An Economic Approach to Issues of Religious Freedom

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

An Economic Approach to Issues of Religious Freedom University of Chicago Law School Chicago Unbound Journal Articles Faculty Scholarship 1989 An Economic Approach to Issues of Religious Freedom Richard A. Posner Michael W. McConnell Follow this and additional works at: https://chicagounbound.uchicago.edu/journal_articles Part of the Law Commons Recommended Citation Richard A. Posner & Michael W. McConnell, "An Economic Approach to Issues of Religious Freedom," 56 University of Chicago Law Review 1 (1989). This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at Chicago Unbound. It has been accepted for inclusion in Journal Articles by an authorized administrator of Chicago Unbound. For more information, please contact [email protected]. The University of Chicago Law Review VOLUME 56 NUMBER 1 WINTER 1989 0 1989 by The University of Chicago An Economic Approach to Issues of Religious Freedom Michael W. McConnell & Richard A. Posnert The First Amendment forbids Congress to make any law re- specting an establishment of religion (the "Establishment Clause") or interfering with the free exercise of religion (the "Free Exercise Clause"). Since the critical terms in the clauses are neither self- evident nor defined, and religion is a profoundly emotional subject, it is not surprising that the religion clauses have given rise to enor- mous controversy, both popular and academic, and to a body of case law riven by contradictions and bogged down in slogans and metaphors ("wall of separation," "entanglement," "primary ef- fect"). There is need for a fresh approach. As one component of that approach, we propose using an economic definition of "neu- trality" to determine when government action impinges impermis- sibly on religious choice. The application of economics to issues of religious freedom t Michael McConnell is an assistant professor of law at the University of Chicago Law School; Richard Posner is a judge of the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Seventh Circuit and a senior lecturer at the Law School. McConnell received financial support during the prepara- tion of this article from the Russell Baker Scholars Fund. The authors acknowledge with gratitude the helpful comments of Gary Becker, Frank Easterbrook, David Friedman, Milton Friedman, Douglas Laycock, Ira Lupu, Michael Paulsen, and participants in the Law and Economics Workshop of the University of Chicago Law School, where a previous draft of this paper was given on May 24, 1988. The University of Chicago Law Review [56:1 may seem an eccentric response to the inadequacies of current doc- trine. Religious reasoning and religious faith may seem antithetical to economic reasoning and values; religious freedom may seem un- quantifiable even in principle and therefore beyond the reach of any economic or socio-scientific metric. We shall concede these points at least to the extent of taking no position, as economists or lawyers, on the truths of religion. Instead we shall apply economics to the government regulation of religious institutions. The impor- tant set of regulatory issues that religion has raised makes eco- nomic analysis pertinent to religion.' There are three reasons for believing that economics may be a useful tool for understanding the religion clauses. First, whatever their precise meaning, the religion clauses are plainly concerned with limiting government regulation (promotional as well as re- strictive) of religious activities and institutions; and regulation is an area of central concern to economists. Second, the prevailing view of the religion clauses is that their central purpose is to pre- vent government from either advancing or retarding religion-or, in equivalent economic terms, from subsidizing or taxing reli- gion-and economists are experts in discerning the existence, sometimes heavily disguised, of taxes and subsidies. Third, reli- gious organizations compete with each other and with secular insti- tutions, public and private, to furnish such services as education, consolation, the inculcation of moral values, and the development of a sense of community. These services may confer external bene- fits, meaning benefits that the provider