Monetary Policy During the Recession (Brookings Papers on Economic

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Monetary Policy During the Recession (Brookings Papers on Economic WILLIAM POOLE Brown University Monetary Policy during the Recession THE DEPTH of the currentrecession makes it clearex post that government stabilizationpolicy shouldhave been less contractionaryin 1974.In fact, both monetaryand fiscal policy were extremelycontractionary not only relativeto the needs of a decliningeconomy but also relativeto policy duringthe 1972-73boom. During 1974,the full employmentbudget sur- plus rose sharplyand monetaryexpansion slowed markedly.My task in this reportis to analyzethe monetarypart of recentstabilization policies. A sharpdeceleration of moneygrowth (both M1and M2)since mid-1974 is evident in figure 1.1 Economistsgenerally agree that money growthin the secondhalf of 1974 was too low, but split over the propositionthat moneygrowth in the firsthalf-6.2 percentfor M1from December 1973 to June1974-was aboutright.2 As I argueda yearago, an M1 growthtarget of about6 percentwas appropriateon the basis of informationavailable in earlyand mid-1974.3 Therefore, I applaudthe FederalReserve for restrain- Note: I want to thank the FederalReserve Bank of Boston for researchsupport and especiallyRuth Kupfer and Redenta de Leon of the Bank for researchassistance and typing.The views expressed,however, are mine and do not necessarilyreflect those of the FederalReserve Bank of Boston. 1. I am inclinedto believethat M2 is more closely relatedto businessconditions than M1, but have decidedto use M1 in most of my analysis because the Federal Reserve tends to emphasizeit and because the differencesin the recentbehavior of the two mea- sures are relativelyminor. 2. All growth rates in this report are continuously compounded annual rates of growth. 3. William Poole, "Reflections on U.S. MacroeconomicPolicy," BPEA (1:1974), pp. 233-46. 123 124 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1975 Figure 1. Money Stock and Selected Interest Rates, Monthly, January1971-March 1975 Billions of dollars (ratio scale) Billions of dollars (ratio scale) 325 300 . 600 275275 10 -]550 MeMa,~-(rightscale) ~ 250 500 225 Z 450 200 400 Percent 13 12 10 Federaliunds f rate 9. 7 Yield on Aaa corporate bonds 6 S 4 3 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 Sources: Federal Reserve Bulletin, various issues. a. Ms plus time deposits except large certificates of deposit. b. Currency plus demand deposits at commercial banks. WilliamPoole 125 ing moneygrowth and permittinginterest rates to rise sharplyin the first half of 1974. The next sectionis devotedto a defenseof the propositionthat a 6 per- cent M1 growthwas appropriatein 1974.There follows an analysisof the FederalReserve's explanation of monetarypolicy in the second half of 1974.The reportconcludes with a few generalcomments on whatthe Fed- eral Reserveshould do, givenrecent experience. Judgingthe Appropriatenessof MonetaryPolicy Policymakingis inherentlya problemof decisionmakingunder uncer- tainty;an ex post analysisof policy ought,therefore, to be cast in the same terms.Judging the performanceof policymakersrequires that somethingbe said about preferencesfor possible outcomes,especially those relatedto unemploymentand inflation;about the effect of events known to policy- makerswhen decisionsare made on the odds of various outcomes;and about the impacton the odds of policy adjustments. Althoughopinions differ on the relativecosts of unemploymentand in- flation,I know of no statementsby publicofficials suggesting that the cur- rentrapid reduction in inflationhas been worththe cost in termsof unem- ployment.On the contrary,public officialshave stressedrepeatedly that inflationmust be reducedslowly in orderto avoida depression,and that the unavoidablecost was a modestrise in unemployment. Differencesover the role of preferencesarise largely because of varying views of how the worldworks. I assignvery little importanceto inflation per se but feel that the economicand politicaldynamics of inflationcom- bine to rule out any significantchance of simplystabilizing the rate of in- flation at 1973 or 1974levels. Furtheracceleration of inflationvery likely would have generatedvastly increasedodds of deeper recessionin the future. I basicallyagree, then, with Milton Friedman'sargument that the real choiceis not betweeninflation and unemployment,but betweenunemploy- ment now and unemploymentlater.4 This is an empiricalstatement-cor- rect or incorrect-about the way the world works and not about prefer- ences. Nevertheless,the tradeoffbetween unemployment now and unem- 4. Milton Friedman,"The Role of Monetary Policy," AmericaniEconlomic Review, vol. 58 (March 1968), pp. 1-17 (especially7-11). 