Property Rights and Finance Author(S): Simon Johnson, John Mcmillan, Christopher Woodruff Source: the American Economic Review, Vol

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Property Rights and Finance Author(S): Simon Johnson, John Mcmillan, Christopher Woodruff Source: the American Economic Review, Vol American Economic Association Property Rights and Finance Author(s): Simon Johnson, John McMillan, Christopher Woodruff Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 92, No. 5 (Dec., 2002), pp. 1335-1356 Published by: American Economic Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3083253 Accessed: 02/03/2010 11:22 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=aea. Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The American Economic Review. http://www.jstor.org PropertyRights and Finance By SIMON JOHNSON,JOHN MCMILLAN, AND CHRISTOPHERWOODRUFF* Whichis the tighter constrainton private sector investment:weak property rights or limited access to externalfinance? From a survey of new firms in post-communist countries, we find that weak property rights discouragefirms from reinvestingtheir profits, even when bank loans are available. Whereproperty rights are relatively strong,firms reinvest theirprofits; where they are relativelyweak, entrepreneursdo not want to investfrom retained earnings. (JEL D23, P23) Property rights are fundamental: entrepre- Levine,1997; Raghuram Rajan and Luigi Zingales, neurs will not invest if they expect to be unable 1998). Is external finance, in addition to secure to keep the fruits of their investment. Country- property rights, necessary for entrepreneursto level studies consistently show that less secure invest, or is property-rightssecurity all that is property rights are correlated with lower ag- needed? Broad cross-countrystudies cannot an- gregate investment and slower economic swer this question because effective protection growth (Stephen Knack and Philip Keefer, for propertyrights is positively correlatedwith 1995; Paolo Mauro, 1995; Jakob Svensson, the use of externalfinance. For example, Rafael 1998; Daron Acemoglu et al., 2001). The mi- La Porta et al. (1997, 1998, 2000) show more croeconomic evidence is more limited, but Tim- external finance is available when there is a othy Besley (1995), for example, finds in Ghana stronger legal system in general and more ef- a significant link between property rights and fective protection of investors in particular, investment. while Asli Demirguii-Kuntand Vojislav Mak- Secure propertyrights may be necessary for simovic (1998) find that firms invest more from entrepreneurialinvestment, but are they suffi- externalfunds in countrieswith secure property cient? External finance could also matter for rights. investment and growth, for if bank credit is not Recent experience in EasternEurope and the available it may be hard for entrepreneursto former Soviet Union offers an experiment that take advantage of new opportunities.There is can help disentangle the effects of property evidence that a well-functioning financial sys- rights and external finance. Although all these tem contributesto investmentand growth (Ross former communist countries have relatively weak institutional environments, there is con- siderablevariation in the extent to which prop- * Johnson: Sloan School of Management,MIT, 50 Me- erty rights are protected.For example, Timothy morial Drive, Cambridge, MA 02142 (e-mail: sjohnson@ Frye and Shleifer (1997) and Shleifer (1997) mit.edu);McMillan: GraduateSchool of Business, Stanford evidence that the Russian 518 provide government University, Memorial Way, Stanford, CA 94305 acts like a entre- (e-mail: [email protected]);Woodruff: Grad- "grabbinghand," discouraging uate School of InternationalRelations and Pacific Studies, preneursfrom investing, while the Polish gov- University of California-San Diego, La Jolla, CA 92093 ernment does not. In general, property rights (e-mail: [email protected]).We thank Timothy Besley, have proven more secure in Polandthan in other Bengt Holmstrom, Takeo Hoshi, James Rauch, Andrei of Eastern and the former Soviet and two referees for Todd parts Europe Shleifer, anonymous comments, Union. Within Mitton for help with the Worldscope data, Mark Schanker- countries, also, there is variation man for help in facilitating the surveys, and the European in both the perceived security of propertyrights Bank for Reconstructionand Development for funding the and in the access to bank credit. Given these surveys in Poland, Slovakia, and Romania,and the National countries' banking systems, small firms are able Council for Soviet and East EuropeanResearch for funding to borrow if can the surveys in Russia and Ukraine. For support, Johnson only they provide adequate thanks the MIT EntrepreneurshipCenter and McMillan collateral.Owning collateralis thereforea good thanks the StanfordGraduate School of Business. proxy for at least having the possibility to 1335 1336 THEAMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER2002 borrow. Firm-level evidence from these post- credit leads to more investment for these firms. communist countries thereforeallows us to de- Secure propertyrights are therefore also suffi- termine whether secure propertyrights are (a) cient for investment. In fact, the firms in our