cannot capture in the price for the services. An extensive economic literature deals with com- petition, with the firm (including the nonprofit firm), and with ex- ternalities in general and the external benefits of education in particular. There are also three reasons why many readers may resist the application of economics to religious freedom. None is convincing. First is the tenacious fallacy that the proper domain of economics is confined to profit-maximizing behavior in explicitly "economic" markets. An extensive literature on the economics of nonmarket behavior refutes this view.2 Second, and related, is the paucity of We are not the first to note the similarity between interference with religious freedom and regulatory intervention in economic markets. Dean Kelley, the long time executive di- rector for religious and civil liberty at the National Council of Churches, made the point in his recent essay, Free Enterprise in Religion, or How the Constitution Protects Religion and Religious Freedom, in Robert A. Goldwin and Art Kaufman, eds, How Does the Consti- tution Protect Religious Freedom? 114 (AEI, 1987). 2 See, for example, Gary S. Becker, The Economic Approach to Human Behavior (Chi- 1989] Economics and Religious Freedom economic studies of religion, which lends credence to the supposi- tion that religion must lie outside the domain of economics.' Third, a point already mentioned, is that economics, as well as be- ing scientific and rationalistic in methodology, embodies its own system of values, which are resolutely anti-religious. Viewed nor- matively, economics is a form of applied utilitarianism, or at least closely related to it; and utilitarianism-the philosophy that our duty in life is to maximize the excess of pleasure over pain in the universe-is a secular faith. The questions we seek to answer in this paper, however, are unrelated to issues of faith, and economic theory does not dispute the proposition that an individual may de- rive pleasure or pain from religiously motivated activities, includ- ing self-sacrifice, self-denial, and obedience to religious values. An economic analysis of the religion clauses can have either a descriptive or a normative focus. That is, the analyst can attempt either to determine whether particular government policies have been neutral toward religion and, if not, what the direction of the effect is, or to determine what policy should be adopted in order to achieve consistency with the ideal of neutrality. This paper presents examples of each form. Section I proposes an economi- cally meaningful definition of neutrality. Section II is a normative analysis of aid to parochial schools, an issue arising under the Es- cago, 2d ed 1976); Jack Hirshleifer, The Expanding Domain of Economics, 75 Am Econ Rev 53 (Dec 1985 Supp); Richard A. Posner, The Law and Economics Movement, 77 Am Econ Rev Papers & Proceedings 1 (May 1987). 3 There have been economic studies of religion, but most are very recent (many not yet published) and not widely known. The best known paper, Corry Azzi and Richard Ehren- berg, Household Allocation of Time and Church Attendance, 83 J Pol Econ 27 (1975), ex- plores the hypothesis (for which the paper finds empirical support) that people allocate their time to religious activities in a manner rationally designed to maximize "afterlife util- ity" net of cost. Posner, 77 Am Econ Rev Papers & Proceedings at 9-12 (cited in note 2), contains a brief discussion of the economics of religion, with emphasis on the religion clauses; the present paper both amplifies and modifies the analysis in that paper. Several other recent papers-Gary M. Anderson, Mr. Smith and the Preachers:The Economics of Religion in The Wealth of Nations, 96 J Pol Econ 1066 (1988); Frederick Bold and Brooks B. Hull, Would You Buy a Used Car From This Priest: An Economic Theory of Religion and the Church (Battelle Pacific Northwest Labs & U Mich-Dearborn, Feb 3, 1987)(on file, University of Chicago Law Review office); Laurence R. Tannaccone, A Formal Model of Church and Sect, 94 Am J Soc 5241 (Supp 1988); and Fred S. McChesney, The Efficient Organizationof Religions: A Club-Theoretic Approach (U Chi L Sch, March 1987)(on file, University of Chicago Law Review office)-contain interesting discussions of the