126 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1975 ploymentlater applies only within a certainrange. After a point, more unemploymentnow clearlybrings more unemploymentlater, again for a mixtureof economicand politicalreasons. When firmsgo bankruptand are dismantledor fall far behindin their capitalspending, an irreversible loss occurs,and productionand employmentcannot be returnedeasily to full employmentlevels. In addition, some governmentactions taken in responseto unemployment,as well as in responseto inflation,reduce eco- nomicefficiency and interferewith the returnto full employment. I also agreewith the Modigliani-Papademosargument that the desirable path for the economyis one involvingthe fastestpossible recovery con- sistentwith maintaining low odds of overshootingfull employmentand re- acceleratinginflation.5 I differwith Modiglianiand Papademosnot over goalsbut overthe odds of achievingany giventarget path for the economy. Thispoint will be discussedfurther in my commentson currentpolicy, but it is centralto my analysisof FederalReserve policy in 1974. THE EVIDENCE OF 1974 Whateverlessons evolve from the sharprise in unemploymentin late 1974and early1975, an analysisof monetarypolicy in 1974should be lim- ited to the evidenceavailable at the time the policy decisionswere made. The consensusforecast in early 1974 was for a flat economy.Pessimists arguedthat a couple of quartersof decliningreal gross nationalproduct werelikely and optimiststhought a recessionwould be avoided.No one foresaweither a deep recessionor a boom.6 By June the forecastsbecame, if anything,a bit more optimistic.The disruptiveoil embargohad been lifted, the unemploymentrate was the same as in January,and the index of industrialproduction actually had risena bit sinceApril. From what is known now, the businesscycle peak may be tentatively placedat November1973. However, after a significantdecline in the early monthsof 1974,the economyremained basically on a plateauuntil autumn. As the yearcontinued, the consensusforecast was reviseddownward, but 5. See their paperin this issue. 6. It is fair to say that a year ago many economists were concernedover the possi- bility that maintaininga 6 percent trend of money growth would lead to a prolonged periodof economicslack, with unemploymentremaining above 6 percent,and perhaps risingslowly, for severalyears. No one I know, however,assigned any significantproba- bility to a 1975 unemploymentrate of the currentmagnitude. WilliamPoole 127 this plateauled most forecastersto believe that any furthercontraction wouldbe relativelymild. Indeed,even as late as fall, manyforecasters an- ticipatedonly a moderaterecession. The "TypicalQuarterly Forecast for 1975"-the medianquarterly forecast among twenty-three surveyed by the FederalReserve Bank of Richmond-had a quarterlypattern of unemploy- mentfor 1975of 6.8, 7.0, 7.2, and7.3 percent,respectively.7 Since seventeen of the twenty-threeforecasts are dated December 1, 1974,or later,it is clear that the magnitudeof impendingunemployment was completelyunfore- seen by the professionalforecasters, or at least not foreseenwith enough confidenceto be includedin the publishedforecasts. Criticsof monetarypolicy in the firsthalf of 1974point to threereasons why unusuallyrapid money growthwould have been appropriate:exog- enous shocksin the form of the oil embargo,and shortharvests in 1973; the sidewaysmovement of the economy;and the rapidescalation of interest rates. Shocks.Those who emphasizethe importanceof the recentshocks from farmand fuel productshave not, as far as I know, referredto similarpast episodesin supportof theirposition favoring a more expansionarymone- tarypolicy. The KoreanWar experience presents some intriguing parallels, at least on the surface.Raw materialand farm pricessurged sharply up- wardfollowing the outbreakof the war,transferring income to foreignpro- ducersof primaryproducts. However, most of this income transferwas probablysaved