Yegor Gaidar Is an Economist and Was Russia's Acting Prime Minister on Whose Watch the First Reforms—Most Notably Price Liberalization—Were Introduced

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Yegor Gaidar Is an Economist and Was Russia's Acting Prime Minister on Whose Watch the First Reforms—Most Notably Price Liberalization—Were Introduced Yegor Gaidar 1 Yegor Gaidar is an economist and was Russia's acting prime minister on whose watch the first reforms—most notably price liberalization—were introduced. In this interview, Gaidar recalls his path as an economist toward embracing markets, his tenure as Russia's first prime minister, and assesses the outcomes of a decade of economic and political reform in Russia. What the Future Holds: The Clandestine Meetings of Soviet Economists INTERVIEWER: Set the stage for what things were like in the late '80s, when you and your colleagues got together at the retreat outside of St. Petersburg. What was the economic situation in your country and what were you as economists thinking might be happening the Soviet Union? And what were you discussing at that weekend? YEGOR GAIDAR: The economic situation by 1986 still on the surface remained stable. Of course there were fundamental long-term problems with the Soviet economy, which were well known. There was an acutely low competitive ability, the ineffective use of resources, a high dependence on income from the transport of energy products, and the obvious worsening state of affairs in the world oil market. To this were added the attempts of the new team of Gorbachev and [Nikolai] Ryzhkov to bring about a political "speeding up" to cause economic growth, which was very dangerous, it seemed to us, because there weren't the objective prerequisites for it. There were a combination of several unpleasant and dangerous processes, still in their early phases, in a general crisis condition of the economy. There was the anti- alcohol campaign, which brought about the crisis in the budget income. There was the attempt to speed up capital investment without having a financial basis for it. [There] was the fall in the price of oil. [There] was the fall in the amount of revenue from unprofitable imports. It was clear that macroeconomic stability, which was ineffective and was a characteristic feature of the Soviet Union, was now in danger, and there would be serious financial problems which, in conditions of an economic deficit, would inescapably lead to sharp tension in the consumer market, to an increase in queues, to a disappearance of goods from the shelves. But all that was at the very beginning. Along the way there was the new team of Gorbachev and Ryzhkov, who obviously wanted and were willing to achieve something. It seemed to us that there was a window of opportunity to correct the economic policy and transfer it to a Yegor Gaidar 2 more rational course, to achieve some kind of reasonably well-thought-out changes which would allow the creation of the basis of a gradual increase in the effectiveness of the Soviet economy, the basis of the introduction of market mechanisms. INTERVIEWER: You felt at the time that socialism could be reformed? YEGOR GAIDAR: We started at the point that political stability in a totalitarian regime would be preserved. We, like the majority of people in the Soviet Union and the West, didn't believe in a short-term political collapse of the totalitarian regime of the Soviet Union. We considered that there was hope for a gradual liberalization of the regime. We considered that there was hope that a politically liberalized regime would at the same time bring about a more well- thought-out industrial and economic policy, something like Hungary in 1958 or like China in 1989. We supposed that these market reforms within the framework of socialism would gradually give a base for a full-scale market economy. We imagined that this would be a long process, and that it would take not a few months but a few years. It would be a gradual reform, a gradual changing, but [creating a] more or less stable totalitarian regime in a gradual transformation to a market—or at least that is the way we saw the political picture in the coming years. As you see, we were seriously mistaken. INTERVIEWER: When you say "we," who are you talking about? YEGOR GAIDAR: I am talking about the majority of those who participated in the seminar in Zmeynaya Gora, and those who later on took an active part in reform in Russia. That would be myself, Anatoly Chubais, Sergei Vasiliev, Pyotr Aven, Sergei Ignatiev, and many others who participated in the seminar. INTERVIEWER: For people who don't know, what kind of people were you? Were you politicians or academics? YEGOR GAIDAR: We were academics or teachers. Some of us worked in the system of the Academy of Sciences. Some worked in universities and institutes. We were 30-year-old researchers or