economics of religion but do not discuss the regulation of religion, the subject of the present paper. The Posner, McChesney, Iannaccone, and Bold and Hull papers, among them, cite all of the earlier, and very sparse, economic literature on religion. Finally, Laurence R. Iannaccone, Testing Smith's Theory of Religious Markets (Santa Clara U, Dept Econ, Nov 1987)(on file, University of Chicago Law Review office), is an analysis similar to but more extensive than Posner's. The University of Chicago Law Review [56:1 tablishment Clause. Section III is a normative analysis of religion- specific exemptions under the Free Exercise Clause. Section IV analyzes Supreme Court doctrines under the religion clauses to de- termine whether they have been neutral toward religion and what their effect on religious activity has been. I. THEORY A. The Nature of Religious Competition Religious competition can be extraordinarily bitter, divisive, and destructive, especially when religion is mixed with, and used as an instrument of, political struggle. The history of religious in- tolerance persuaded many Enlightenment thinkers,
Recommended publications
  • Economics, Religion and Happiness
    www.ssoar.info Economics, religion and happiness Steiner, Lasse; Leinert, Lisa; Frey, Bruno S. Veröffentlichungsversion / Published Version Zeitschriftenartikel / journal article Zur Verfügung gestellt in Kooperation mit / provided in cooperation with: Rainer Hampp Verlag Empfohlene Zitierung / Suggested Citation: Steiner, L., Leinert, L., & Frey, B. S. (2010). Economics, religion and happiness. Zeitschrift für Wirtschafts- und Unternehmensethik, 11(1), 9-24. https://nbn-resolving.org/urn:nbn:de:0168-ssoar-348987 Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Dieser Text wird unter einer Deposit-Lizenz (Keine This document is made available under Deposit Licence (No Weiterverbreitung - keine Bearbeitung) zur Verfügung gestellt. Redistribution - no modifications). We grant a non-exclusive, non- Gewährt wird ein nicht exklusives, nicht übertragbares, transferable, individual and limited right to using this document. persönliches und beschränktes Recht auf Nutzung dieses This document is solely intended for your personal, non- Dokuments. Dieses Dokument ist ausschließlich für commercial use. All of the copies of this documents must retain den persönlichen, nicht-kommerziellen Gebrauch bestimmt. all copyright information and other information regarding legal Auf sämtlichen Kopien dieses Dokuments müssen alle protection. You are not allowed to alter this document in any Urheberrechtshinweise und sonstigen Hinweise auf gesetzlichen way, to copy it for public or commercial purposes, to exhibit the Schutz beibehalten werden. Sie dürfen dieses Dokument document in public, to perform, distribute or otherwise use the nicht in irgendeiner Weise abändern, noch dürfen Sie document in public. dieses Dokument für öffentliche oder kommerzielle Zwecke By using this particular document, you accept the above-stated vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, aufführen, vertreiben oder conditions of use. anderweitig nutzen. Mit der Verwendung dieses Dokuments erkennen Sie die Nutzungsbedingungen an.
    [Show full text]
  • Was Adam Smith Right About Religious Competition?
    Department of Economics Working Paper Series Was Adam Smith Right About Religious Competition? Peter J. Boettke Joshua C. Hall Kathleen M. Sheehan Working Paper No. 15-47 This paper can be found at the College of Business and Economics Working Paper Series homepage: http://be.wvu.edu/phd_economics/working-papers.htm Was Adam Smith Right About Religious Competition? Peter J. Boettke University Professor of Economics Department of Economics George Mason University MSN 3G4 Fairfax, VA 22030 [email protected] Joshua C. Hall Associate Professor of Economics College of Business and Economics West Virginia University Morgantown, WV 26506 [email protected] Kathleen M. Sheehan Assistant Professor of Economics Heider College of Business Creighton University Omaha, NE 68178 [email protected] Abstract Adam Smith famously argued that increased competition in religion would result in more religious tolerance and that the benefits of competition in the marketplace would also be seen in religious instruction when many religious sects are tolerated. We use a cross-section of a maximum of 167 countries to explore whether increased religious competition results in less governmental regulation of religion and less governmental favoritism of religion. Our measure of religious regulation and favoritism comes from the Association of Religion Data Archives. Our empirical analysis also explores the influence of economic and political factors, including the size of the economy, openness of trade, legal origins, education, the amount of checks
