Does Oil Hinder Democracy? Author(S): Michael L

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Does Oil Hinder Democracy? Author(S): Michael L Trustees of Princeton University Does Oil Hinder Democracy? Author(s): Michael L. Ross Reviewed work(s): Source: World Politics, Vol. 53, No. 3 (Apr., 2001), pp. 325-361 Published by: Cambridge University Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/25054153 . Accessed: 16/07/2012 16:29 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp . JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Cambridge University Press and Trustees of Princeton University are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to World Politics. http://www.jstor.org DOES OIL HINDER DEMOCRACY? ByMICHAEL L.ROSS* Introduction scientists believe that oil has some very odd proper POLITICALties. Many studies show that when incomes rise, governments tend to more some an become democratic. Yet scholars imply there is excep to can to a tion this rule: if rising incomes be traced country's oil wealth, they suggest, this democratizing effect will shrink or disappear. min Does oil really have antidemocratic properties? What about other erals and other commodities? What might explain these effects? not area The claim that oil and democracy do mix is often used by to states the specialists explain why the high-income of Arab Middle East have not become democratic. If oil is truly at fault, this insight could help explain?and perhaps, predict?the political problems of oil as exporters around the world, such Nigeria, Indonesia, Venezuela, and the oil-rich states of Central Asia. If other minerals have similar prop account or of erties, this effect might help for the absence weakness de mocracy in dozens of additional states in sub-Saharan Africa, Latin "oil America, and Southeast Asia. Yet the impedes democracy" claim has received little attention outside the circle of Mideast scholars; not moreover, it has been carefully tested with regression analysis, ei ther within or beyond theMiddle East. use states I pooled time-series cross-national data from 113 between to 1971 and 1997 explore three aspects of the oil-impedes-democracy claim. The first is the claims validity: is it true?Although the claim has been championed byMideast specialists, it is difficult to test by examining cases only from the Middle East because the region provides scholars with * were to at Previous versions of this article presented seminars Princeton University, Yale Univer at sity, and the University of California, Los Angeles, and the September 2000 annual meeting of the comments on ear American Political Science Association inWashington, D.C. For their thoughtful am to lier drafts, I grateful Pradeep Chhibber, Indra de Soysa, Geoffrey Garrett, Phil Keefer, Steve Knack, Miriam Lowi, Ellen Lust-Okar, Lant Pritchett, Nicholas Sambanis, Jennifer Widner, Michael owe to Woolcock, and three anonymous reviewers. I special thanks Irfan Nooruddin for his research wrote was a assistance and advice and to Colin Xu for his help with the Stata. I this article while I vis re iting scholar at The World Bank inWashington, D.C. The views I express in this article, and all maining errors, are mine alone. WorldPolitics 53 (April2001), 325-61 326 WORLD POLITICS Table 1 Index of Oil-Reliant Statesa 1. Brunei (1994) 47.58 2. Kuwait 46.14 3. Bahrain 45.60 4. Nigeria (1991) 45.38 45.14 5. Congo, Dem. Rep. 6. Angola (1996) 45 7. Yemen 38.58 8. Oman 38.43 9. Saudi Arabia 33.85 10. Qatar (1994) 33.85 11. Libya (1988) 29.74 12. Iraq (1983) 23.48 13. Algeria 21.44 14. Venezuela 18.84 15. Syria 15.00 16. 13.46 Norway 17. Iran (1983) 11.95 18. Ecuador 8.53 19. Malaysia 5.91 20. Indonesia 5.69 21. Cameroon 5.63 22. Lithuania 4.48 23. Kyrgyz Republic (1996) 4.25 24. Netherlands 3.14 25. Colombia 3.13 divided GDP. Most aOil reliance is measured by the value of fuel-based exports by figures are based on data for 1995 fromWorld Bank (fn. 71).Figures for Brunei, Nigeria, Qatar, and Iran are the most recent available. Since 1995 for and Libya, Iraq, figures Angola Kyr are not 1996 are gyz Republic available, figures reported. on all Mideast little variation the dependent variable: virtually govern ments have been authoritarian since gaining independence. Moreover, are absence of in the there other plausible explanations for the democracy distinct Mideast, including the influence of Islam and the regions culture a influence on de and colonial history. Does oil have consistently negative mocracy once one accounts for these and other variables? two dimensions. One Second, I examine the claim's generality along obvious reasons the claim is geographic. For oil-impedes-democracy ten has been explored most carefully byMideast specialists: of the fif on are teen states most reliant oil wealth in the Middle East region (see Table 1). But is oil an obstacle to democracy only in theMideast, or does it harm oil exporters everywhere? If the hypothesis is true for all oil-rich DOES OIL HINDER DEMOCRACY? 