necessary, (b) sufficient, or (c) necessary and sample with weak perceived propertyrights and sufficient for investment by entrepreneurs. high levels of unreinvestedprofits do not want Our data come from a 1997 survey of re- to borrow. cently formed and relatively small manufactur- Part of the explanation for these results is ing firms in five transition countries: Poland, that, for the firms in our sample, retainedearn- Romania, Slovakia, Ukraine, and Russia. The ings have consistently been large, and therefore perceived securityof propertyrights and the use have been a source of potential investment of bankcredit vary considerablyboth across and funds. Many of these new firms are extremely within these countries.As an outcome variable, profitablebecause the relatively hostile business we focus on the amountentrepreneurs choose to environment creates barriers to entry and be- reinvest out of their profits. This provides a cause the partially reformed economy offers robust measure of investment, as our survey entrepreneurslucrative unfilled niches.2 High work indicates, that is comparableacross firms. profits mean that entrepreneurshave the re- Our approachhas two parts, both of which sources they need for expansion, without need- are designed to be straightforwardto implement ing to borrow. The issue is not whether in countries where standardfinancial informa- entrepreneurshave enough resources,but rather tion is hard to obtain. First, we explain the data whether they want to invest their retainedearn- we were able to obtain, putting particularem- ings or instead consume these earnings,perhaps phasis on what our investigation shows is a outside the country. reasonableway to ask questions about sensitive At the low level of institutionaldevelopment financialinformation and property-rightsissues of the countries in our sample, secure property (Section I).1 Second, we test whether secure rights are both necessary and sufficient to in- propertyrights are sufficient for investment by duce investment by entrepreneurs.The avail- entrepreneurs(Sections II and III). ability of bank loans surely mattersfor growth, The entrepreneursin our sample reinvest less but perhaps only once propertyrights are per- of their retained earnings when they perceive ceived to be secure. If propertyrights are inse- their propertyrights to be insecure, irrespective cure, it is immaterialwhether or not finance is of whether they own the collateral that is gen- available.Our findingsthus add empiricaldetail erally needed to obtain credit. This effect is to the view that certainmarket-supporting insti- large. Those entrepreneursin our sample with tutions will work only after other institutions the least secure propertyrights invest nearly 40 have been built (McMillan, 1997; Shleifer and percent less of their profits than those with the Vishny, 1998). most secure propertyrights (specifically, entre- Because our survey covers only firms already preneurs with the least secure perceived prop- in existence, we cannot infer anythingabout the erty rights reinvest 32 percent of their profits, relativeimportance of propertyrights and finance while those with the most secure reinvest 56 for potential entrepreneurswho are considering percent). Secure property rights are necessary entry. We focus instead on entrepreneurswho for the entrepreneursin our sample to take are already in business with small-scale opera- full advantageof opportunitiesto invest. More- tions. Our question
Recommended publications
  • Introduction: Economics and Transition Erik Berglöf and Gérard Roland
    1 Introduction: Economics and Transition Erik Berglöf and Gérard Roland The transition from socialism to capitalism at the end of the twentieth century was one of the most significant events in the world economy since industrialization. Fundamental institutional change affected about a quarter of the population of the world. Few, if any, historical events have involved such change for so many over a short period of time. The transition process phases out the equally massive economic and political experiment embarked on earlier in the twentieth century. The socialist economic model with central planning was initially promoted as an alternative to capitalism, itself the result of gradual, small-scale and decentralized experimentation over the centuries. During the first decades of socialism, this challenge was taken very seri- ously, but by the late 1980s few doubts remained that the socialist economic system was in the long run dynamically less efficient than capitalism. The system gener- ated little innovation, but led to widespread shortages and poor product quality. Over the course of several decades, growth gradually came to a halt (for a definitive analysis of the socialist economic system, see Kornai, 1992). Nevertheless, even to experts, the transition came as a surprise. A few years ear- lier, in the USA, the CIA and others assembled the best sovietologists to discuss the prospects of the Soviet economic system. In 1983, they published a book with the title, The Soviet Economy Toward the Year 2000 (Bergson and Levine, 1983). With- out the early political changes initiated by Mikhail Gorbachev, largely triggered, it seems, by a deterioration in revenues from oil exports, the Soviet Union might still have existed in the year 2000.