    [Show full text]
  • A Study on Religious Variables Influencing GDP Growth Over Countries
    Religion and Economic Development - A study on Religious variables influencing GDP growth over countries Wonsub Eum * University of California, Berkeley Thesis Advisor: Professor Jeremy Magruder April 29, 2011 * I would like to thank Professor Jeremy Magruder for his valuable advice and guidance throughout the paper. I would also like to thank Professor Roger Craine, Professor Sofia Villas-Boas, and Professor Minjung Park for their advice on this research. Any error or mistake is my own. Abstract Religion is a popular topic to be considered as one of the major factors that affect people’s lifestyles. However, religion is one of the social factors that most economists are very careful in stating a connection with economic variables. Among few researchers who are keen to find how religions influence the economic growth, Barro had several publications with individual religious activities or beliefs and Montalvo and Reynal-Querol on religious diversity. In this paper, I challenge their studies by using more recent data, and test whether their arguments hold still for different data over time. In the first part of the paper, I first write down a simple macroeconomics equation from Mankiw, Romer, and Weil (1992) that explains GDP growth with several classical variables. I test Montalvo and Reynal-Querol (2003)’s variables – religious fragmentation and religious polarization – and look at them in their continents. Also, I test whether monthly attendance, beliefs in hell/heaven influence GDP growth, which Barro and McCleary (2003) used. My results demonstrate that the results from Barro’s paper that show a significant correlation between economic growth and religious activities or beliefs may not hold constant for different time period.
    [Show full text]
  • Religion, Moral Attitudes & Economic Behavior
    Religion, Moral Attitudes & Economic Behavior Isadora Kirchmaiera, Jens Prüferb, & Stefan T. Trautmanna,b* aUniversity of Heidelberg, Germany bTilburg University, the Netherlands November 22, 2016 Abstract: Using data for a representative sample of the Dutch population with information about participants’ religious background, we study the link between religion and moral behavior and attitudes. Religious people are less accepting of unethical behavior and report more volunteering. They report lower preference for redistribution. Religious people are equally likely as non-religious people to betray trust in an anonymous experimental game. Controlling for Christian denominations, we find that Catholics betray less than non-religious people, while Protestants betray more than Catholics and are indistinguishable from the non- religious. We also explore the intergenerational transmission of religiosity effects. KEYWORDS: religion, ethics, redistribution, trust game JEL CODES: A13, Z12 ______________ * Trautmann (corresponding author): Alfred-Weber-Institute, University of Heidelberg, Bergheimer Strasse 58, 69115 Heidelberg, Germany; Phone: +49 6221 54 2952; Fax: +49 6221 54 3592; email: [email protected]; Kirchmaier: Alfred-Weber-Institute, University of Heidelberg, Bergheimer Strasse 58, 69115 Heidelberg, Germany; Phone: +49 6221 54 2951; Fax: +49 6221 54 3592; email: [email protected]; Prüfer: Department of Economics, Tilburg University, P.O. BOX 90153, 5000LE Tilburg, The Netherlands; [email protected], phone: +31.13.466.3250, fax: +31.13.466.3042 1 1. Introduction Thirty-nine percent of the participants in a representative panel of the Dutch population (used in this paper) have some religious affiliation. In contrast, sixty-five percent of those participants’ parents were church members when our participants were aged 15.