327 Table 2 of Mineral-Reliant _Index States'1_ 1. Botswana 35.11 2. Zambia 24.97 3. Bahrain 16.39 4. Chile 12.63 5. Angola (1996) 11.5 6. Papua New Guinea 10.13 7. Togo (1991) 7.79 8. Bolivia 5.53 9. Congo, Dem. Rep. (1983) 7.00 10. Jordan 5.28 11. Peru 3.84 12. Central African Republic 3.16 13. Iceland 3.11 14. Zimbabwe 3.00 15. Norway 2.49 16. Belgium 2.23 17. Canada 2.22 18. Australia 2.20 19. Lithuania 1.96 20. Jamaica 1.87 21. Slovak Republic 1.74 22. South Africa 1.69 23. Morocco 1.65 24. Cameroon 1.62 25. Kyrgyz Republic 1.56 aMineral reliance ismeasured by the value of nonfuel mineral exports divided by GDP. Most figures are for 1995 based on data fromWorld Bank (fn. 71). The figures for Congo and are the most recent the 1996 is for since no Togo available; figure reported Angola, fig ure for 1995 is available. states, then its importance has been underappreciated by other political scientists. If it holds only for states in theMideast, why is this so? The other dimension is sectoral: do other types of minerals and on other types of commodities have similar effects governments? While to oil exporters tend be concentrated in the Middle East, exporters of nonfuel minerals aremore geographically dispersed (seeTable 2). Have these states, too, been rendered less democratic because of resource are not wealth? Or does petroleum have antidemocratic properties that found in other commodities? Finally, I explore the question of causality: if oil does have antidem test ocratic effects, what is the causal mechanism? I three possible a explanations: "rentier effect," which suggests that resource-rich 328 WORLD POLITICS use rates governments low tax and patronage to relieve pressures for a that resource greater accountability; "repression effect," which argues to wealth retards democratization by enabling governments boost their a funding for internal security; and "modernization effect," which holds on to that growth based the export of oil and minerals fails bring about to the social and cultural changes that tend produce democratic gov ernment. I also have two broader aims. The first is to encourage scholars who to study democracy incorporate the Middle East into their analyses. en Many "global" studies of democratization have avoided the Mideast tirely.1 Influential studies by Przeworski and Limongi and Przeworski, Alvarez, Cheibub, and Limongi simply drop the oil-rich Mideast states no reason from their database.2 There is, however, sound analytical for to states scholars of democracy exclude these from their research, and so can to doing only weaken any general findings. It also tends margin alize the field ofMiddle East studies. to on My second aim is address the literature the "resource curse." Many of the poorest and most troubled states in the developing world resource is a have, paradoxically, high levels of natural wealth. There resource a coun growing body of evidence that wealth itself may harm resource try's prospects for development. States with greater natural to more counter wealth tend grow slowly than their resource-poor are more to from civil wars.4 This article parts.3 They also likely suffer a resource curse: suggests as well that there is third component to the oil and mineral wealth tends to make states less democratic. 1 See, for example, Guillermo O'Donnell, Philippe C. Schmitter, and Lawrence Whitehead, eds., Transitions from Authoritarian Rule: Prospects for Democracy (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1986); D. Larry Diamond, Juan J. Linz, and Seymour Martin Lipset, eds., Democracy inDevel Ronald Modernization andPostmod oping Countries (Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Rienner, 1988); Inglehart, emization (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1997). 2 Adam Przeworski and Fernando Limongi, "Modernization: Theories and Facts," World Politics 49 (January 1997); Adam Przeworski, Michael Alvarez, Jos? Antonio Cheibub, and Fernando Limongi, De "What Makes Democracies Endure?"JournalofDemocracy 7 (January 1996); idem, Democracy and Institutions and in 1950-1990 York: Uni velopment: Political Well-Being the World, (New Cambridge versity Press, 2000). 3 Jeffrey D. Sachs and Andrew M. Warner, "Natural Resource Abundance and Economic Growth," no. for Development Discussion Paper 517a (Cambridge: Harvard Institute International Develop ment, 1995); idem, "The Big Push, Natural Resource Booms and Growth," Journal ofDevelopment Nat Economics 59 (February 1999); Carlos Leite and JensWeidmann, "Does Mother Nature Corrupt? IMF ural Resources, Corruption, and Economic Growth," Working Paper, WP/99/85 (1999); Michael L.