in the shortrun, and the U.S. balanceon goodsand services (excludingmilitary) declined by $4.3 billionbetween 1949 and 1950.Even the high-employmentfederal budget surplus rose untillate in 1950.But the KoreanWar shock did not producea recessionand the 1950acceleration of money growthhas to be viewed, in retrospect,with regret ratherthan pleasure. My pointis not to offerthe KoreanWar experience as a counter-example, but ratherto arguethat the case for a more expansionarypolicy in 1974 oughtto rest on morethan simplyfeeding an assumedsurge in the aggre- gate pricelevel into a standardmacro model. The underlyingmicro be- havioralequations reflect the holding of inventoriesand precautionary balancesby individualeconomic units preciselyin order to cushion the effectsof unforeseendisturbances. The advocatesof a policy responseto the oil shockought, therefore, to displaysome evidencethat outsizemicro 7. FederalReserve Bank of Richmond,Business Forecasts, 1975 (February 1975), p. 5. 128 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity,
Recommended publications
  • Monetary Policy in Economies with Little Or No Money
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MONETARY POLICY IN ECONOMIES WITH LITTLE OR NO MONEY Bennett T. McCallum Working Paper 9838 http://www.nber.org/papers/w9838 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 July 2003 This paper was prepared for presentation at the December 16-17, 2002, meeting of the Hong Kong Economic Association. I am indebted to Marvin Goodfriend, Lok Sang Ho, Allan Meltzer, and Edward Nelson for helpful comments and suggestions. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the National Bureau of Economic Research ©2003 by Bennett T. McCallum. All rights reserved. Short sections of text not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit including © notice, is given to the source. Monetary Policy in Economies with Little or No Money Bennett T. McCallum NBER Working Paper No. 9838 July 2003 JEL No. E3, E4, E5 ABSTRACT The paper's arguments include: (1) Medium-of-exchange money will not disappear in the foreseeable future, although the quantity of base money may continue to decline. (2) In economies with very little money (e.g., no currency but bank settlement balances at the central bank), monetary policy will be conducted much as at present by activist adjustment of overnight interest rates. Operating procedures will be different, however, with payment of interest on reserves likely to become the norm. (3) In economies without any money there can be no monetary policy. The relevant notion of a general price level concerns some index of prices in terms of a medium of account.
    [Show full text]
  • The Labor Force Experience of Women from 'Generation X'
    Women from ‘‘Generation X' The labor force experience of women from ‘Generation X’ Women aged 25 to 34 years in 2000 participated in the labor force in greater proportions, were more educated, earned more, and generally enjoyed more labor market benefits than their counterparts 25 years earlier; moreover, the “earnings gap” between young women and men narrowed substantially over the period Marisa DiNatale uring the 1960s and 1970s, legislation years had completed 4 or more years of col- and and changing social mores dramatically lege, compared with 18 percent 25 years Stephanie Boraas Daltered the choices young women had earlier. about their futures. Girls growing up during this • Young women have substantially closed period were influenced both by the conventions the “earnings gap” with their male coun- of their parents’ generation and by the new op- terparts since 1979 (the first year for which portunities that were becoming available to them. comparable earnings data are available In contrast, girls born in later years grew up in an from the CPS). They earned 82 percent as era in which women often were expected to com- much as young men in 2000 for full-time bine market work1 with family responsibilities. work, compared with 68 percent in 1979. Consequently, women who were aged 25 to 34 years in 2000 had a markedly different relation- • Married women aged 25 to 34 years—par- ship to the labor market than did their counter- ticularly those who had children—were far parts in 1975. more likely to be in the labor force in 2000 The first part of this article focuses on the than 25 years earlier.