    [Show full text]
  • David Aske University of Northern Colorado College of Humanities and Social Sciences (970) 351-1564 Email: [email protected]
    David Aske University of Northern Colorado College of Humanities and Social Sciences (970) 351-1564 Email: [email protected] Education PhD, University of Nebraska-Lincoln, 1992. Area of Study: Economics BS, Mankato State University, 1986. Area of Study: Economics/ Political Science Professional Academic Experience Professor Tenure, University of Northern Colorado. (2016 - Present). Associate Professor Tenure, University of Northern Colorado. (2002 - 2016). Assistant Professor, Tenure-Track, University of Northern Colorado. (1997 - 2002). Assistant Professor, Term, University of Northern Colorado. (1994 - 1997). Instructor, University of Northern Colorado. (1993 - 1994). Instructor/ Teaching and Research Assistant, University of Northern Colorado. (1987 - 1992). RESEARCH, SCHOLARSHIP, AND CREATIVE WORKS Publications Juried Journal Article Corman, R. R., Aske, D. (2018). Developing an Operational Placement Model of Institutions. Journal of Behavioral and Social Sciences, 5(2). [email protected] Aske, D., Connolly, L., Corman, R. (2013). Accessibility or accountability? The rhetoric and reality of no child left behind. Journal of Economics and Economic Education Research, 14(3), 107. Aske, D., Corman, R., Marston, C. (2011). Education Policy and School Segregation: A Study of the Denver Metropolitan Region. Journal of Legal, Ethical and Regulatory Issues, 14(2), 27-35. Aske, D. (2003). How prepared are prospective high school social studies teachers to infuse economics in social studies courses? Journal of Social Studies Research, 27(1), 23. McDaniel, B., Aske, D. (2000). Egg prices, feed costs, and the decision to molt. Poultry science, 79(9), 1242-1245. Report Generated on July 16, 2018 Page 33 of 1526 Aske, D. (2000). Who is teaching economics to Colorado high school students? Journal of Social Studies Research, 24(1), 35.
    [Show full text]
  • Religion and Economic Development
    R000245 religion and economic development The role of religion in economic development warrants a nuanced perspec- tive that integrates economic theory with an understanding of socio-political structures, appreciating the econometric issues that arise in quantifying re- ligious processes. Existing research focuses on religious structures and or- ganizations, state religions, faith-based welfare programmes, the regulation of religion, and the impact of religion on measures of well-being such as income and education. Viewing religion as spiritual capital, with the attend- ant role played by religious network externalities in fostering economic de- velopment, is vital for development policy. Contemporary research in religion and economic development is flourishing, encompassing all these diverse concerns. The number of micro-level social anthropological studies is continually growing. Many of these concentrate on what to the economist may appear odd aspects of society such as ritual and religion y and to which he pays little or no attention. For instance, an understanding of the complex of Hindu religious beliefs as they operate at village level y is directly relevant to the problem of developing India’s economy. This is but one of numerous examples which can be quoted to support the claim that development economists work in the dark unless they ac- quaint themselves with the relevant socio-political literature. (Epstein, 1973, p. 6) How times have changed since Scarlett Epstein first lamented economists’ general neglect of the role of religion in the study of economic development. She need not have been quite so fearful: contemporary economics has seen the light, as it were, increasingly demanding a perspective on religion in order better to understand how it interacts with economic decision making.
    [Show full text]
  • The Case of Rational Choice Is One of a Tribe Within The
    AN IDEA, A TRIBE, AND THEIR CRITICS: RATIONAL CHOICE AND THE SOCIOLOGY OF RELIGION (written for Bryan Turner (ed.): Companion to the Sociology of Religion, Blackwell, c. 2010) David Lehmann A tribe and its leader The case of rational choice is one of a tribe within the broader tribe of sociologists of religion, identified by a distinctive sense of embattlement and by a particular jargon. The writing of the highly prolific founding scholar, Rodney Stark, is interspersed with dismissive, even offensive, remarks and often sarcastic attacks on the secularization thesis and its defenders (Stark and Finke 2000: 60-1), on those who would despise deductive theory or simply do not know what real theory is (Stark 1997), on historians who accept the secularization thesis or versions thereof or who write approvingly of a long-term trend towards liberalization - notably Martin Marty (Finke and Stark 2005: 7-8 and 244-7) - on Emile Durkheim (Stark and Finke 2000: 7), on intellectuals and theologians in general, placed sarcastically in quotes as ‘learned professors’ (Finke and Stark 2005: 87,133) on journal editors who would not publish his papers (Stark 1997: 9- 11), and on structural functionalism (‘more like astrology than astronomy’ (Stark 1997: 5; Lehmann 2001) The list is very long. The school can be said to have announced its birth in Stark and Bainbridge’s A Theory of Religion (1987), and to have its existence confirmed by Stephen Warner in a 1993 paper whose title referred to ‘a new paradigm’ (Warner 1993) and highlighted the use of concepts drawn from economics as its hallmark.