Recommended publications
  • South of the Border, Down Mexico Way: the Past, Present, and Future of Petroleum Development in Mexico,‡ Part I
    Owen L. Anderson* & J. Jay Park† SOUTH OF THE BORDER, DOWN MEXICO WAY: THE PAST, PRESENT, AND FUTURE OF PETROLEUM DEVELOPMENT IN MEXICO,‡ PART I ABSTRACT Mexico is estimated to have 9.8 billion barrels of untapped oil reserves, or about 10 percent of the world’s crude oil; however, much remains undeveloped and production is declining as a result of dysfunction in the structure of Mexico’s petroleum regime. Until recently, Mexico’s Constitution and laws limited oil and gas activities to those of its state oil company, Petróleos Mexicanos (Pemex), which struggled to invest in new drilling and technology. In 2013, however, Mexico reopened its petroleum sector to foreign investment. Although 75 years in the making, Mexico is taking a bold new path toward developing its petroleum resources. Mexico stands to benefit from foreign investment and new technology to develop its remaining resources, which include shale deposits, deepwater reserves, and reserves only recoverable through modern enhanced recovery techniques. This two-part article has two objectives: Part I reviews the history of petroleum in Mexico—much of it unhappy—as a reminder of the long and tortuous pathway that led to Mexico’s current initiative to open its petroleum sector to foreign investment. The Mexican economy was built on oil in the early 1900s, but a combination of nationalism, petroleum-investor arrogance, and eventual over- dependence on petroleum revenues all served to undermine the Mexican oil industry. It is important for petroleum investors to understand and appreciate this history in order to ease the transition of new oil production in Mexico.
    [Show full text]
  • The Modernization of the EU-Mexico Global Agreement, 2000-2020
    Master’s Degree in Comparative International Relations Final Thesis Towards a new generation trade agreement: the modernization of the EU-Mexico Global Agreement, 2000-2020 Supervisor Ch. Prof. Duccio BASOSI Assistant supervisor Ch. Prof. Vanni PETTINÀ Graduand Silvia SCHIAVONI 877176 Academic Year 2019/2020 Index Abstract 1 Introduction 5 Chapter 1: The external trade policy of the EU 1) Influences on the evolution of European trade policies 10 2) The Common Commercial Policy of the EU 13 3) The Treaty of Lisbon and the new EU trade strategies 20 4) Main characteristics of FTAs/PTAs 26 5) First Generation FTAs 31 6) DCFTA 35 7) EPA 36 8) New Generation Agreements 38 9) The new generation of EU FTAs: South Korea, Japan, Singapore, Vietnam, TTIP, CETA and Mercosur 41 Chapter 2: Mexico’s external policy and its trade relations with the EU 1) History of Mexican commercial policy 53 2) The 1980s trade opening and liberalization reforms 60 3) The North America Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) 64 4) European Union relations with Latin America 68 5) Evolution of Mexican relation with the European Union, 1900s – 1992 73 6) The framework of the 1997 Mexico-European Union Global Agreement negotiations 83 Chapter 3: Modernization of the Mexico-European Union Global Agreement 1) Analysis of the Global Agreement and the 2008 Strategic Partnership 88 2) First years of Global Agreement implementation: 2002-2006 97 3) EU-Mexico relations in the framework of the Global Agreement 2006-2012 106 4) The period 2012-2016 and the decision to modernize the Global Agreement 115 5) Global Agreement impact assessment 123 6) The Agreement in Principle and the inclusion of new elements 129 Conclusion 139 Bibliography 144 Abstract Verso la metà degli anni Novanta, mentre il Messico firmava l’Accordo nordamericano di libero commercio con i due partner principali dell’America del Nord, gli Stati Uniti e il Canada, la quota europea del mercato messicano diminuiva in maniera costante.