    [Show full text]
  • FOMC Statement
    For release at 2 p.m. EDT July 28, 2021 The Federal Reserve is committed to using its full range of tools to support the U.S. economy in this challenging time, thereby promoting its maximum employment and price stability goals. With progress on vaccinations and strong policy support, indicators of economic activity and employment have continued to strengthen. The sectors most adversely affected by the pandemic have shown improvement but have not fully recovered. Inflation has risen, largely reflecting transitory factors. Overall financial conditions remain accommodative, in part reflecting policy measures to support the economy and the flow of credit to U.S. households and businesses. The path of the economy continues to depend on the course of the virus. Progress on vaccinations will likely continue to reduce the effects of the public health crisis on the economy, but risks to the economic outlook remain. The Committee seeks to achieve maximum employment and inflation at the rate of 2 percent over the longer run. With inflation having run persistently below this longer-run goal, the Committee will aim to achieve inflation moderately above 2 percent for some time so that inflation averages 2 percent over time and longer‑term inflation expectations remain well anchored at 2 percent. The Committee expects to maintain an accommodative stance of monetary policy until these outcomes are achieved. The Committee decided to keep the target range for the federal funds rate at 0 to 1/4 percent and expects it will be appropriate to maintain this target range until labor market conditions have reached levels consistent with the Committee’s assessments of maximum employment and inflation has risen to 2 percent and is on (more) For release at 2 p.m.
    [Show full text]
  • Money in the Economy: a Post-Keynesian Perspective
    Money in the Economy: A post-Keynesian perspective Jo Michell, SOAS, University of London Fundamental Uncertainty • Originates in Keynes’ theory of probability • “non-ergodic” = distinction between known probability distribution (known unknowns) and unknowable future (unknown unknowns) • Risk and uncertainty • Conventions and animal spirits • Decisions on investment and saving “Is our expectation of rain, when we start out for a walk, always more likely than not, or less likely than not, or as likely as not? I am prepared to argue that on some occasions none of these alternatives hold, and that it will be an arbitrary matter to decide for or against the umbrella. If the barometer is high, but the clouds are black, it is not always rational that one should prevail over the other in our minds, or even that we should balance them, though it will be rational to allow caprice to determine us and to waste no time on the debate” (Keynes, Treatise on Probability) Money • Mechanism to cope with uncertainty • Three functions: store of value, unit of account, means of payment • Liquidity • Means to transfer purchasing power in order to meet contractual obligations • Contrast with Classical view: money as a means of transaction. Why hold money? “Money, it is well known, serves two principal purposes. By acting as a money of account it facilitates exchange without its being necessary that it should ever itself come into the picture as a substantive object. In this respect it is a convenience which is devoid of significance or real influence. In the second place, it is a store of wealth.
    [Show full text]
  • Dangers of Deflation Douglas H
    ERD POLICY BRIEF SERIES Economics and Research Department Number 12 Dangers of Deflation Douglas H. Brooks Pilipinas F. Quising Asian Development Bank http://www.adb.org Asian Development Bank P.O. Box 789 0980 Manila Philippines 2002 by Asian Development Bank December 2002 ISSN 1655-5260 The views expressed in this paper are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views or policies of the Asian Development Bank. The ERD Policy Brief Series is based on papers or notes prepared by ADB staff and their resource persons. The series is designed to provide concise nontechnical accounts of policy issues of topical interest to ADB management, Board of Directors, and staff. Though prepared primarily for internal readership within the ADB, the series may be accessed by interested external readers. Feedback is welcome via e-mail ([email protected]). ERD POLICY BRIEF NO. 12 Dangers of Deflation Douglas H. Brooks and Pilipinas F. Quising December 2002 ecently, there has been growing concern about deflation in some Rcountries and the possibility of deflation at the global level. Aggregate demand, output, and employment could stagnate or decline, particularly where debt levels are already high. Standard economic policy stimuli could become less effective, while few policymakers have experience in preventing or halting deflation with alternative means. Causes and Consequences of Deflation Deflation refers to a fall in prices, leading to a negative change in the price index over a sustained period. The fall in prices can result from improvements in productivity, advances in technology, changes in the policy environment (e.g., deregulation), a drop in prices of major inputs (e.g., oil), excess capacity, or weak demand.
