg, Michigan State University; Alexandra Bernasek, Colorado State University; Michael A. Bernstein, University of California – San Diego; Jared Bernstein, Economic Policy Institute; Rari Bhandari, University of California – Berkeley; Melissa Binder, University of New Mexico; Peter Birckmayer, SUNY – Empire State College; L.
    [Show full text]
  • Janet L Yellen: the Federal Reserve's Monetary Policy Toolkit
    Janet L Yellen: The Federal Reserve’s monetary policy toolkit – past, present, and future Speech by Ms Janet L Yellen, Chair of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Symposium “Designing resilient monetary policy frameworks for the future”, Jackson Hole, Wyoming, 26 August 2016. * * * The Global Financial Crisis and Great Recession posed daunting new challenges for central banks around the world and spurred innovations in the design, implementation, and communication of monetary policy. With the U.S. economy now nearing the Federal Reserve’s statutory goals of maximum employment and price stability, this conference provides a timely opportunity to consider how the lessons we learned are likely to influence the conduct of monetary policy in the future. The theme of the conference, “Designing Resilient Monetary Policy Frameworks for the Future,” encompasses many aspects of monetary policy, from the nitty-gritty details of implementing policy in financial markets to broader questions about how policy affects the economy. Within the operational realm, key choices include the selection of policy instruments, the specific markets in which the central bank participates, and the size and structure of the central bank’s balance sheet. These topics are of great importance to the Federal Reserve. As noted in the minutes of last month’s Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) meeting, we are studying many issues related to policy implementation, research which ultimately will inform the FOMC’s views on how to most effectively conduct monetary policy in the years ahead. I expect that the work discussed at this conference will make valuable contributions to the understanding of many of these important issues.
    [Show full text]
  • The Secret of Our Non-Success
    Print edition version: Monday October 22, 2012 The Secret of Our Non-Success By PAUL KRUGMAN The U.S. economy finally seems to be recovering in earnest, with housing on the rebound and job creation outpacing growth in the working-age population. But the news is good, not great — it will still take years to restore full employment — and it has been a very long time coming. Why has the slump been so protracted? Fred R. Conrad/The New York Times Paul Krugman The answer — backed by overwhelming evidence — is that this is what normally happens after a severe financial crisis. But Mitt Romney’s economic team rejects that evidence. And this denialism bodes ill for policy if Mr. Romney wins next month. About the evidence: The most famous study is by Harvard’s Carmen Reinhart and Kenneth Rogoff, who looked at past financial crises and found that such crises are typically followed by years of high unemployment and weak growth. Later work by economists at the International Monetary Fund and elsewhere confirmed this analysis: crises that followed a sharp run-up in private-sector debt, from the U.S. Panic of 1893 to the Swedish banking crisis of the early 1990s, cast long shadows over the economy’s future. There was no reason to believe that this time would be different. This isn’t an after-the-fact rationalization. The Reinhart-Rogoff “aftermath” paper was released almost four years ago. And a number of other economists, including, well, me, issued similar warnings. In early 2008 I was already pointing out the distinction between recessions like 1973-5 or 1981-2, brought on by high interest rates, and “postmodern” recessions brought on by private-sector overreach.
    [Show full text]
  • Blanchard and Summers 1984 for the U.K., Germany and France; See Buiter 1985 for a More De- Tailed Study of U.K
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1986, Volume 1 Volume Author/Editor: Stanley Fischer, editor Volume Publisher: MIT Press Volume ISBN: 0-262-06105-8 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/fisc86-1 Publication Date: 1986 Chapter Title: Hysteresis and the European Unemployment Problem Chapter Author: Olivier J. Blanchard, Lawrence H. Summers Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c4245 Chapter pages in book: (p. 15 - 90) — Olivier I. Blanchard andLawrenceH. Summers MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY AND NBER, HARVARD UNWERSITY AND NBER Hysteresis and the European Unemployment Problem After twenty years of negligible unemployment, most of Western Europe has since the early 1970s suffered a protracted period of high and ris- ing unemployment. In the United Kingdom unemployment peaked at 3.3 percent over the period 1945—1970, but has risen almost continu- ously since 1970, and now stands at over 12 percent. For the Common Market nations as a whole, the unemployment rate more than doubled between 1970 and 1980 and has doubled again since then. Few forecasts call for a significant decline in unemployment over the next several years, and none call for its return to levels close to those that prevailed in the 1950s and 1960s. These events are not easily accounted for by conventional classical or Keynesian macroeconomic theories. Rigidities associated with fixed- length contracts, or the costs of adjusting prices or quantities, are un- likely to be large enough to account for rising unemployment over periods of a decade or more.