teachers who were involved in the study of the Soviet economy who knew approximately how it functioned, who knew its weak points. Some of us were recruited into Yegor Gaidar 3 giving advice on economic policy—more or less demanded by the authorities—but we were first of all academics. INTERVIEWER: Were your ideas at the time considered radical within the Soviet establishment? YEGOR GAIDAR: Within the framework of the Soviet establishment, our ideas were considered at the time more than radical. They departed from the region of politically acceptable ideas. Some of our discussions were behind closed doors; we didn't even speak of it [to] all the participants of the seminar because we didn't trust everyone to an equal degree. They were not in the full sense of the word revolutionary, but they were far outside the realm of political permissibility. INTERVIEWER: I read a story where it said that you went around the table and said that you will either end up running the country or in jail. Could you tell us about that? YEGOR GAIDAR: It's true. It was a joke of the sort that in Russia we call cabbage. After the official program of the seminar ended, we had some leisure time in the evening and it was there that people were telling jokes. I was one of those who did, and I [talked about] the basic analysis of the development of the crisis of the type of a "crease"—there was such an official report about the crisis of the "crease." I said that in the further development of the crisis of the "crease" there are two scenarios. The first scenario in the development of reform in Russia was called the top end. There I described in detail the role the process of implementing reform in Russia would take and mentioned the very serious role that Chubais would have. The second scenario was called "the crease." That one described the jail term and the kind of food that the participants of the seminar would get with that development of events. The Worldwide Appeal of Socialism and the Command Economy INTERVIEWER: Could you talk about the appeal that communism and state control of the economy had, not just here, but around the world? You saw the flaws in the system, but a lot of people, not just in this country, but around the world, did not. What was the appeal that socialism had? Yegor Gaidar 4 YEGOR GAIDAR: First was the attraction tied to objective problems of the market political economy, particularly its earlier stages. Capitalism and the market at the same time showed, absolutely unprecedented in world economic history, a flow of incomes and benefits and led to the radical change in all social structures and system of relations beginning with social and ending with the family, population structures, demographic structures, such changes that human history didn't know. As the Chinese correctly say, "God forbid that you live in times of great change," like the ones we know now. And the government was always on the crossroads. These changes and the social organizations gave a powerful wave of protest against earlier capitalism. Marxism and socialism were a more consequential and clear embodiment of that process, all the more since the capitalist heaven gave the impression of the boundlessness of human technological possibilities—"See what it is possible for a person to do." At the same time, [in] the background of that mass of unresolved problems in the country, and because it was evident by the institutions that produced this growth and wealth, millions of people were attracted by the idea of negating the global institutions that had produced contemporary economic growth, which produced contemporary imperialism. That's the first thing. To the second was added specific Russian problems in pursuing industrialization. The country was not able to provide the group of institutions which would allow growth. There was no developed economy. There was no well-rooted system of private property. There was no developed civil society dealing with labor and catching up with Europe. And there were major contradictions that Russia went through in the first World War. They were faced with the chaos of revolution, quite often with a totalitarian regime with a powerful ideological defense. Finally, the third [was] socialism with all of its cruelty in the stages of industrialization, [implemented] at the expense of a colossal robbery of the peasants and the millions of innocent people who died when the Kulaks [a supposed wealthy peasant class] were put off their land and died in Stalin's camps. But [the government] supported industrialization, and from a purely economic point of view was in keeping with the path to that stage. Then it would be the foundation of big estates of millions of peasants, where they could get grain and give the peasants short rations and sentence them to starve to death, and with exported grain buy baking factories from America and Europe.