    [Show full text]
  • Cy Martin Collection
    University of Oklahoma Libraries Western History Collections Cy Martin Collection Martin, Cy (1919–1980). Papers, 1966–1975. 2.33 feet. Author. Manuscripts (1968) of “Your Horoscope,” children’s stories, and books (1973–1975), all written by Martin; magazines (1966–1975), some containing stories by Martin; and biographical information on Cy Martin, who wrote under the pen name of William Stillman Keezer. _________________ Box 1 Real West: May 1966, January 1967, January 1968, April 1968, May 1968, June 1968, May 1969, June 1969, November 1969, May 1972, September 1972, December 1972, February 1973, March 1973, April 1973, June 1973. Real West (annual): 1970, 1972. Frontier West: February 1970, April 1970, June1970. True Frontier: December 1971. Outlaws of the Old West: October 1972. Mental Health and Human Behavior (3rd ed.) by William S. Keezer. The History of Astrology by Zolar. Box 2 Folder: 1. Workbook and experiments in physiological psychology. 2. Workbook for physiological psychology. 3. Cagliostro history. 4. Biographical notes on W.S. Keezer (pen name Cy Martin). 5. Miscellaneous stories (one by Venerable Ancestor Zerkee, others by Grandpa Doc). Real West: December 1969, February 1970, March 1970, May 1970, September 1970, October 1970, November 1970, December 1970, January 1971, May 1971, August 1971, December 1971, January 1972, February 1972. True Frontier: May 1969, September 1970, July 1971. Frontier Times: January 1969. Great West: December 1972. Real Frontier: April 1971. Box 3 Ford Times: February 1968. Popular Medicine: February 1968, December 1968, January 1971. Western Digest: November 1969 (2 copies). Golden West: March 1965, January 1965, May 1965 July 1965, September 1965, January 1966, March 1966, May 1966, September 1970, September 1970 (partial), July 1972, August 1972, November 1972, December 1972, December 1973.
    [Show full text]
  • The Interaction Between Monetary and Fiscal Policy: Insights from Two Business Cycles in Israel
    The interaction between monetary and fiscal policy: insights from two business cycles in Israel Kobi Braude and Karnit Flug1 Abstract Comparing the two significant recessions Israel experienced over the last decade, we highlight the importance of sustained fiscal discipline and credible monetary policy during normal times for expanding the set of policy options available at a time of need. In the first recession Israel was forced to conduct a contractionary fiscal and monetary policy, whereas in the second one it was able to pursue an expansionary policy. The difference in the effect of the policy response between the two recessions is sizable: it exacerbated the first recession while it helped to moderate the second one. Keywords: Fiscal policy, fiscal discipline, public debt, monetary policy, counter-cyclical policy, business cycles JEL classification: E52, E62, H6 1 Bank of Israel. We thank Stanley Fischer and Alon Binyamini for helpful comments and Noa Heymann for her research assistance. BIS Papers No 67 205 Introduction Over the last decade Israel experienced two significant business cycles. The monetary and fiscal policy response to the recession at the end of the decade was very different from the response to recession of the early 2000s. In the earlier episode, following a steep rise in the budget deficit and a single 2 percentage point interest rate reduction, policy makers were forced to make a sharp reversal and conduct a contractionary policy in the midst of the recession. In the second episode, monetary and fiscal expansion was pursued until recovery was well under way. This note examines the factors behind the difference in the policy response to the two recession episodes.
