The Emergence of Intangible Capital

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Emergence of Intangible Capital JYVÄSKYLÄ STUDIES IN HUMANITIES 285 Olli Turunen The Emergence of Intangible Capital Human, Social, and Intellectual Capital in Nineteenth Century British, French, and German Economic Thought JYVÄSKYLÄ STUDIES IN HUMANITIES 285 Olli Turunen The Emergence of Intangible Capital Human, Social, and Intellectual Capital in Nineteenth Century British, French, and German Economic Thought Esitetään Jyväskylän yliopiston humanistisen tiedekunnan suostumuksella julkisesti tarkastettavaksi yliopiston vanhassa juhlasalissa S212 huhtikuun 22. päivänä 2016 kello 12. Academic dissertation to be publicly discussed, by permission of the Faculty of Humanities of the University of Jyväskylä, in building Seminarium, auditorium S212, on April 22, 2016 at 12 o’clock noon. UNIVERSITY OF JYVÄSKYLÄ JYVÄSKYLÄ 2016 The Emergence of Intangible Capital Human, Social, and Intellectual Capital in Nineteenth Century British, French, and German Economic Thought JYVÄSKYLÄ STUDIES IN HUMANITIES 285 Olli Turunen The Emergence of Intangible Capital Human, Social, and Intellectual Capital in Nineteenth Century British, French, and German Economic Thought UNIVERSITY OF JYVÄSKYLÄ JYVÄSKYLÄ 2016 Editors Ilkka Nummela Department of History and Ethnology, University of Jyväskylä Pekka Olsbo, Ville Korkiakangas Publishing Unit, University Library of Jyväskylä Jyväskylä Studies in Humanities Editorial Board Editor in Chief Heikki Hanka, Department of Art and Culture Studies, University of Jyväskylä Petri Karonen, Department of History and Ethnology, University of Jyväskylä Paula Kalaja, Department of Languages, University of Jyväskylä Petri Toiviainen, Department of Music, University of Jyväskylä Tarja Nikula, Centre for Applied Language Studies, University of Jyväskylä Epp Lauk, Department of Communication, University of Jyväskylä URN:ISBN:978-951-39-6596-9 ISBN 978-951-39-6596-9 (PDF) ISSN 1459-4331 ISBN 978-951-39-6595-2 (nid.) ISSN 1459-4323 Copyright © 2016, by University of Jyväskylä Jyväskylä University Printing House, Jyväskylä 2016 ABSTRACT Turunen, Olli The Emergence of Intangible Capital: Human, Social, and Intellectual Capital in Nineteenth Century British, French, and German Economic Thought Jyväskylä: University of Jyväskylä, 2016, 379 p. (Jyväskylä Studies in Humanities ISSN 1459-4323; 285 (nid.) ISSN 1459-4331; 285 (PDF)) ISBN 978-951-39-6595-2 (nid.) ISBN 978-951-39-6596-9 (PDF) Since the late 1950s the concept of human capital, understood as the stock of knowledge, skills, and abilities that determine individual productivity, has become one of the central tools with which economists explain both individual success and economic growth. During the latter half of the 20th century complementing concepts such as social capital, meaning the value of social networks and norms of reciprocity, and intangible capital, meaning the investments in knowledge and innovation generation, have emerged. The term intellectual capital is sometimes used as a major concept to bind different forms of intangible capital. This study focuses on the conceptual equivalents of these ideas in 19th century English, French, and German economic thought in order to show that most of the phenomena now connected to human capital, intangible capital, intellectual capital, and social capital were already extensively discussed as capital in different phases of the long 19th century (1789-1914). Equally, many of the arguments presented since the late 1950s against the extension of the concept of capital to human beings, human attributes, knowledge, reputation, social norms, or social relations after the new emergence of these ideas were also part of the earlier discussion. A better understanding of past debates about the definitional scope and functional role of capital in economic theory should help to avoid unintentionally circular or repetitive argumentation which presents what were in fact once solid arguments of political economy as previously unattainable insights made in the past five decades. Keywords: history of economic thought, human capital, intangible capital, social capital, intellectual capital, conceptual history Author’s address Olli Turunen Department of History and Ethnology P.O. Box 35 (H) FIN-40014 University of Jyväskylä Finland [email protected] Supervisors Ilkka Nummela Department of