Recommended publications
  • Ukraine in a Geopolitical Game Between the West and the Russian Federation
    Ukraine in a Geopolitical Game between the West and the Russian Federation Wiktor Możgin1 Ph.D. Student, Jagiellonian University in Kraków (Kraków, Poland) E-mail: [email protected] https://orcid.org/0000-0001-5744-8103 The beginning of the 21st century told all observers of international politics about the phenomenon of a rivalry revival between the West and the Russian Federation. Moscow’s resurgent imperialist aspirations are being negated both by the United States and by the countries of the European Union. In the context of world events, Washington loses its hegemonic position in favor of the reviving powers, which Russia is also included to nowadays. The territory of the Ukrainian state is the area in which the active phase of rivalry between the West and the Russian Federation currently takes place. The Donbas war is an exemplification of the Kremlin’s expansionist plans, because by destabilizing the integrity of Ukraine, Russia wants to restore control over this territory. This raises the fundamental issue concerning the subjectivity of Ukraine in the international arena. Therefore, will Ukraine be able to cope with the struggle of the great powers in the context of geopolitical clash, in which it is treated as the object of struggle? The multifaceted nature of this phenomenon is the basis of this article, which presents the situation of Ukraine in the context of the geopolitical rivalry between the West and the Russian Federation. Keywords: geopolitics; objectivity of the state; Ukrainian-Russian war; destabilization; Ukraine Received: October 23, 2018; accepted: November 19, 2018 Ukrainian Policymaker, Volume 3, 2018: 36-42.
    [Show full text]
  • Exorcising Stalin's Ghost
    TURNING BACK TOTALITARIANISM: Exorcising Stalin’s Ghost Matthew R. Newton The Evergreen State College N e w t o n | 1 "During times of universal deceit, telling the truth becomes a revolutionary act." --George Orwell The death of Joseph Stalin left the Soviet Union in a state of dynastic confusion, and the most repressive elements of the society he established remained. After Nikita Khrushchev secured power in the mid-1950s, he embarked on a campaign to vanquish these elements. While boldly denouncing Stalin’s cult of personality and individual authority in his ‘Secret Speech’ of 1956, he failed to address the problems of a system that allowed Stalin to take power and empowered legions of Stalin-enablers. Khrushchev’s problem was complex in that he wanted to appease the entire Communist Party of the Soviet Union in 1956 and yet legitimize his position of power. The level of embeddedness of Stalinism in the Soviet Union was the biggest obstacle for Khrushchev. Characterized with the “permanent” infrastructure of the Soviet Union, Stalin’s autocratic rule was intertwined with virtually all aspects of Soviet life. These aspects can be broken down into four elements: Stalin’s status as an absolute champion of Communism, and his cult of personality; the enormous amount of propaganda in all forms that underlined Stalin as the “protector” of the Soviet Union during threat and impact of foreign war, and the censorship of any content that was not aligned with this mindset; the necessity and place of the Gulag prison camp in the Soviet economy, and how it sustained itself; and the transformation of Soviet society into something horrifically uniform and populated with citizens whom were universally fearful of arrest and arbitrary repression.
    [Show full text]
  • Russian Political, Economic, and Security Issues and U.S. Interests
    Order Code RL33407 Russian Political, Economic, and Security Issues and U.S. Interests Updated July 28, 2008 Stuart D. Goldman Specialist in Russian and Eurasian Affairs Foreign Affairs, Defense, and Trade Division Russian Political, Economic, and Security Issues and U.S. Interests Summary Dmitry Medvedev, Putin’s chosen successor and long-time protege, was elected President of the Russian Federation on March 2, 2008 with about 70% of the vote. Medvedev, formerly First Deputy Prime Minister, announced during the campaign that if elected, he would propose Putin as Prime Minister. Medvedev was inaugurated as President on May 7; Putin was confirmed as Prime Minister the next day. The Kremlin’s Unified Russia party had previously swept the parliamentary election (December 2, 2007), winning more than two-thirds of the seats in the Duma. U.S. and EU observers criticized both elections as unfairly controlled by the governing authorities. Nevertheless, Putin’s widespread popularity in Russia led many to conclude that the election results corresponded to Russian public opinion. The economic upturn that began in 1999 is continuing. The GDP, domestic investment, and the general living standard have been growing impressively after a decade-long decline, fueled in large part by profits from oil and gas exports. There is a budget surplus, and the ruble is stable. Some major problems remain: 15% of the population live below the poverty line; foreign investment is relatively low; inflation is rising; and crime, corruption, capital flight, and unemployment remain high. Russian foreign policy has grown more self-confident, assertive and anti- western, fueled by its perceived status as an “energy superpower.” Russia’s drive to reassert dominance in and integration of the former Soviet states is most successful with Belarus and Armenia but arouses opposition in Georgia, Ukraine, Azerbaijan, and Moldova.