    [Show full text]
  • A Rentier State Under Blockade: Qatar's Water-Energy-Food
    water Article A Rentier State under Blockade: Qatar’s Water-Energy-Food Predicament from Energy Abundance and Food Insecurity to a Silent Water Crisis 1,2, 3, Hussam Hussein * and Laurent A. Lambert y 1 Department of Politics and International Relations (DPIR), University of Oxford, Manor Road, Oxford OX1 3UQ, UK 2 International Agricultural Policy and Environmental Governance, Faculty of Organic Agricultural Sciences, University of Kassel, 37213 Witzenhausen, Germany 3 Department of Public Policy, Doha Institute for Graduate Studies, Al Tarfa Street, Zone 70, P.O. Box 200592, Doha, Qatar; [email protected] * Correspondence: [email protected] Both authors contributed equally to this manuscript. y Received: 29 February 2020; Accepted: 5 April 2020; Published: 8 April 2020 Abstract: This article investigates Qatar’s sustainability crisis of the high levels of water, electricity and food use. The high levels of consumption have been enabled by Qatar’s significant hydrocarbons wealth, a generous rentier state’s redistributive water governance, and structural dependence on imported food and food production subsidies. The water crisis is silent because it does not generate supply disruptions nor any public discontentment. The geopolitical blockade Qatar is experiencing sparked discussions in policy circles on the best ways to ensure food security, but has only exacerbated its water insecurity. The blockade makes more urgent than ever the necessity to maximize and increase synergies among different sectors. Keywords: desalination; water-energy-food; rentier state; redistributive water governance; Qatar; blockade 1. Introduction Qatar and the other monarchies of the Gulf region are paradoxes. They represent some of the most arid drylands in the world, yet they feature some of the highest levels of water and food consumption per capita in the world [1].
    [Show full text]
  • Pervasive Precarity: Migrant Mexican Oil Workers
    Pervasive Precarity: Migrant Mexican Oil Workers’ Experiences and Tactics to Navigate Uncertainty By Rebecca J. Crosthwait © 2014 Submitted to the graduate degree program in Anthropology and the Graduate Faculty of the University of Kansas in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy. ________________________________ Chairperson, Donald D. Stull, Ph.D., M.P.H. ________________________________ Brent E. Metz, Ph.D. ________________________________ Ebenezer Obadare, Ph.D. ________________________________ Peter Herlihy, Ph.D. ________________________________ Ruben Flores, Ph.D. Date Defended: November 24, 2014 The Dissertation Committee for Rebecca J. Crosthwait certifies that this is the approved version of the following dissertation: Pervasive Precarity: Migrant Mexican Oil Workers’ Experiences and Tactics to Navigate Uncertainty ________________________________ Chairperson Donald D. Stull Date approved: December 10, 2014 ii Abstract An ethnographic analysis of precarity as experienced by migrant Mexican oil workers in permanently insecure work structures in the Gulf of Mexico, this study explores precarious employment situations in the oil industry and tactics workers use to navigate, cope with, and diminish uncertainty. In addition to workers’ experiences, I analyze the contexts in which individuals live and work, including: labor-market changes; the history, politics, and geography of oil; and hurricanes’ impacts on labor. To better understand the tightrope walk between precarious employment and unemployment, I conducted interviews with workers and others affiliated with the oil industry during fieldwork in the Coastal Bend of Texas, in 2008, and Ciudad del Carmen, Mexico, in 2012. Both areas are important in the Gulf of Mexico oil industry and draw workers for projects both in the fabrication of offshore vessels and drilling and production of offshore oil.
    [Show full text]
  • What Would the Saudi Economy Have to Look Like to Be 'Post Rentier'?