    [Show full text]
  • Religion, Culture, and Economic Performance
    RELIGION, CULTURE, AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE Marcus Noland Senior Fellow Institute for International Economics Abstract The hypothesis that the coefficients on variables of religious affiliation are jointly equal to zero can frequently be rejected at conventional levels of statistical significance (i.e., religion matters), but no robust relationship between adherence to major world religions and national economic performance is uncovered, using both cross-national and subnational data. The results with respect to Islam do not support the notion that it is inimical to growth. On the contrary, virtually every statistically significant coefficient on Muslim population shares reported in this paper—in both cross-country and within-country statistical analyses—is positive. If anything, Islam promotes growth. JEL codes: O40, Z12 Keywords: economic growth, convergence, religion, Islam, India, Malaysia, Ghana Author’s note: I would like to thank Scott Holladay, Paul Karner, and Josh Catlin for essential research assistance. Fred Bergsten, Jari Eloranta, Howard Pack, Dave Richardson, and seminar participants at the Korea Development Institute, the East Asia Economics Association meeting in Kuala Lumpur, Middle East Technical University, and the Institute for International Economics offered helpful comments on an earlier draft. Email address: [email protected] INTRODUCTION Abundant evidence affirms that religious belief affects a wide range of behavioral outcomes (Iannaccone 1998), and religious activity can affect economic performance at the level
    [Show full text]
  • Rational Choice Theory: Implication and Critique
    RATIONAL CHOICE THEORY: IMPLICATION AND CRITIQUE The application of Rational Choice Theory (RCT) to the domain of religion is debatable. The cost-benefit model of RCT does not solely determine individuals’ allegiance to particular religious belief or practice. Hence religious activity is a field where applying RCT may not be adequate. However RCT stands out as the most reliable theory formulated so far in an attempt to objectively understand religious affinity. Rational Choice theory is part of economic theory where maximum benefit for least cost determines human behaviour. All behaviour accounted here is then by nature rational. As for example friendship and marital relations can be understood through RCT. Choice of friend or partner is a measure of benefits over costs. Applying RCT to sociology of religion has led to a reanalysis of the latter. Within which i. RCT explains secularization thesis through new basis, and ii. RCT attempts to provide new understanding in the study of sectarianism and religious movements. Rodney Stark and William Sims Bainbridge first applied the laws of Rational Choice Theory to sociology of religion (1980). It has since then been furthered and modified by them continuously. Roger Finke and Laurence Iannaccone have also significantly contributed to refining RCT. Stark and Bainbridge developed a deductive theory of religion. The theory is based on a general theory of human nature and action. It is closely related to the popular exchange theory. According to exchange theory actors will always try to obtain maximum benefit through every interaction. Every human interaction is treated in the form of an exchange.