History and Ethnology University of Jyväskylä Jari Ojala Department of History and Ethnology University of Jyväskylä Jari Eloranta Department of History Appalachian State University Reviewers Reino Hjerppe VATT Institute for Economic Research Sulevi Riukulehto University of Helsinki Opponent Reino Hjerppe VATT Institute for Economic Research PREFACE This book is an attempt to describe the emergence and development of the idea that acquired human attributes as well as various phenomena of the social sphere are similar enough to financial investments and material capital to be treated as capital in economic and social analysis. The idea is not wholly trivial, since such a capital framework offers a forward-looking perspective for invest- ing time and resources in education, health, science, governance, and institu- tions that work. It is followed by the idea that the real constraint on our exist- ence is our level of technology, and not land as has classically been perceived. As the reader will discover, the nineteenth-century discussion on these subjects was vibrant and diverse. While I have been working with this theme from the late 2000s to this date in March 2016, different aspects and variants of what (as will be explained later) I call the “intangible capital connection” have resurfaced and become topical. First, during the latter half of the previous decade, the publication boom on the subject of ‘social capital’ was still in full swing. Research looked for the secret of thriving societies and communities in social aspects such as trust, reciprocity, and healthy institutions. Secondly, at the same time, the UN System of National Accounts (2008, SNA) was being reformed to better account for investments in intangible capital (research and development). This has also meant revisions of contemporary and historical GDP figures to reflect the new accounting methods. Thirdly, the consequences of the financial crisis of 2007-2008 combined with the continued effects of globalization and automatization have created an environment of increasing inequality, which has prompted some prominent economists to challenge the promise of the human capital theory in the same manner as Karl Marx or Eugen Böhm von Bawerk challenged the liberal idea of Mitkapitalistentum of workers in the nineteenth century. Indeed, the fears that robots and automatization will wipe out jobs on a large scale have their coun- terpart in fears caused by early industrialization. Fourthly, the old resource constraint of classical economics has come to haunt us on a global scale. Wheth- er our investments in knowledge and technology are the key to helping us through this remains to be seen. All these themes had quite close parallels in nineteenth-century economic literature. While writing this volume, the availability of digitized eighteenth and nineteenth-century literature has been constantly improving. The digitization projects and libraries of Google Books, Archive.org, Calliga, Deutsche Digitale Bibliothek, DigiZeitschriften, Persée, Europeana, Econlib.org, and others have combined to give access to a library of proportions that few physical libraries can match. In this work, I have barely scratched the surface of possibilities that these resources are revealing; but at the same time, digitized literature has helped tremendously in locating and studying the relevant discourses. I would like to thank professors Ilkka Nummela, Jari Ojala, Jari Eloranta, Juha-Antti Lamberg, and Kustaa Vilkuna for their help and guidance. The re- viewers Reino Hjerppe and Sulevi Riukulehto gave numerous constructive suggestions on how to improve the work. Unfortunately, there was not quite enough time to carry out all of these. The colleagues at the Department of His- tory and Ethnology have created a great work community, and reflective dis- cussions with Miikka Voutilainen, Pasi Saarimäki, Timo Särkkä, Matti Roitto, Sofia Kotilainen, Heli Valtonen, Maare Paloheimo, Ville Sarkamo, Pasi Neva- lainen, Heli Niskanen, Merja Uotila, Eerika Koskinen-Koivisto, and many others have provided diverse perspectives to the practices of scholarship. Thanks also goes to Alex Reed for greatly improving the language of the work. The Kone Foundation, the Emil Aaltonen Foundation, and the University of Jyväskylä (Rector’s Research Grant) have provided funding for this research, for which I am grateful. While writing this book, I have also