    [Show full text]
  • Resolutions Adopi'ed and Decisions Taken by the Security Council in 1973
    RESOLUTIONS ADOPI'ED AND DECISIONS TAKEN BY THE SECURITY COUNCIL IN 1973 Part I. Questions considered by the Security Council under its responsibility for the maintenance of international peace and security THE SITUATION IN NAMIBIA1 Decisions At the 1684th meeting, on 16 January 1973, the the provisional rules of procedure of the Security Coun­ President informed the Council that, as a result of con­ cil, to a delegation of the United Nations Council. for sultations held among members of the Council, a con­ Namibia, composed of the President of the United sensus had been reached to appoint the representatives Nations Council for Namibia, and the representatives of Peru and the Sudan to fill the vacancies that had of Burundi, Indonesia and Mexico. occurred in ,the Group es,tablished in accordance with At its 1757th meeting, on 11 December 1973, the resolution 309 (1972) as a result of the expiration of Council decided to invite the representative of Nigeria the terms of office of ,the delegations of Argentina and ,to participate, without vote, in the discussion of the Somalia. question. At its 1756th meeting, on 10 December 1973, the At its 1758th meeting, on 11 December 1973, the Council decided to invite the representatives of Niger Council decided to invite the representative of Saudi and Somalia ito participate, without vote, in the discus­ Arabia to participate, without vote, in the discussion of sion of the item entitled: the question. "The situation in Namibia: At •the same meeting, the Council decided, at the re­ "(a) Letter dated 4 December 1973 from the quest of the representatives of Guinea, Kenya and the Permanent Representatives of Glllinea, Sudan,4 to extend an invitation, under rule 39 of the Kenya and the Sudan to the United Nations provisional ruJes of procedure of the Security Council, addressed to the President of the Seourity to Mr.
    [Show full text]
  • Recent Monetary Policy in the US
    Loyola University Chicago Loyola eCommons School of Business: Faculty Publications and Other Works Faculty Publications 6-2005 Recent Monetary Policy in the U.S.: Risk Management of Asset Bubbles Anastasios G. Malliaris Loyola University Chicago, [email protected] Marc D. Hayford Loyola University Chicago, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://ecommons.luc.edu/business_facpubs Part of the Business Commons Author Manuscript This is a pre-publication author manuscript of the final, published article. Recommended Citation Malliaris, Anastasios G. and Hayford, Marc D.. Recent Monetary Policy in the U.S.: Risk Management of Asset Bubbles. The Journal of Economic Asymmetries, 2, 1: 25-39, 2005. Retrieved from Loyola eCommons, School of Business: Faculty Publications and Other Works, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/ j.jeca.2005.01.002 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Publications at Loyola eCommons. It has been accepted for inclusion in School of Business: Faculty Publications and Other Works by an authorized administrator of Loyola eCommons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-Noncommercial-No Derivative Works 3.0 License. © Elsevier B. V. 2005 Recent Monetary Policy in the U.S.: Risk Management of Asset Bubbles Marc D. Hayford Loyola University Chicago A.G. Malliaris1 Loyola University Chicago Abstract: Recently Chairman Greenspan (2003 and 2004) has discussed a risk management approach to the implementation of monetary policy. This paper explores the economic environment of the 1990s and the policy dilemmas the Fed faced given the stock boom from the mid to late 1990s to after the bust in 2000-2001.