    What would the Saudi economy have to look like to be 'post rentier'? LSE Research Online URL for this paper: http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/101386/ Version: Published Version Article: Hertog, Steffen (2019) What would the Saudi economy have ot look like to be 'post rentier'? POMEPS Studies. pp. 29-33. Reuse Items deposited in LSE Research Online are protected by copyright, with all rights reserved unless indicated otherwise. They may be downloaded and/or printed for private study, or other acts as permitted by national copyright laws. The publisher or other rights holders may allow further reproduction and re-use of the full text version. This is indicated by the licence information on the LSE Research Online record for the item. [email protected] https://eprints.lse.ac.uk/ POMEPS STUDIES 33 The Politics of Rentier States in the Gulf January 2019 Contents Introduction: The politics of rentier states in the Gulf ..............................................3 Rentierism: Institutions and Economics Labor markets and economic diversification in the Gulf rentiers ....................................8 Michael Herb, Georgia State University Exploring why institutional upgrading is not so easy in rentier states ................................13 Makio Yamada, Princeton University Subsidy reform and tax increases in the rentier Middle East ........................................18 Jim Krane, Rice University’s Baker Institute Saudi Arabia as a Model A landing strategy for Saudi Arabia ..............................................................25
    [Show full text]
  • Oil Revenues and Rentier States
    Oil Revenues and Rentier States How did Economic Sanctions and Subsidy Reforms Affect Iranian Lower-Middle Class During the Presidency of Ahmadinejad in Iran? Dena Motevalian INTRODUCTION This study focuses on the “rentier” character of a state1, and the effect of economic sanctions on the state’s foreign policy and its economic infrastructures. The resource-dependent economic foundation of rentier states allows the allocation of welfare benefits to society in boom periods. However, a rentier state’s high dependency on resource export revenues creates a risky economy that can collapse by international oil price fluctuations or oil sanctions. Thus, I argue that oil sanctions can cause economic deprivation and resource revenue cuts, which leads to a shift in a rentier state’s policies in favor of the sender state. I also argue that resource sanctions can lead to democratic shifts in economic administrations within the rentier state. To investigate this, first I review literature on the resource curse hypothesis, the rentier state’s economy and its power structures, and on successful sanctions among adversaries. Secondly, I present Iran as a case study and its rentier economic character. I summarize the process of global sanctions on Iran and their effects on tax reforms and government expenditures. More specifically, I look into the effects of intensified international economic sanctions during the presidency of Mahmoud Ahmadinejad, which led to a tax and subsidy reform for the first time in Iran’s history. Lastly, I explore how subsidy reforms affected the Iranian lower-middle class and the inequality ratio. This paper aims to show that resource coercions on the Iranian case study with a rentier character were successful in shifting Iran’s policy to comply with the senders’ policies.
    [Show full text]
  • Redalyc.Myths and Realities on Islam and Democracy in the Middle East
    Estudios Políticos ISSN: 0121-5167 [email protected] Instituto de Estudios Políticos Colombia Cevik, Salim Myths and Realities on Islam and Democracy in the Middle East Estudios Políticos, núm. 38, enero-junio, 2011, pp. 121-144 Instituto de Estudios Políticos Medellín, Colombia Available in: http://www.redalyc.org/articulo.oa?id=16429066007 How to cite Complete issue Scientific Information System More information about this article Network of Scientific Journals from Latin America, the Caribbean, Spain and Portugal Journal's homepage in redalyc.org Non-profit academic project, developed under the open access initiative Myths and Realities on Islam and Democracy in the Middle East* Salim Cevik** Abstract There is a strong body of literature that claims that Islam and democracy are essentially incompatible. However, Islam like all other religions is multivocal and it has strong theorethical elements that can also work for a basis of a democratic polity. Throughout the Muslim world there are certain countries that achieved a considerable level of democratization. It is only the Arab world, not the Muslim world, that so far represents a complete failure in terms of democratic transition. The failure of Arab world should be attributed to more political reasons, such as oil economy and the rentier state model than to Islam. Lack of international support for pro-democracy movements in the region, under the fear that they might move towards an Islamist political system is also an important factor in the democratic failures in the region. However, democratic record of Turkey’s pro-Islamic Justice and Development Party challenges these fears. With the international attention it attracts, particularly from the Arab world, Turkish experience provides a strong case for the compatibility of [ 121 ] democracy and Islam.