    [Show full text]
  • The Central Role of Entrepreneurs in Transition Economies
    Journal of Economic Perspectives—Volume 16, Number 3—Summer 2002—Pages 153–170 The Central Role of Entrepreneurs in Transition Economies John McMillan and Christopher Woodruff ll sorts of small enterprises boomed in the countryside, as if a strange army appeared suddenly from nowhere,” remarked Deng Xiaoping, reflecting A in 1987 on the first eight years of China’s economic reforms (Zhao, 1996, p. 106). These startup firms drove China’s reform momentum; they were arguably the single main source of China’s growth. But their rapid emergence, Deng said, “was not something I had thought about. Nor had the other comrades. This surprised us.” The reformers had not foreseen the key to their own reforms. The other ex-communist economies had similar experiences. As in China, new firms were drivers of reform. They strengthened the budding market economy by creat- ing jobs, supplying consumer goods, mobilizing savings and ending the state firms’ monopoly. As in China, also, the reformers usually did not anticipate the force of entry. Of the two routes to a private sector—privatizing the existing firms and creating new ones—the policy debates focused almost exclusively on the former. Little attention was given to what reform policies would foster entry. Dusan Triska, for example, the architect of Czechoslovakia’s privatization program, said priva- tization “is not just one of the many items on the economic program. It is the transformation itself ” (Nellis, 2001, p. 32). It is not surprising that those who had spent their lives under central planning did not foresee the impact of entrepre- neurship, but few analysts from the West predicted it either.
    [Show full text]
  • Experimental Evidence from Sri Lanka
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics De Mel, Suresh; McKenzie, David J.; Woodruff, Christopher Working Paper Business training and female enterprise start-up, growth, and dynamics: Experimental evidence from Sri Lanka IZA Discussion Papers, No. 6896 Provided in Cooperation with: IZA – Institute of Labor Economics Suggested Citation: De Mel, Suresh; McKenzie, David J.; Woodruff, Christopher (2012) : Business training and female enterprise start-up, growth, and dynamics: Experimental evidence from Sri Lanka, IZA Discussion Papers, No. 6896, Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA), Bonn This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/67188 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made
    [Show full text]
  • 2Nd Annual Meeting on the Economics of Risky Behaviors (AMERB)
    CEPR/IGC Conference on Labour Market in Developing Countries 4-5 May 2017 Venue: London School of Economics 1st Floor Conference Room, 1.04., 32 Lincoln’s Inn Fields, London WC2A 3PH Programme Thursday 4 May 10:00 - 10:20 Registration and coffee Session 1: Education 10:20 - 11:10 Labour Market Frictions and Schooling Investments *Luca Flabbi (University of North Carolina) joint with Matteo Bobba (Toulouse School of Economics) and Santiago Levy (Inter-American Development Bank) 11:10 – 12:00 Gender Stereotypes in the Classroom and Effects of Achievement *Sule Alan (University of Essex) joint with Seda Ertac (Koc University) and Ipek Mumcu (University of Essex) 12:00 - 13:00 Buffet lunch Session 2: Field Experiments In Labour Markets 13:00 - 13:50 Labour Drops: Experimental Evidence on the Return to Additional Labour in Microenterprises *David J. McKenzie (World Bank and CEPR) joint with Suresh de Mel (University of Peradeniya, Sri Lanka) and Christopher Woodruff (University of Oxford and CEPR) 13:50 - 14:40 Anonymity or Distance? Experimental Evidence on Obstacles to Youth Employment Opportunities *Stefano Caria (University of Oxford) joint with Girum Abebe (Ethiopian Development Research Institute), Simon Franklin (London School of Economics), Simon Quinn (University of Oxford), Marcel Fafchamps (Stanford University and CEPR), Paolo Falco (OECD), and Forhad Shilpi (World Bank) 14:40 - 15:00 Coffee break Session 3: Structural Change 15:00 - 15:50 Re-evaluating Agricultural Productivity Gaps with Longitudinal Microdata *Marieke Kleemans