been employed by Aalto University and two Academy of Finland projects. In addition, I have had the privilege to work with IEHA and MIT in preparing the World Economic History Congress (2018) in Boston. I would like to thank Matti Pursula and Mauri Airila at Aalto, Jari Ojala and Juha-Antti Lamberg here in Jyväskylä, Anne E.C. McCants at MIT, and Jari Eloranta at Appalachian State University for these much appreciated opportunities. Furthermore, my long-standing in- volvement with the Economic and Business History Society, especially with Dan Giedeman and Jason E. Taylor, has brought invaluable experience in or- ganizing conferences, scholarly publishing, and in the running of a scholarly association. Finally, I want to thank my wife Arja for her loving patience. I dedicate this book to my children Hilda and Tuure. I hope
Recommended publications
  • Hermann, Rau, Mangoldt : Les Origines De La Fonction D’Offre De Marché En Allemagne (1830 - 1870) Paola Tubaro
    Hermann, Rau, Mangoldt : les origines de la fonction d’offre de marché en Allemagne (1830 - 1870) Paola Tubaro To cite this version: Paola Tubaro. Hermann, Rau, Mangoldt : les origines de la fonction d’offre de marché en Allemagne (1830 - 1870). Recherches Economiques de Louvain - Louvain economic review, De Boeck Université, 2005, 71 (2), pp.223 - 243. 10.3917/rel.712.0223. hal-01648314 HAL Id: hal-01648314 https://hal.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-01648314 Submitted on 28 Nov 2020 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. HERMANN, RAU, MANGOLDT : LES ORIGINES DE LA FONCTION D'OFFRE DE MARCHÉ EN ALLEMAGNE (1830 - 1870) Paola Tubaro De Boeck Supérieur | « Recherches économiques de Louvain » 2005/2 Vol. 71 | pages 223 à 243 ISSN 0770-4518 ISBN 2-8041-4747-9 Document téléchargé depuis www.cairn.info - 176.183.201.126 25/11/2017 13h00. © De Boeck Supérieur Article disponible en ligne à l'adresse : -------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- https://www.cairn.info/revue-recherches-economiques-de- louvain-2005-2-page-223.htm -------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- Pour citer cet article : -------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- Paola Tubaro, « Hermann, Rau, Mangoldt : les origines de la fonction d'offre de marché en Allemagne (1830 - 1870) », Recherches économiques de Louvain 2005/2 (Vol.
    [Show full text]
  • Free Trade by Gordon Bannerman
    Free Trade by Gordon Bannerman Exchanging commodities by commercial transaction is one of the most direct forms of transferring cultural and intellectual capital. Historically, however, international trading relationships have been complicated by national rivalries, opposing economic interests, and the desire of nation‐states to protect domestic industries as a guarantee of economic power and military strength. Against these restrictive influences, the acceptance of free trade has varied according to time, place, and circumstance. This article examines the international and ideological trajectory of the idea and considers the structural and economic influences which shaped policy development and outcomes, as well as the historical context within which it occurred. TABLE OF CONTENTS 1. Introduction 2. Early Modern Conceptions of Trade 3. Mercantilism and Liberal Political Economy 4. The Emergence of Free Trade in Europe 5. Repeal of the British Corn Laws 6. The Rise of Free Trade in Europe 7. The Revival of Protection in Europe 8. Free Trade in Decline 9. Conclusion 10. Appendix 1. Sources 2. Bibliography 3. Notes Indices Citation Introduction The notion of free trade in international commerce has a long history, but only in the 18th century did an increasingly liberal view of the practical benefits and economic efficiency of free international commerce emerge in scholarly work. Most notably, The Wealth of Nations (1776) by Adam Smith (1723–1790) (➔ Media Link #ab) saw free international commerce as a prerequisite for the wealth creation of expanding capitalist economies through the division of labour and the removal of artificial barriers to trading relationships. Smith's work was the catalyst for free trade theory, and despite the obstinate survival of protectionism, notably in emerging nation‐ states anxious to protect domestic industries as a guaranty of national strength, free trade theory was increasingly accepted as underpinning progressive, modern policy‐making.