    [Show full text]
  • Modern Monetary Theory: Cautionary Tales from Latin America
    Modern Monetary Theory: Cautionary Tales from Latin America Sebastian Edwards* Economics Working Paper 19106 HOOVER INSTITUTION 434 GALVEZ MALL STANFORD UNIVERSITY STANFORD, CA 94305-6010 April 25, 2019 According to Modern Monetary Theory (MMT) it is possible to use expansive monetary policy – money creation by the central bank (i.e. the Federal Reserve) – to finance large fiscal deficits that will ensure full employment and good jobs for everyone, through a “jobs guarantee” program. In this paper I analyze some of Latin America’s historical episodes with MMT-type policies (Chile, Peru. Argentina, and Venezuela). The analysis uses the framework developed by Dornbusch and Edwards (1990, 1991) for studying macroeconomic populism. The four experiments studied in this paper ended up badly, with runaway inflation, huge currency devaluations, and precipitous real wage declines. These experiences offer a cautionary tale for MMT enthusiasts.† JEL Nos: E12, E42, E61, F31 Keywords: Modern Monetary Theory, central bank, inflation, Latin America, hyperinflation The Hoover Institution Economics Working Paper Series allows authors to distribute research for discussion and comment among other researchers. Working papers reflect the views of the author and not the views of the Hoover Institution. * Henry Ford II Distinguished Professor, Anderson Graduate School of Management, UCLA † I have benefited from discussions with Ed Leamer, José De Gregorio, Scott Sumner, and Alejandra Cox. I thank Doug Irwin and John Taylor for their support. 1 1. Introduction During the last few years an apparently new and revolutionary idea has emerged in economic policy circles in the United States: Modern Monetary Theory (MMT). The central tenet of this view is that it is possible to use expansive monetary policy – money creation by the central bank (i.e.
    [Show full text]
  • Modern Monetary Theory: a Marxist Critique
    Class, Race and Corporate Power Volume 7 Issue 1 Article 1 2019 Modern Monetary Theory: A Marxist Critique Michael Roberts [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.fiu.edu/classracecorporatepower Part of the Economics Commons Recommended Citation Roberts, Michael (2019) "Modern Monetary Theory: A Marxist Critique," Class, Race and Corporate Power: Vol. 7 : Iss. 1 , Article 1. DOI: 10.25148/CRCP.7.1.008316 Available at: https://digitalcommons.fiu.edu/classracecorporatepower/vol7/iss1/1 This work is brought to you for free and open access by the College of Arts, Sciences & Education at FIU Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Class, Race and Corporate Power by an authorized administrator of FIU Digital Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Modern Monetary Theory: A Marxist Critique Abstract Compiled from a series of blog posts which can be found at "The Next Recession." Modern monetary theory (MMT) has become flavor of the time among many leftist economic views in recent years. MMT has some traction in the left as it appears to offer theoretical support for policies of fiscal spending funded yb central bank money and running up budget deficits and public debt without earf of crises – and thus backing policies of government spending on infrastructure projects, job creation and industry in direct contrast to neoliberal mainstream policies of austerity and minimal government intervention. Here I will offer my view on the worth of MMT and its policy implications for the labor movement. First, I’ll try and give broad outline to bring out the similarities and difference with Marx’s monetary theory.
    [Show full text]
  • Interview of Stanley Fischer by Olivier Blanchard
    UBRARIBS Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from Boston Library Consortium IVIember Libraries http://www.archive.org/details/interviewofstanlOOblan 2 DEWEY HB31 .M415 Massachusetts Institute of Technology Department of Economics Working Paper Series Interview of Stanley Fischer By Olivier Blanchard Working Paper 05-1 April 1 9, 2005 Room E52-251 50 Memorial Drive Cambridge, MA 021 42 This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Networl< Paper Collection at http://ssrn.com/abstract=707821 MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY APR 2 6 2005 LIBRARIES Interview of Stanley Fischer, by Olivier Blanchard.i Abstract Stanley Fischer is a macroeconomist par excellence. After three careers, the first in academia at Chicago, and at MIT, the second at the World Bank and at the International Monetary Fund, the third in the private sector at Citigroup, he is starting a fourth, as the head of the Central Bank of Israel. This interview, to be published in Macroeconomic Dynamics, took place in April 2004, before the start of his fourth career. This interview took place long before Stan had any idea he would become Governor of the Bank of Israel, a position he took up in May 2005. We have not changed the text to reflect this latest stage. Introduction. The interview took place in April 2004 in my office at the Russell Sage Foundation in New York City, where I was spending a sabbatical year. We completed it while running together in Central Park during the following weeks. Our meeting at Russell Sage was just like the many meetings we have had over the years.
    [Show full text]
  • CURRICULUM VITAE August, 2015
    CURRICULUM VITAE August, 2015 Robert James Shiller Current Position Sterling Professor of Economics Yale University Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics P.O. Box 208281 New Haven, Connecticut 06520-8281 Delivery Address Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics 30 Hillhouse Avenue, Room 11a New Haven, CT 06520 Home Address 201 Everit Street New Haven, CT 06511 Telephone 203-432-3708 Office 203-432-6167 Fax 203-787-2182 Home [email protected] E-mail http://www.econ.yale.edu/~shiller Home Page Date of Birth March 29, 1946, Detroit, Michigan Marital Status Married, two grown children Education 1967 B.A. University of Michigan 1968 S.M. Massachusetts Institute of Technology 1972 Ph.D. Massachusetts Institute of Technology Employment Sterling Professor of Economics, Yale University, 2013- Arthur M. Okun Professor of Economics, Yale University 2008-13 Stanley B. Resor Professor of Economics Yale University 1989-2008 Professor of Economics, Yale University, 1982-, with joint appointment with Yale School of Management 2006-, Professor Adjunct of Law in semesters starting 2006 Visiting Professor, Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 1981-82. Professor of Economics, University of Pennsylvania, and Professor of Finance, The Wharton School, 1981-82. Visitor, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts, and Visiting Scholar, Department of Economics, Harvard University, 1980-81. Associate Professor, Department of Economics, University of Pennsylvania, 1974-81. 1 Research Fellow, National Bureau of Economic Research, Research Center for Economics and Management Science, Cambridge; and Visiting Scholar, Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, 1974-75. Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, University of Minnesota, 1972-74.
    [Show full text]