    [Show full text]
  • The Russia You Never Met
    The Russia You Never Met MATT BIVENS AND JONAS BERNSTEIN fter staggering to reelection in summer 1996, President Boris Yeltsin A announced what had long been obvious: that he had a bad heart and needed surgery. Then he disappeared from view, leaving his prime minister, Viktor Cher- nomyrdin, and his chief of staff, Anatoly Chubais, to mind the Kremlin. For the next few months, Russians would tune in the morning news to learn if the presi- dent was still alive. Evenings they would tune in Chubais and Chernomyrdin to hear about a national emergency—no one was paying their taxes. Summer turned to autumn, but as Yeltsin’s by-pass operation approached, strange things began to happen. Chubais and Chernomyrdin suddenly announced the creation of a new body, the Cheka, to help the government collect taxes. In Lenin’s day, the Cheka was the secret police force—the forerunner of the KGB— that, among other things, forcibly wrested food and money from the peasantry and drove some of them into collective farms or concentration camps. Chubais made no apologies, saying that he had chosen such a historically weighted name to communicate the seriousness of the tax emergency.1 Western governments nod- ded their collective heads in solemn agreement. The International Monetary Fund and the World Bank both confirmed that Russia was experiencing a tax collec- tion emergency and insisted that serious steps be taken.2 Never mind that the Russian government had been granting enormous tax breaks to the politically connected, including billions to Chernomyrdin’s favorite, Gazprom, the natural gas monopoly,3 and around $1 billion to Chubais’s favorite, Uneximbank,4 never mind the horrendous corruption that had been bleeding the treasury dry for years, or the nihilistic and pointless (and expensive) destruction of Chechnya.
    [Show full text]
  • The Origins of United Russia and the Putin Presidency: the Role of Contingency in Party-System Development
    The Origins of United Russia and the Putin Presidency: The Role of Contingency in Party-System Development HENRY E. HALE ocial science has generated an enormous amount of literature on the origins S of political party systems. In explaining the particular constellation of parties present in a given country, almost all theoretical work stresses the importance of systemic, structural, or deeply-rooted historical factors.1 While the development of social science theory certainly benefits from the focus on such enduring influ- ences, a smaller set of literature indicates that we must not lose sight of the crit- ical role that chance plays in politics.2 The same is true for the origins of politi- cal party systems. This claim is illustrated by the case of the United Russia Party, which burst onto the political scene with a strong second-place showing in the late 1999 elec- tions to Russia’s parliament (Duma), and then won a stunning majority in the 2003 elections. Most accounts have treated United Russia as simply the next in a succession of Kremlin-based “parties of power,” including Russia’s Choice (1993) and Our Home is Russia (1995), both groomed from the start primarily to win large delegations that provide support for the president to pass legislation.3 The present analysis, focusing on United Russia’s origin as the Unity Bloc in 1999, casts the party in a somewhat different light. When we train our attention on the party’s beginnings rather than on what it wound up becoming, we find that Unity was a profoundly different animal from Our Home and Russia’s Choice.