    [Show full text]
  • General Index
    SCIENCE & SOCIETY GENERAL INDEX VOLUMESI-XXV (1936�1961) Part I: Author, Subject and Title Part II: Books Reviewed SCIENCE & SOCIETY, INC. New York 1965 Copyright © 1965 by Science and Society, Inc. 30 East 20th Street, New York, N.Y. 10003 All Rights Reserved Printed in the United States of America Library of Congress Catalog Card Number: 40-10163 �341 PREFACE The editors of Science & Society believe that this index to its contents during the first twenty-five years of publication deserves the uncustomary tribute of an editorial note, since it serves to remind us that Science & Society is theoldest publication extant devoted to the theory of Marxism. Indeed, with the single exception of that monument to German scholar­ ship, Die Neue Zeit (1883-1923), it is the longest-lived Marxist theoretical journal in the world, and this despite the enormous difficulties under which Science & Society has always been published. The editors, therefore, take this opportunity to reaffirm their inten­ tion of making Science & Society a forum for the best Marxist scholarship, and their hope that the preface to some future edition of its index will no longer need to note the exception of Die N eue Zeit. We think that those who, using this index, rediscover the great variety of subjects treated and the quality of critical scholarship represented, will agree with us that it is a bibliographic tool of real value to all scholars, but truly invaluable to Marxists. Finally, the editors of Science & Society wish to express their deep gratitude to the Louis M. Rabinowitz Foundation whose generous grant made the publication of this index possible.
    [Show full text]
  • 1. the Damnation of Economics
    Notes 1. The Damnation of Economics 1. One example of vice-regal patronage of anti-economics is Canada’s ‘Governor General’s Award for Non-Fiction’. In 1995 this honour was bestowed upon John Raulston Saul’s anti-economic polemic The Unconscious Civilization (published in 1996). A taste of Saul’s wisdom: ‘Over the last quarter-century economics has raised itself to the level of a scientific profession and more or less foisted a Nobel Prize in its own honour onto the Nobel committee thanks to annual financing from a bank. Yet over the same 25 years, economics has been spectacularly unsuc- cessful in its attempts to apply its models and theories to the reality of our civili- sation’ (Saul 1996, p. 4). See Pusey (1991) and Cox (1995) for examples of patronage of anti-economics by Research Councils and Broadcasting Corporations. 2. Another example of economists’ ‘stillness’: the economists of 1860 did not join the numerous editorial rebukes of Ruskin’s anti-economics tracts (Anthony, 1983). 3. The anti-economist is not to be contrasted with the economist. An economist (that is, a person with a specialist knowledge of economics) may be an anti- economist. The true obverse of anti-economist is ‘philo-economist’: someone who holds that economics is a boon. 4. One may think of economics as a disease (as the anti-economist does), or one may think of economics as diseased. Mark Blaug: ‘Modern economics is “sick” . To para- phrase the title of a popular British musical: “No Reality, Please. We’re Economists”’ (Blaug 1998, p.
    [Show full text]
  • 1. the Heritage of Modern Socialist Ideas
    Section XVI: Developments in Socialism, Contemporary Civilization (Ideas and Institutions 1848-1914 of Western Man) 1958 1. The eH ritage of Modern Socialist Ideas Robert L. Bloom Gettysburg College Basil L. Crapster Gettysburg College Harold L. Dunkelberger Gettysburg College See next page for additional authors Follow this and additional works at: https://cupola.gettysburg.edu/contemporary_sec16 Part of the Models and Methods Commons, and the Sociology Commons Share feedback about the accessibility of this item. Bloom, Robert L. et al. "1. The eH ritage of Modern Socialist Ideas. Pt. XVI: Developments in Socialism, (1848-1914)." Ideas and Institutions of Western Man (Gettysburg College, 1958), 2-6. This is the publisher's version of the work. This publication appears in Gettysburg College's institutional repository by permission of the copyright owner for personal use, not for redistribution. Cupola permanent link: https://cupola.gettysburg.edu/ contemporary_sec16/2 This open access book chapter is brought to you by The uC pola: Scholarship at Gettysburg College. It has been accepted for inclusion by an authorized administrator of The uC pola. For more information, please contact [email protected]. 1. The eH ritage of Modern Socialist Ideas Abstract Of the total heritage which gave birth to modern socialism, brief attention may be given to certain of the predecessors of Karl Marx. Although some now are saved from obscurity only by the diligence of interested historians, others generated powerful ideas still not extinguished today. Together they created an amorphous body of thought from which Marx freelv drew. Consequently, an understanding of the varieties of later socialism, and specifically of Marx, requires a brief survey of these men.