    [Show full text]
  • Greenspan's Conundrum and the Fed's Ability to Affect Long-Term
    Research Division Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Paper Series Greenspan’s Conundrum and the Fed’s Ability to Affect Long- Term Yields Daniel L. Thornton Working Paper 2012-036A http://research.stlouisfed.org/wp/2012/2012-036.pdf September 2012 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS Research Division P.O. Box 442 St. Louis, MO 63166 ______________________________________________________________________________________ The views expressed are those of the individual authors and do not necessarily reflect official positions of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, the Federal Reserve System, or the Board of Governors. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Papers are preliminary materials circulated to stimulate discussion and critical comment. References in publications to Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Working Papers (other than an acknowledgment that the writer has had access to unpublished material) should be cleared with the author or authors. Greenspan’s Conundrum and the Fed’s Ability to Affect Long-Term Yields Daniel L. Thornton Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Phone (314) 444-8582 FAX (314) 444-8731 Email Address: [email protected] August 2012 Abstract In February 2005 Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan noticed that the 10-year Treasury yields failed to increase despite a 150-basis-point increase in the federal funds rate as a “conundrum.” This paper shows that the connection between the 10-year yield and the federal funds rate was severed in the late 1980s, well in advance of Greenspan’s observation. The paper hypothesize that the change occurred because the Federal Open Market Committee switched from using the federal funds rate as an operating instrument to using it to implement monetary policy and presents evidence from a variety of sources supporting the hypothesis.
    [Show full text]
  • FEDERAL FUNDS Marvin Goodfriend and William Whelpley
    Page 7 The information in this chapter was last updated in 1993. Since the money market evolves very rapidly, recent developments may have superseded some of the content of this chapter. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Richmond, Virginia 1998 Chapter 2 FEDERAL FUNDS Marvin Goodfriend and William Whelpley Federal funds are the heart of the money market in the sense that they are the core of the overnight market for credit in the United States. Moreover, current and expected interest rates on federal funds are the basic rates to which all other money market rates are anchored. Understanding the federal funds market requires, above all, recognizing that its general character has been shaped by Federal Reserve policy. From the beginning, Federal Reserve regulatory rulings have encouraged the market's growth. Equally important, the federal funds rate has been a key monetary policy instrument. This chapter explains federal funds as a credit instrument, the funds rate as an instrument of monetary policy, and the funds market itself as an instrument of regulatory policy. CHARACTERISTICS OF FEDERAL FUNDS Three features taken together distinguish federal funds from other money market instruments. First, they are short-term borrowings of immediately available money—funds which can be transferred between depository institutions within a single business day. In 1991, nearly three-quarters of federal funds were overnight borrowings. The remainder were longer maturity borrowings known as term federal funds. Second, federal funds can be borrowed by only those depository institutions that are required by the Monetary Control Act of 1980 to hold reserves with Federal Reserve Banks.
    [Show full text]
  • An Assessment of Modern Monetary Theory
    An assessment of modern monetary theory M. Kasongo Kashama * Introduction Modern monetary theory (MMT) is a so-called heterodox economic school of thought which argues that elected governments should raise funds by issuing money to the maximum extent to implement the policies they deem necessary. While the foundations of MMT were laid in the early 1990s (Mosler, 1993), its tenets have been increasingly echoed in the public arena in recent years. The surge in interest was first reflected by high-profile British and American progressive policy-makers, for whom MMT has provided a rationale for their calls for Green New Deals and other large public spending programmes. In doing so, they have been backed up by new research work and publications from non-mainstream economists in the wake of Mosler’s work (see, for example, Tymoigne et al. (2013), Kelton (2017) or Mitchell et al. (2019)). As the COVID-19 crisis has been hitting the global economy since early this year, the most straightforward application of MMT’s macroeconomic policy agenda – that is, money- financed fiscal expansion or helicopter money – has returned to the forefront on a wider scale. Some consider not only that it is “time for helicopters” (Jourdan, 2020) but also that this global crisis must become a trigger to build on MMT precepts, not least in the euro area context (Bofinger, 2020). The MMT resurgence has been accompanied by lively political discussions and a heated economic debate, bringing fierce criticism from top economists including P. Krugman, G. Mankiw, K. Rogoff or L. Summers. This short article aims at clarifying what is at stake from a macroeconomic stabilisation perspective when considering MMT implementation in advanced economies, paying particular attention to the euro area.
    [Show full text]