    [Show full text]
  • The Central Role of Entrepreneurs in Transition Economies
    Journal of Economic Perspectives—Volume 16, Number 3—Summer 2002—Pages 153–170 The Central Role of Entrepreneurs in Transition Economies John McMillan and Christopher Woodruff ll sorts of small enterprises boomed in the countryside, as if a strange army appeared suddenly from nowhere,” remarked Deng Xiaoping, re� ecting A in 1987 on the � rst eight years of China’s economic reforms (Zhao, 1996, p. 106). These startup � rms drove China’s reform momentum; they were arguably the single main source of China’s growth. But their rapid emergence, Deng said, “was not something I had thought about. Nor had the other comrades. This surprised us.” The reformers had not foreseen the key to their own reforms. The other ex­communist economies had similar experiences. As in China, new � rms were drivers of reform. They strengthened the budding market economy by creat­ ing jobs, supplying consumer goods, mobilizing savings and ending the state � rms’ monopoly. As in China, also, the reformers usually did not anticipate the force of entry. Of the two routes to a private sector—privatizing the existing � rms and creating new ones—the policy debates focused almost exclusively on the former. Little attention was given to what reform policies would foster entry. Dusan Triska, for example, the architect of Czechoslovakia’s privatization program, said priva­ tization “is not just one of the many items on the economic program. It is the transformation itself ” (Nellis, 2001, p. 32). It is not surprising that those who had spent their lives under central planning did not foresee the impact of entrepre­ neurship, but few analysts from the West predicted it either.
    [Show full text]
  • Why Do Firms Hide? Bribes and Unofficial Activity After Communism
    No. 2105 WHY DO FIRMS HIDE? BRIBES AND UNOFFICIAL ACTIVITY AFTER COMMUNISM Simon Johnson, John McMillan and Christopher Woodruff TRANSITION ECONOMICS ISSN 0265-8003 WHY DO FIRMS HIDE? BRIBES AND UNOFFICIAL ACTIVITY AFTER COMMUNISM Simon Johnson, John McMillan and Christopher Woodruff Discussion Paper No. 2105 March 1999 Centre for Economic Policy Research 90–98 Goswell Rd London EC1V 7RR Tel: (44 171) 878 2900 Fax: (44 171) 878 2999 Email: [email protected] This Discussion Paper is issued under the auspices of the Centre’s research programme in Transition Economics. Any opinions expressed here are those of the author(s) and not those of the Centre for Economic Policy Research. Research disseminated by CEPR may include views on policy, but the Centre itself takes no institutional policy positions. The Centre for Economic Policy Research was established in 1983 as a private educational charity, to promote independent analysis and public discussion of open economies and the relations among them. It is pluralist and non-partisan, bringing economic research to bear on the analysis of medium- and long-run policy questions. Institutional (core) finance for the Centre has been provided through major grants from the Economic and Social Research Council, under which an ESRC Resource Centre operates within CEPR; the Esmée Fairbairn Charitable Trust; and the Bank of England. These organizations do not give prior review to the Centre’s publications, nor do they necessarily endorse the views expressed therein. These Discussion Papers often represent preliminary or incomplete work, circulated to encourage discussion and comment. Citation and use of such a paper should take account of its provisional character.