    [Show full text]
  • Authoritarianism and Democracy in Muslim Countries: Rentier States and Regional Diffusion
    Authoritarianism and Democracy in Muslim Countries: Rentier States and Regional Diffusion AHMET T. KURU ACCORDING TO FREEDOM HOUSE (2013),1 among countries with populations higher than 200,000, the proportion of electoral democracies is 56 percent (98/174) worldwide, whereas it is only 20 percent (10/49) in Muslim‐majority countries. The average Freedom House score (1 for most and 7 for least democratic) for all countries (3.5) is also better than the average score for Muslim‐majority countries (5.1). Analyzing countries with populations over 500,000, Polity (2010) reaches a similar result: 57 percent (93/164) of all countries and 28 percent (13/47) of Muslim‐majority countries are democracies.2 Why is the rate (and score) of democracy disproportionately low among Muslim‐majority countries? This article argues that the combined effects of rentier states and regional diffusion provide the best explanation. The rentier state model explains the links between the rent revenue, limited taxation, and authoritarianism. A state becomes “rentier” if oil, gas, and mineral rents constitute over 40 percent of its revenues. The state 1Freedom House, “Freedom in the World 2013,” accessed at http://www.freedomhouse.org/sites/default/ files/FIW%202013%20Booklet.pdf, 1 October 2013. 2Polity IV, “Country Reports 2010,” accessed at http://www.systemicpeace.org/polity/polity06.htm, 1 Jan- uary 2012. AHMET T. KURU is an associate professor of political science at San Diego State University. He is the author of the award‐winning Secularism and State Policies toward Religion: The United States, France, and Turkey, and the co‐editor (with Alfred Stepan) of Democracy, Islam, and Secularism in Turkey.
    [Show full text]
  • The Case of Mexico
    Wright State University CORE Scholar Browse all Theses and Dissertations Theses and Dissertations 2011 When Prohibition and Violence Collide: The Case of Mexico Kyleigh M. Clark Wright State University Follow this and additional works at: https://corescholar.libraries.wright.edu/etd_all Part of the International Relations Commons Repository Citation Clark, Kyleigh M., "When Prohibition and Violence Collide: The Case of Mexico" (2011). Browse all Theses and Dissertations. 1070. https://corescholar.libraries.wright.edu/etd_all/1070 This Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the Theses and Dissertations at CORE Scholar. It has been accepted for inclusion in Browse all Theses and Dissertations by an authorized administrator of CORE Scholar. For more information, please contact [email protected]. WHEN PROHIBITION AND VIOLENCE COLLIDE: THE CASE OF MEXICO A thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Arts By KYLEIGH CLARK B.A. International Studies, Wright State University, 2009 2011 Wright State University WRIGHT STATE UNIVERSITY GRADUATE SCHOOL November 18,2011 I HEREBY RECOMMEND THAT THE THESIS PREPARED UNDER MY SUPERVISION BY Kyleigh Clark ENTITLED When Violence and Prohibition Collide: The Case of Mexico BE ACCEPTED IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF Master of Arts. ______________________________ December Green, Ph.D. Thesis Director ______________________________ Laura M. Luehrmann, Ph.D. Director, Master of Arts Program in International and Comparative Politics Committee on Final Examination: ___________________________________ December Green, Ph.D. Department of Political Science ___________________________________ Laura Luehrmann, Ph.D. Department of Political Science ___________________________________ Nancy Broughton, Ph.D. Department of Modern Languages ______________________________ Andrew T.