    [Show full text]
  • ADAM SMITH's ECONOMICS of the CHURCH Paul Oslington
    ADAM SMITH’S ECONOMICS OF THE CHURCH Paul Oslington Introduction In this paper I will examine Adam Smith’s economics of the church in Book V of the Wealth of Nations within the structure of the book, his 18th century Scottish context, as well as 18th century debates over church establishment, toleration of other religious groups, financial support of clergy, and related issues. I want to be particularly attentive to how the theological framework helps us to appreciate what he was doing in these passages. Smith on theology, religion and human nature In previous work (Oslington 2011a, 2011b, 2012), I have argued that Smith operates within the theological framework of the moderate Calvinism of the Scottish Enlightenment. Newtonian natural theology is an important part of this framework, and such natural theology justified and nourished scientific enquiry, including Smith’s enquiries into emerging commercial society in 18th century Britain (Brooke 1991 is a fuller discussion of the role of natural theology in scientific enquiry in this period). Others such as Jacob Viner (1927), Anthony Waterman (2004) and Lisa Hill (2001) have made similar arguments about the importance of Smith’s theological background. Consistent with this theological framework, Smith avoids discussion of particular doctrines such as the Atonement, the Trinity, etc. The finer points of these doctrines were irrelevant to his purposes in the Theory of Moral Sentiments and Wealth of Nations, and a potentially dangerous distraction from those purposes. The examples of Thomas Aikenhead, executed in Edinburgh in 1697 for blasphemy, and the stalled university career of his friend David Hume, amply illustrate the dangers of engaging in doctrinal controversy in 18th century Scotland.
    [Show full text]
  • The Economics of Religion in India Sriya Iyer
    The Economics of Religion in India Sriya Iyer “Economists are increasingly taking the importance of religion seriously in their work. Sriya Iyer is a leader in the field and has produced a major work which provides a distinctive and original perspective on religion in India. It will be of interest to anyone who wishes to see what an economic approach can bring to discussions of religion.” —Tim Besley, London School of Economics and Political Science Religion has not been a popular target for economic analysis. Yet the tools of economics can offer deep insights into how religious groups compete, deliver social services, and reach out to potential converts— how, in daily life, religions nurture and deploy market power. Sriya Iyer puts these tools to use in an expansive, creative study of India, one of Belknap Press the most religiously diverse countries in the world. cloth • £39.95 • €45.00 ISBN 9780674979642 Iyer explores how growth, inequality, education, technology, and 304 pages • 4 photos, 2 maps, 33 illus. social trends both affect and are affected by religious groups. Her exceptionally rich data—drawn from ten years of research, including a survey of almost 600 religious organizations in seven states—re- veal the many ways religions interact with social welfare and political conflict. After India’s economy was liberalized in 1991, she shows, reli- gious organizations substantially increased their provision of services, compensating for the retreat of the state. Iyer’s data also indicate that religious violence is more common where economic growth is higher, apparently because growth increases inequality, which sec- tarian politicians might exploit to encourage hostility toward other religions.
    [Show full text]
  • Competition and Performance in the Marketplace for Religion: A
    Competition and Performance in the Marketplace for Religion: A Theoretical Perspective by Mukesh Eswaran* University of British Columbia March 2009, Revised June 2010 ABSTRACT This paper, which contributes to the literature that rigorously models religious markets, offers a theoretical framework that incorporates demand and supply sides. The model can accommodate Adam Smith’s view that competition may possibly improve on monopoly’s performance and also David Hume’s opposite view that, because the clergy have an incentive to distort the message of religion, monopoly might possibly improve on competition. Impacts on religiosity of greater diversity and of increased competition in the marketplace for religion are isolated. It is shown that, while greater diversity benefits the devout (as claimed by ‘supply-side’ theorists), increased competition dilutes spiritual standards by encouraging monetary donations at the expense of genuine piety. These opposing effects of diversity and competition help reconcile apparently contradictory empirical findings on the American religious market and also those suggesting European ‘exceptionalism’. Furthermore, the theory offers strong support for the suggestion made in the literature that competition within a monopoly (as in Roman Catholicism) could improve performance. Keywords: religion, competition, monopoly, supply-side theory, Adam Smith JEL Classification Nos: Z12, L1 * Department of Economics, University of British Columbia, Vancouver, B.C., CANADA V6T 1Z1. Email: [email protected]. I thank Doug Allen, Mario Ferrero, Dan Hungerman, Hugh Neary, and Jonathan Rosborough for comments on an earlier draft. I also benefitted from the comments of the participants of the participants of the “Economics and Religion” session of the Canadian Economics Association Meeting at Quebec City, May 2010.
    [Show full text]