    [Show full text]
  • Private Order Under Dysfunctional Public Order
    Michigan Law Review Volume 98 Issue 8 2000 Private Order Under Dysfunctional Public Order John McMillan Stanford Graduate School of Business Christopher Woodruff University of California at San Diego Follow this and additional works at: https://repository.law.umich.edu/mlr Part of the Commercial Law Commons, Contracts Commons, and the Law and Economics Commons Recommended Citation John McMillan & Christopher Woodruff, Private Order Under Dysfunctional Public Order, 98 MICH. L. REV. 2421 (2000). Available at: https://repository.law.umich.edu/mlr/vol98/iss8/2 This Symposium is brought to you for free and open access by the Michigan Law Review at University of Michigan Law School Scholarship Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Michigan Law Review by an authorized editor of University of Michigan Law School Scholarship Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. PRIVATE ORDER UNDER DYSFUNCTIONAL PUBLIC ORDER John McMillan* Christopher Woodruff** The freedom and extent of human commerce depend entirely on a fidelity with regard to promises.1 INTRODUCTION Businesspeople need contractual assurance. Most transactions are less straightforward than a cash sale of an easily identifiable item. Buyers need assurance of the quality of what they are purchasing, and sellers need assurance that bills will be paid. The legal system may not always be available to provide contractual assurance - and when the law is dysfunctional, private order might arise in its place. Many developing and transition economies
    [Show full text]
  • Promoting Property Rights in Russia: the Value of Private Solutions
    PROMOTING PROPERTY RIGHTS IN RUSSIA: THE VALUE OF PRIVATE SOLUTIONS An NCEEER Working Paper by Timothy Frye Columbia University The National Council for Eurasian and East European Research University of Washington Box 353650 Seattle, WA 98195 [email protected] http://www.nceeer.org/ TITLE VIII PROGRAM Project Information* Principal Investigator: Timothy Frye NCEEER Contract Number: 823-02 Date: October 16, 2009 Copyright Information Individual researchers retain the copyright on their work products derived from research funded through a contract or grant from the National Council for Eurasian and East European Research (NCEEER). However, the NCEEER and the United States Government have the right to duplicate and disseminate, in written and electronic form, reports submitted to NCEEER to fulfill Contract or Grant Agreements either (a) for NCEEER’s own internal use, or (b) for use by the United States Government, and as follows: (1) for further dissemination to domestic, international, and foreign governments, entities and/or individuals to serve official United States Government purposes or (2) for dissemination in accordance with the Freedom of Information Act or other law or policy of the United States Government granting the public access to documents held by the United States Government. Neither NCEEER nor the United States Government nor any recipient of this Report may use it for commercial sale. * The work leading to this report was supported in part by contract or grant funds provided by the National Council for Eurasian and East European Research, funds which were made available by the U.S. Department of State under Title VIII (The Soviet-East European Research and Training Act of 1983, as amended).
    [Show full text]
  • Download PDF (51.3
    - 39 - APPENDIX EXTENSION OF THE MODEL TO THREE PARTIES TO PRODUCTION Suppose that production of the M-good requires joining outside capital K, labor L, and an entrepreneur. The joining is organized the following way. First, entrepreneurs raise K, and establish a company. Then, the company hires workers. Sticking to the Grossman-Hart-Moore framework, suppose that in establishing a company, a fraction K of K becomes specific to the relationship. The parameter K is meant to capture institutional quality in the La Porta et al. sense. Suppose also that when the company hires a worker, a fraction C of its value becomes specific as well. This parameter can be thought of as capturing the conditions in the labor market as well as technological features of the production process. In both relationships, we assume once again that the ex post surplus is split equally between the parties. Suppose that the entrepreneur's outside option is fixed at zero. Because K becomes partly specific to the entrepreneur, its participation constraint will hold with equality. Given its ex ante opportunity cost r, it will pin down the required return that the company must earn on each unit of K, R: 1 1 − Krx Rx − 1 − Krx rx, 2 or, R 1 r. K Since the company becomes partly specific to L, its participation constraint will provide a joint restriction on w, r, and pM that is analogous to equation (11): p y w 1 Rx w 1 1 rx. M C C K The reward to labor in the M-sector is then: w +ψ C +ψ K rx,)1( A )1( which corresponds to equation (12).
    [Show full text]
  • Why Do Firms Hide?