    [Show full text]
  • Networks of Modernity: Germany in the Age of the Telegraph, 1830–1880
    OUP CORRECTED AUTOPAGE PROOFS – FINAL, 24/3/2021, SPi STUDIES IN GERMAN HISTORY Series Editors Neil Gregor (Southampton) Len Scales (Durham) Editorial Board Simon MacLean (St Andrews) Frank Rexroth (Göttingen) Ulinka Rublack (Cambridge) Joel Harrington (Vanderbilt) Yair Mintzker (Princeton) Svenja Goltermann (Zürich) Maiken Umbach (Nottingham) Paul Betts (Oxford) OUP CORRECTED AUTOPAGE PROOFS – FINAL, 24/3/2021, SPi OUP CORRECTED AUTOPAGE PROOFS – FINAL, 24/3/2021, SPi Networks of Modernity Germany in the Age of the Telegraph, 1830–1880 JEAN-MICHEL JOHNSTON 1 OUP CORRECTED AUTOPAGE PROOFS – FINAL, 24/3/2021, SPi 3 Great Clarendon Street, Oxford, OX2 6DP, United Kingdom Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford. It furthers the University’s objective of excellence in research, scholarship, and education by publishing worldwide. Oxford is a registered trade mark of Oxford University Press in the UK and in certain other countries © Jean-Michel Johnston 2021 The moral rights of the author have been asserted First Edition published in 2021 Impression: 1 Some rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, for commercial purposes, without the prior permission in writing of Oxford University Press, or as expressly permitted by law, by licence or under terms agreed with the appropriate reprographics rights organization. This is an open access publication, available online and distributed under the terms of a Creative Commons Attribution – Non Commercial – No Derivatives 4.0 International licence (CC BY-NC-ND 4.0), a copy of which is available at http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/.
    [Show full text]
  • H-France Review Vol. 20 (October 2020), No. 176 Julia Nicholls
    H-France Review Volume 20 (2020) Page 1 H-France Review Vol. 20 (October 2020), No. 176 Julia Nicholls, Revolutionary Thought after the Paris Commune, 1871-1885. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2019. vii + 309 pp. Bibliography and index. $99.99 U.S. (cl). ISBN 9781108499262; $32.99 U.S. (pb). ISBN 9781108713344; $80.00 U.S. (eb). ISBN 9781108600002. Review by Julian Bourg, Boston College. Revision is the historian’s stock-in-trade. Explanations of the past do not endure. Interpretations change as constantly altering circumstances shift vantage points, and even new evidence comes into view more often as a consequence than as a cause of such temporal parallax. In another way, however, in recent decades revisionism has become a default mode of historical writing. To take classic examples from contemporary French historical studies, one thinks of post-colonialism successfully decentering the metropole, François Furet overcoming Marxist interpretations of the French Revolution, and Robert Faurisson’s miserable négationnisme trying to abandon the facts of the Shoah. The extremely different normative consequences of such debates are clear, make no mistake, but so too is a certain historiographical pattern: the move to challenge and substitute prevailing views. The gesture of the hand that turns the kaleidoscope’s viewfinder, offering up endlessly combining and dispersing shards of colored glass, is itself repetitive. Historical revisionism can thus seem both a regular gambit--knotting historical writing to its present--and also a seemingly expected, even obligatory move within the “ironist’s cage” of the late twentieth and early twenty-first centuries.[1] Julia Nicholls has revised one of the most tired stereotypes of the early Third Republic: that in the wake of the Commune’s defeat in 1871, little transpired by way of revolutionary thought in France until Marxist orthodoxy ascended in the mid-to-late 1880s.