    [Show full text]
  • Privatization in Russia: Catalyst for the Elite
    PRIVATIZATION IN RUSSIA: CATALYST FOR THE ELITE VIRGINIE COULLOUDON During the fall of 1997, the Russian press exposed a corruption scandal in- volving First Deputy Prime Minister Anatoli Chubais, and several other high- ranking officials of the Russian government.' In a familiar scenario, news organizations run by several bankers involved in the privatization process published compromising material that prompted the dismissal of the politi- 2 cians on bribery charges. The main significance of the so-called "Chubais affair" is not that it pro- vides further evidence of corruption in Russia. Rather, it underscores the im- portance of the scandal's timing in light of the prevailing economic environment and privatization policy. It shows how deliberate this political campaign was in removing a rival on the eve of the privatization of Rosneft, Russia's only remaining state-owned oil and gas company. The history of privatization in Russia is riddled with scandals, revealing the critical nature of the struggle for state funding in Russia today. At stake is influence over defining the rules of the political game. The aim of this article is to demonstrate how privatization in Russia gave birth to an oligarchic re- gime and how, paradoxically, it would eventually destroy that very oligar- chy. This article intends to study how privatization influenced the creation of the present elite structure and how it may further transform Russian decision making in the foreseeable future. Privatization is generally seen as a prerequisite to a market economy, which in turn is considered a sine qua non to establishing a democratic regime. But some Russian analysts and political leaders disagree with this approach.
    [Show full text]
  • Does Breaking Through the •Œfinal Glass Ceilingâ•Š Really Pave The
    Does Breaking Through the “Final Glass Ceiling” Really Pave the Way for Subsequent Women to Become Heads of State? 1 Does Breaking Through the “Final Glass Ceiling” Really Pave the Way for Subsequent Women to Become Heads of State? By Katherine Rocha, Joseph Palazzo, Rebecca Teczar and Roger Clark Rhode Island College Abstract Women’s ascension to the role of national president or prime minister of any country is a relatively new phenomenon in world history. The first woman to break the “final glass ceiling,” Sirinavo Bandaranaike of Ceylon (Sri Lanka today), did it in 1960, just 58 years ago. Since then, the ceiling has been broken in about 83 nations worldwide, but we still know little about what it takes for women to achieve such national leadership roles. Previous research (e.g., Jalalzai, 2013; Skard, 2015) has pointed to the importance of family connections, political turmoil, and the nature of a country’s political system. But only one study (Jalalzai, 2013) provided quantitative, cross-national support for any of these observations. Our paper replicates Jalalzai’s analysis, done using data from the first decade of the twenty-first century, with data from the second decade. We find that there have been dramatic changes over time. We find that family connections are now no more useful for explaining women’s rise to presidencies and prime ministerial positions than men’s; that, in fact, women are now more likely to rise in politically stable nation states than in fragile ones. And, perhaps most importantly, women are much more likely to ascend to the highest positions in countries where they have already broken the “final glass ceiling.” Keywords: final glass ceiling, women presidents, women prime ministers Introduction In a course on the Sociology of Gender we had learned that, while such a ceiling might exist in Following Hillary Clinton’s loss in the 2016 U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • PERESTROIKA PROPAGANDA in the SOVIET FOREIGN PRESS by Matthew Brown