    Journal of Public Economics 76 (2000) 495±520 www.elsevier.nl/locate/econbase Why do ®rms hide? Bribes and unof®cial activity after communism Simon Johnsona,* , Daniel Kaufmann b , John McMillan c , Christopher Woodruffd aSloan School of Management, MIT, Cambridge, MA 02142, USA bThe World Bank, Washington, DC, USA cStanford University, Stanford, CT, USA dUniversity of California, San Diego, CA, USA Abstract Our survey of private manufacturing ®rms ®nds the size of hidden `unof®cial' activity to be much larger in Russia and Ukraine than in Poland, Slovakia and Romania. A comparison of cross-country averages shows that managers in Russia and Ukraine face higher effective tax rates, worse bureaucratic corruption, greater incidence of ma®a protection, and have less faith in the court system. Our ®rm-level regressions for the three Eastern European countries ®nd that bureaucratic corruption is signi®cantly associated with hiding output. 2000 Elsevier Science S.A. All rights reserved. Keywords: Corruption; Taxation; Legal system; Unof®cial economy JEL classi®cation: H26; K42; O17 1. Introduction A substantial part of output in many developing and post-communist transition economies goes unreported. This `unof®cial economy' impedes economic growth *Corresponding author. Tel.: 1 1-617-253-8412; fax: 1 1-617-253-2660. E-mail address: [email protected] (S. Johnson) 0047-2727/00/$ ± see front matter 2000 Elsevier Science S.A. All rights reserved. PII: S0047-2727(99)00094-8 496 S. Johnson et al. / Journal of Public Economics 76 (2000) 495 ±520 in various ways. First, ®rms operating underground cannot make use of market- supporting institutions like the courts and so may invest too little, as de Soto (1989) argues occurs in Peru.
    [Show full text]
  • When Is Capital Enough to Get Female Microenterprises Growing? Evidence from a Randomized Experiment in Ghana
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHEN IS CAPITAL ENOUGH TO GET FEMALE MICROENTERPRISES GROWING? EVIDENCE FROM A RANDOMIZED EXPERIMENT IN GHANA Marcel Fafchamps David McKenzie Simon R. Quinn Christopher Woodruff Working Paper 17207 http://www.nber.org/papers/w17207 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 July 2011 We are grateful to Markus Mobius and conference and seminar participants at Auvergne, Bristol, the IPA Microfinance conference, Madrid, Michigan, Oxford, Paris, Stern (NYU), Tilburg, Leuven, the World Bank, and Microsoft Research, Cambridge for useful comments. The authors thank Caroline Kouassiaman for outstanding work as project coordinator, and Innovations for Poverty Action for their support on the ground. Financial support from the World Bank’ Gender Action Plan and Research Budget is gratefully acknowledged. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer- reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2011 by Marcel Fafchamps, David McKenzie, Simon R. Quinn, and Christopher Woodruff. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. When is capital enough to get female microenterprises growing? Evidence from a randomized experiment in Ghana Marcel Fafchamps, David McKenzie, Simon R. Quinn, and Christopher Woodruff NBER Working Paper No. 17207 July 2011 JEL No. O12,O16 ABSTRACT Standard models of investment predict that credit-constrained firms should grow rapidly when given additional capital, and that how this capital is provided should not affect decisions to invest in the business or consume the capital.
    [Show full text]
  • Working Paper No. 102 Entrepreneurs in Economic Reform
    Working Paper No. 102 Entrepreneurs in Economic Reform by John McMillan* Christopher Woodruff** July 2001 Stanford University John A. and Cynthia Fry Gunn Building 366 Galvez Street | Stanford, CA | 94305-6015 * Graduate School of Business, Stanford University ** Graduate School of International Relations and Pacific Studies, University of California, San Diego; Visiting Researcher (fall of 2000), Center for Research on Economic Development and Policy Reform, Stanford University Entrepreneurs in Economic Reform John McMillan and Christopher Woodruff* August 31, 2001 Abstract: New firms have been created at a striking rate the transition countries. The entrants generated welfare gains by creating jobs, supplying consumer goods, constraining the market power of the state firms, and building reform momentum. We summarize evidence on the relative role of entrepreneurs and the state in economic reform. Early in the transition, the government’s main contribution to entrepreneurship was to avoid impeding the entrepreneurs’ self help. Later, the entrepreneurs came to need positive assistance from the state: institutions to support contracting and finance. 1. Introduction Reflecting on the first eight years of China’s economic reforms, Deng Xiaoping remarked that “all sorts of small enterprises boomed in the countryside, as if a strange army appeared suddenly from nowhere.” The rapid growth of the new firms “was not something I had thought about. Nor had the other comrades. This surprised us.”1 These new firms arguably were the single most important contributor to China’s reform success. They drove China’s reform momentum and economic growth. As Deng said, however, their emergence was “not the achievement of our central government.” The reformers had failed to foresee, by Deng’s admission, the pivotal feature of their own reforms.
    [Show full text]