    [Show full text]
  • Blanqui’S Note Nov
    Biliana Kassabova History of Political Thought Workshop December 4, 2017 Blanqui’s note Nov. 23, 1848 Blanqui between Myth and Archives: Revolution, Dictatorship, and Education This piece, very much a work in progress, aims to make sense of the revolutionary ideas and actions of Louis-Auguste Blanqui. It complicates our ideas of political thought regarding revolution in the nineteenth century, by arguing that the binary of centralized versus popular revolution needs to be revised. It is part of a larger project on concepts of revolutionary leadership in France from the French Revolution of 1789 until the Paris Commune of 1871. Within this historical trajectory, Blanqui is an interpreter of 18th century ideas into 19th century contexts, a political thinker and actor who plays a key role in the various reformulations of the revolutionary tradition. 1848 does not enjoy a stellar reputation among historians of France. The revolution of February that year saw the overthrow of the last king of France, followed by the establishment of a new French republic. This republic, however, lasted for only three years, brought little and short-lived social change, remained rather conservative, though was also laden with bitter parliamentary strife, and ended through a coup d’état that inaugurated a new authoritarian régime, a Second Empire with Napoleon III at its head. To add insult to injury, even the attempts at establishing a viable parliamentary republican system were famously seen by political observers and participants from 2 almost all parts of the political spectrum as derivative, incompetent, and worse yet – laughable. “There have been more mischievous revolutionaries than those of 1848, but I doubt if there have been any stupider,”1 quipped Alexis de Tocqueville in his posthumously published Recollections.
    [Show full text]
  • Karl Helfferich and Rudolf Hilferding on Georg Friedrich Knapp's State
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Greitens, Jan Conference Paper — Manuscript Version (Preprint) Karl Helfferich and Rudolf Hilferding on Georg Friedrich Knapp’s State Theory of Money: Monetary Theories during the Hyperinflation of 1923 Suggested Citation: Greitens, Jan (2020) : Karl Helfferich and Rudolf Hilferding on Georg Friedrich Knapp’s State Theory of Money: Monetary Theories during the Hyperinflation of 1923, Annual Conference of the European Society for the History of Economic Thought (ESHET) 2020, Sofia., ZBW - Leibniz Information Centre for Economics, Kiel, Hamburg This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/216102 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available
    [Show full text]
  • September 2020
    Econ Journal Watch Scholarly Comments on Academic Economics Volume 17, Issue 2, September 2020 COMMENTS Comment on Sen, Karaca-Mandic, and Georgiou on Stay-at-Home Orders and COVID-19 Hospitalizations in Four States John A. Spry 270–278 Reply to John Spry on Stay-at-Home Orders and COVID-19 Hospitalizations Soumya Sen, Pinar Karaca-Mandic, and Archelle Georgiou 279–281 The Moving to Opportunity Experiment: What Do Heterogeneous Estimates of the Effect of Moving Imply About Causes? Robert Kaestner 282–298 Response to “The Moving to Opportunity Experiment: What Do Heterogeneous Estimates of the Effect of Moving Imply About Causes?” Raj Chetty, Nathaniel Hendren, and Lawrence F. Katz 299–304 Re-examination of the Theoretical and Historical Evidence Concerning Colonial New Jersey’s Paper Money, 1709–1775: A Further Comment on Grubb Ronald W. Michener 305–332 Recalculating Gravity: A Correction of Bergstrand’s 1985 Frictionless Case Nico Stoeckmann 333–337 ECONOMICS IN PRACTICE Gender, Race and Ethnicity, and Inequality Research in the American Economic Review and the American Economic Association’s Conference Papers Jeremy Horpedahl and Arnold Kling 338–349 INTELLECTUAL TYRANNY OF THE STATUS QUO Professional Scholarship from 1893 to 2020 on Adam Smith’s Views on School Funding: A Heterodox Examination Scott Drylie 350–391 CHARACTER ISSUES Republicans Need Not Apply: An Investigation of the American Economic Association Using Voter Registration and Political Contributions Mitchell Langbert 392–404 Liberalism in Brazil Lucas Berlanza 405–441 WATCHPAD Dispute on Method or Dispute on Institutional Context? Foreword to the Translation of Carl Menger’s “Errors of Historicism” Karen Horn and Stefan Kolev 442–459 The Errors of Historicism in German Economics Carl Menger 460–507 What 21st-Century Works Will Merit a Close Reading in 2050?: First Tranche of Responses Niclas Berggren, Arthur M.