    CONTRIBUTOR BIO MATTHEW BROWN graduated from Cal Poly, San Luis Obispo in June of 2013 with a Bachelor of Arts in History and a minor in Geography & Anthropology. His academic in- terests include the Cold War, the Soviet Union, and revolutionary political theory. Matthew is currently working as a substitute teacher while pursuing a Social Science teaching credential at CSU Long Beach, and is exploring his op- tions for teaching English abroad next school year. He plans on pursuing a Master’s degree in Russian and/or Eastern European history, and would like to eventually teach at the uni- versity level. ECHOES OF A DYING STATE: PERESTROIKA PROPAGANDA IN THE SOVIET FOREIGN PRESS By Matthew Brown “Perestroika means mass initiative. It is the comprehensive devel- opment of democracy, socialist self-government, encouragement of initiative and creative endeavor, improved order and discipline, more glasnost, criticism and self-criticism in all spheres of our society. It is utmost respect for the individual and consideration for personal dignity.”230 The collapse of the Soviet Union marked the end of one of the most tumultuous and volatile periods in modern history. The Soviet Union was not destroyed by a foreign military invasion, nor was it torn apart by civil war. The events that resulted in one of the most powerful countries the world has ever seen literally signing itself out of existence were official government policy, heavily promoted by the Communist Party as the pinnacle of Soviet ideology, and praised by the Soviet intelligentsia as a clear path to a prosperous society. The perestroika and glasnost reforms, instituted under Mikhail Gorbachev, represent the final 230 Mikhail Gorbachev, Perestroika: New Thinking for Our Country and the World (New York: Harper & Row, 1987), 34.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 27. Prime Minister Act 1975. Certified On
    Chapter 27. Prime Minister Act 1975. Certified on: / /20 . INDEPENDENT STATE OF PAPUA NEW GUINEA. Chapter 27. Prime Minister Act 1975. ARRANGEMENT OF SECTIONS. 1. Interpretation. “Acting Prime Minister” “the Deputy Prime Minister” 2. Deputy Prime Minister. 3. Acting Prime Minister. 4. Allowances payable to Acting Prime Minister. 5. Suspension from office of the Prime Minister. INDEPENDENT STATE OF PAPUA NEW GUINEA. AN ACT entitled Prime Minister Act 1975, Being an Act– (a) to implement Section 143 (Acting Prime Minister) of the Constitution by providing for– (i) a Deputy Prime Minister; and (ii) the Deputy Prime Minister or another Minister to be the Acting Prime Minister in certain circumstances; and (b) to provide for the suspension from office of the Prime Minister pending an investigation for the purposes of Section 142(5)(c) (the Prime Minister) of the Constitution. 1. INTERPRETATION. In this Act, unless the contrary intention appears– “Acting Prime Minister” means an Acting Prime Minister appointed by Section 3(1) or under Section 3(2); “the Deputy Prime Minister” means the Deputy Prime Minister appointed under Section 2. 2. DEPUTY PRIME MINISTER. (1) An office of Deputy Prime Minister is hereby established. (2) The Deputy Prime Minister shall be appointed by the Head of State, acting with, and in accordance with, the advice of the Prime Minister. (3) The Deputy Prime Minister– (a) shall be dismissed from office by the Head of State if the Prime Minister recommends his dismissal to the Head of State; and s. 3. Prime Minister 9999 (b) ceases to hold office if he ceases to be a Minister.
    [Show full text]
  • 9, 1980 1 ENROUTE to TOKYO, JAPAN I-NE '3 Jr‘U' I 12:10 P.M.WEDNESDA
    THE WHITE MJUSE THE DAlLY DIARY OF PRESIDENT JIMMY CARTER LtX.‘lC&i OHE I MO.. Z+al\;, k’r.t I WSOARD AIR FORCE ONE 1lT.Y 9, 1980 1 ENROUTE TO TOKYO, JAPAN I-NE '3 jr‘u' i 12:10 p.m.WEDNESDA ACTIVITY Air Force one arrived at Haneda International Airport, Tokyo, Japan. I’ The President was greeted by: Masayoshi Ito, Acting Prime Minister of Japan Ii Michael J. Mansfield, Ambassador of the U.S. to Japan I1. Mrs. Michael J. (Maureen) Mansfield I Nobuyuki Nakasthima, Chief of Protocol, Japan. i- f 12:18 The President, escorted by Ambassador Mansfield, went to the speaking platform, I 12:20 12:23 The President addressed the crowd gathered for his arrival in Japan. Members of the press 12:26 The President went to his motorcade. He was accompanied by: 1 Edmund S. Muskie, Secretary of State Ambassador Mansfield I: George R. Ariyoshi (D-Hawaii) I? 12:26 12:51 The Presidential party motored from Haneda International Airport I. to the residence of Ambassador Mansfield. I 1 ;i .'I The President went to his suite. I i f I 1:37 The President returned to his motorcade. He was accompanied by:! Secretary Muskie I I Ambassador Mansfield Ii Governor Ariyoshi The Presidential party motored from the Ambassador's residence t to the Budokan Sports Arena. I i The President was greeted by: 1 Saburo Okita, Minister of Foreign Affairs of Japan Keizo Obuchi, Minister of State in Charge of ! Prime Minister's Office, Japan Japanese Protocol Officer I * lt47 The President went to his seat.