    [Show full text]
  • The Reformed Rentier State: the Social Contract in Modern-Day Saudi
    The Reformed Rentier State: The social contract in modern-day Saudi Arabia ABSTRACT Rentier state theory has long been able to explain the relationship between state and society in the oil-rich countries of the Gulf. However, Saudi Arabia has seen a multitude of socioeconomic developments that, as I argue in this thesis, have caused as shift in the role of the state. I argue that the traditional model of the social contract has changed by examining the effect of contextual domestic issues. To support this argument, I investigate the extent to which oil price fluctuations and democratic pressures have had an influence on the nature of the social contract. The analysis concludes that the nature of the social contract has changed, and that rentier state theory should be refined and updated to improve our understanding of the social contract in modern-day Saudi Arabia. C.L.M. Wilmink S2233169 Thesis MSc Political Science: International Politics University of Leiden Dr. Nicolas Blarel Second reader: Dr. Oda van Cranenburgh January 10, 2019 Wordcount: 9247 Table of Contents Introduction 3 Research Question 4 Literature Review 6 Rentier State Theory 6 The social contract in a rentier society 8 Revisions to classical Rentier State Theory 8 Theoretical Section 11 Research Design 14 Case selection 14 General research method 16 Specification of indicators for the variables 16 Empirical Findings 19 The nature of the social contract 19 Non-renewable nature of the source of rents 20 Fluctuation of oil prices 20 Demographic pressures in Saudi Arabia 23 Conclusion 28 Bibliography 30 2 Introduction Since the emergence of the rentier state theory (RST) in the 1970s, the oil- and gas-producing states in the Arab world have often been referred to as ‘rentier states’ (e.g.
    [Show full text]
  • The Rentier State and the Survival of Arab Absolute Monarchies
    THE RENTIER STATE AND THE SURVIVAL OF ARAB ABSOLUTE MONARCHIES Charlotte M. Levins1 I. INTRODUCTION The Arab Spring has captured Western attention. News stories declare, “People all over the Arab world feel a sense of pride in shaking off decades of cowed passivity under dictatorships that ruled with no deference to popular wishes . Egypt is now thought of as an exciting and progressive place.”2 However, despite optimism for an Arab call to democracy, the rentier system poses a tremendous challenge to oil-wealthy Arab nations. In a rentier state, the government collects oil revenues and distributes the pro- ceeds to the population. The population relies on their government for food, shelter, income, and job opportunities. Because the gov- ernment in a rentier state plays the role of benefactor, citizens will not rush to demand an entirely new system – even one with in- creased representation. Thus, Arab absolute monarchies in a ren- tier state, which today include Bahrain, Oman, Qatar, Jordan, Kuwait, and Saudi Arabia, will likely continue to enjoy relatively unchallenged support, at least while oil revenues sustain the states. Nevertheless, the rentier system is finite, and because large government welfare packages are unsustainable in the long term, monarchies must consider reform. This Article will discuss how the rentier state contributes to the survival of Arab absolute monarchies despite the various chal- lenges to their rule. Part II illustrates the theory of the rentier state, and in particular, how the rentier system affects the eco- nomics of the state and work mentality. Part III discusses the mo- narchical quest for legitimacy and how Islam and tribal networks are used for support in the face of challenges to their rule.
    [Show full text]
  • Fiscal Policy in Latin America
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1997, Volume 12 Volume Author/Editor: Ben S. Bernanke and Julio Rotemberg Volume Publisher: MIT Press Volume ISBN: 0-262-02435-7 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/bern97-1 Publication Date: January 1997 Chapter Title: Fiscal Policy in Latin America Chapter Author: Michael Gavin, Roberto Perotti Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c11036 Chapter pages in book: (p. 11 - 72) MichaelGavin and RobertoPerotti INTER-AMERICANDEVELOPMENT BANK; AND COLUMBIAUNIVERSITY AND CEPR Fiscal Policy in Latin America 1. Introduction Macroeconomic analysis of Latin America has long been primarily an exercise in monetary analysis. Fiscal policy has always formed part of this study, but the emphasis has typically been on fiscal deficits only, with the interest primarily centered on their effect on monetary out- comes and inflation. This emphasis is understandable, in light of the region's history of monetary and financial instability, but the time may be ripe for a. change. While inflation has not vanished from Latin Amer- ica, over the course of the past decade it has fallen nearly to single-digit levels. There is good reason to hope that Latin America will no longer be a breeding ground for the extreme and exotic monetary experiments that have in the past occupied monetary economists around the world. If so, policymakers in the region will have scope to turn their attention to other policy problems, and students of economic policy will have to search elsewhere for lessons.
    [Show full text]