    [Show full text]
  • INFORMATION to USERS the Most Advanced Technology Has Been Used to Photo­ Graph and Reproduce This Manuscript from the Microfilm Master
    INFORMATION TO USERS The most advanced technology has been used to photo­ graph and reproduce this manuscript from the microfilm master. UMI films the text directly from the original or copy submitted. Thus, some thesis and dissertation copies are in typewriter face, while others may be from any type of computer printer. The quality of this reproduction is dependent upon the quality of the copy submitted. Broken or indistinct print, colored or poor quality illustrations and photographs, print bleedthrough, substandard margins, and improper alignment can adversely affect reproduction. In the unlikely event that the author did not send UMI a complete manuscript and there are missing pages, these will be noted. Also, if unauthorized copyright material had to be removed, a note will indicate the deletion. Oversize materials (e.g., maps, drawings, charts) are re­ produced by sectioning the original, beginning at the upper left-hand comer and continuing from left to right in equal sections with small overlaps. Each original is also photographed in one exposure and is included in reduced form at the back of the book. These are also available as one exposure on a standard 35mm slide or as a 17" x 23" black and white photographic print for an additional charge. Photographs included in the original manuscript have been reproduced xerographically in this copy. Higher quality 6" x 9" black and white photographic prints are available for any photographs or illustrations appearing in this copy for an additional charge. Contact UMI directly to order. UMI University Microfilms International A Bell & Howell Information Company 3 00 Nortfi Z eeb Road, Ann Arbor, Ml 48106-1346 USA 313/761-4700 800/521-0600 Order Number 9011133 Sudden leaps: The young Alfred Marshall Butler, Robert William, Ph.D.
    [Show full text]
  • Economics - Czech Republic Turnovec, Frantisek
    www.ssoar.info Economics - Czech Republic Turnovec, Frantisek Veröffentlichungsversion / Published Version Sammelwerksbeitrag / collection article Zur Verfügung gestellt in Kooperation mit / provided in cooperation with: GESIS - Leibniz-Institut für Sozialwissenschaften Empfohlene Zitierung / Suggested Citation: Turnovec, F. (2002). Economics - Czech Republic. In M. Kaase, V. Sparschuh, & A. Wenninger (Eds.), Three social science disciplines in Central and Eastern Europe: handbook on economics, political science and sociology (1989-2001) (pp. 50-64). Berlin: Informationszentrum Sozialwissenschaften. https://nbn-resolving.org/urn:nbn:de:0168- ssoar-278768 Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Dieser Text wird unter einer CC BY Lizenz (Namensnennung) zur This document is made available under a CC BY Licence Verfügung gestellt. Nähere Auskünfte zu den CC-Lizenzen finden (Attribution). For more Information see: Sie hier: https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0 https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/deed.de 50 František Turnovec Economics - Czech Republic1 Discussant: Jiří Havel Introduction Until the 1989 “Velvet Revolution”, Czechoslovakia was one of the most conservative socialist countries. Even compared to other former socialist countries in Central Europe, the Czechoslovak economy was exceptional in etatization, with only 4% of GDP produced by the private sector (and 10% produced by the cooperative sector) in 1989. After a promising discussion in the 1960s and then the defeat of the Prague Spring at the end of the 1960s, no significant experiments with the liberalization of the economic and political system were implemented in the 1970s and 1980s, and the rigid party nomenclature running the country had to live with the legacy of post-1968 normalization, when the more liberal segments of the Communist Party and of the Czechoslovak political and intellectual establishment were eliminated, expelled from the country, or isolated and persecuted for two long decades.
    [Show full text]