    [Show full text]
  • Democracy and Institutional Design in Russia
    Democracy and Institutional Design in Russia EUGENE HUSKEY he stunning political comeback of Boris Yeltsin serves as a reminder of the T vital role of the individual in politics. A disengaged and irresolute president through much of his first term, Yeltsin revived himself in time to capture the sup- port of the nation in the 1996 presidential elections. These elections also high- lighted the many informal sources of power in Russia that lie beyond the consti- tution. One of the most influential of these was the media. Through a careful manipulation of the tone and content of campaign coverage, Yeltsin’s backers managed to portray the contest between candidates as a referendum on good ver- sus evil. Personality, informal politics, and circumstance—these are the forces that come to mind during periods of political transition. But a country’s institutional arrangements also shape its development, often in profound though less obvious ways. Put simply, Russia’s particular pattern of institutions and rules has favored certain political outcomes over others.1 The decision to adopt an unusual variant of semi-presidentialism, for example, has had fateful consequences for the sta- bility and efficacy of the new regime.2 This article examines the impact of semi- presidentialism on Russia’s post-communist transition as well as the ways in which the logic of semi-presidentialism has adapted to the distinct circumstances and culture of Russian politics.3 The Origins of Semi-Presidentialism in Russia, 1989-1991 At the end of the 1980s, faced with broad-based resistance to reform within the Communist Party apparatus, Mikhail Gorbachev sought alternative institutional arrangements that would at once enhance regime legitimacy and offer the leader an additional base outside of the party.4 Invoking a variant of the Leninist slogan “All Power to the Soviets,”5 Gorbachev settled upon a reinvigoration of the mori- bund legislature.
    [Show full text]
  • Deputy Prime Ministers of Australia
    Deputy Prime Ministers of Australia The official title of Deputy Prime Minister of Australia was created in 1968 and is given to the second-highest ranked member of the government. The Deputy Prime Minister is always a senior member of the Cabinet with a ministerial portfolio of their own. The Deputy Prime Minister is usually responsible for serving as Acting Prime Minister in the absence of the Prime Minister. However, this is Hon. Sir John McEwen merely convention. The Deputy Prime Minister does not automatically Deputy Prime Minister 1968 – 1971 become Prime Minister in the event the position becomes vacant – in National Library of Australia such a case, the governing party elects a new leader to become Prime Minister. On the three occasions when a serving Prime Minister has died, the unofficial Deputy Prime Minister was temporarily commissioned as Prime Minister in their own right, but none of the three – Earle Page (1939), Frank Forde (1945) or Sir John McEwen (1968) was subsequently elected to lead the government. Originally the position was an unofficial or honorary position. John Gorton was the first to formally establish the position, appointing Sir John McEwen as Deputy Prime Minister on 10 January 1968. While previous governments had had an obvious ‘second-in-command’, they were not known as Deputy Prime Minister. All Prime Ministers since Gorton have appointed an official deputy who is commissioned in that role by the Governor-General. No. Deputy Prime Minister Term of office Party Prime Minister 1. Sir John McEwen 10.01.1968 – 5.2.1971 Country Party Gorton/McMahon 2.
    [Show full text]