Oligopoly and Tacit Collusion at Harvard (1933-1952)

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Oligopoly and Tacit Collusion at Harvard (1933-1952) 23rd Annual Conference of the European Society for the History of Economic Thought (ESHET) Banks, Money and Finance in the History of Economic Thought Lille, France Oligopoly and tacit collusion at Harvard (1933-1952): A tool of Industrial Organization to reappraise American Capitalism Alexandre CHIRAT1, Thibault GUICHERD2 Abstract: This article comes back on the development of industrial organization in Harvard. More specifically, it aims at understanding the process of the emergence of the so-called “Harvard school” which is often presented as a “spontaneous generation” of authors. Indeed, except for the place (Harvard University) and the time period (from the 1930s to the 1950s), very little has been said about a potential research agenda or a set of common and identifiable tools and concepts. This article identifies a specific subject of study that seems to unify all these authors: the development of the theory of tacit collusion in oligopoly. This latter theory was developed in 1933 by Edward Chamberlin in the scope of his theory of monopolistic competition and was gradually taken up in several contributions from the 1930s and early 1940s, all of which authors (Mason, Galbraith, Bain, de Chazeau, Triffin, Kaysen, Schumpeter) were directly linked to Harvard during the publication or the writing of their work. The creation of the NRA in 1934 strengthens interest in the phenomenon. The possibility of tacit collusion in oligopoly then allows the authors to better grasp competitive mechanisms and obvious price rigidity. Simultaneously, these authors encountered a range of theoretical problems (such as the differentiated oligopoly, the notion of large group, the meaning of the concept of price rigidity, the hypothesis of rationality or behavior to be retained) that need to be solved and which guide the research of this community. The analysis of tacit collusion in oligopoly then enters into debates among economists about the “basing point system”. This pricing method was at the time used in the iron, steel and cement industries and led the authors to tackle questions about the effectiveness of existing anti-trust laws. Can this type of price- setting mechanism be considered truly competitive when it is an oligopoly-like situation where prices are rigid and differentiated? The development of tools for the identification of these oligopolies translates into a set of contributions focusing on strategic behavior, market typologies or the use of price administration. It leads some authors to reappraise the nature of the competition and the foundations of American capitalism. Keywords: oligopoly, tacit collusion, strategic behavior, Industrial Organization, American Capitalism, Harvard 1 Ph. D Student in Economics (Université Lumière-Lyon 2, France), TRIANGLE. Mail : [email protected] 2 Doctor in Economics (Université Lumière-Lyon 2, France), TRIANGLE. Mail : [email protected] 1 0. Introduction The Harvard Department of Economics of the 1930s is generally recognized as one of the main centers that fosters the theoretical innovations of this so-called period of “High Theory” (Shackle 1967). On one hand, Harvard is the Ellis Island of the Keynesian revolution3. On the other, it is the birthplace of both monopolistic competition theory and the emerging field of Industrial Organization (IO). The spreading and reshaping of Keynes’ ideas through America has drawn much attention, whereas the field of IO has been neglected regarding its impact on both economic analysis and policy prescriptions. Yet it has even governed some broader reflexions on the very nature of the American capitalism that echoes the spirit of traditional political economy. The literature on the birth of IO at Harvard is obviously far from being inexistent. For instance, Jean Tirole (1988) mentioned the “Harvard Tradition” and assimilated with to the “structure-conduct-performance” paradigm developed by Joe Bain4. Richard Posner (1978) mentions a “Harvard School on antitrust policy” which is defined through its post-war opposition to the Chicago School embodied by George Stigler. The existence of such “Harvard school” is taken for granted. Historians of economic thought have looked for its origin5. Emphasis has been put on the role played by the two Eds - Chamberlin and Mason. Harvard’s tradition of case studies, illustrated by William Ripley’s course on corporations, and it is put forward to explain the empirical stance of the subdiscipline. This literature also traces back the roots of IO to the work of first institutionalist economists (R. Ely, J. Commons, T. Veblen) and their successors of the interwar period (J. M. Clark, W. Hamilton, W. Ripley)6. In a recent paper on “American economists” such as A. Berle, A. Burns, E. Chamberlin, J. M. Clark and G. Means who “sought to explain the Great Depression as a failure of competition”, Roger Backhouse (2015) states that the links between this literature and the “Harvard school of industrial economics” is “easy to trace”7. However, this story has not been written yet since the demonstration of the existence of the Harvard school in IO is always out of scope. 3 Hansen, Harris and Samuelson generally play the prominent role in these stories. We could also add the impact of two young Canadians economists, Robert Bryce, who followed J. M. Keynes course at Cambridge (UK) in 1934, and Lorie Tarshis. On the Keynesian revolution at Harvard, see Galbraith (1965, 1981), Samuelson (1988), Tobin (1988), Colander and Landreth (1999), Backhouse (2017). 4 Tirole (1988, 1-4) 5 See Arena (1991), Phillips and Stevenson (1974), Grether (1970). 6 Phillips and Stevenson (1974), Rutherford (2011). 7 Backhouse (2015, 121). 2 In fact, the aforementioned papers often convey a vision in terms of “spontaneous generation” of IO at Harvard; in this respect we consider them as unsatisfactory8. It consists in a posteriori agglomeration of actors from the similarities of their research thematic, but without giving any institutional and historical reality on the way these actors have interacted. This paper aims at providing the missing story of the birth of Industrial Organization at Harvard and the diverse paths of its development thank to the identification of a research community in and around Harvard. The task is not as easy as suggested by Backhouse. During the 1930s, the Harvard Department of Economics is a reflection of the interwar pluralism in American economics9. Far from being monolithic, it enters into an important renewal stage of its members. Three former Ph.D students successfully defended their Ph.D thesis – Seymour Harris (1923), Edward Mason (1923) and Edward Chamberlin (1927). Recognized American economists – as John D. Black (1927) in the field of agricultural economics, Sumner Slichter (1930) in labor economics, Alvin Hansen (1937) in business cycle - and prominent European immigrants - such as Leontief (1931), Schumpeter (1932) and Haberler (1936) - also join the department. In the mid-1930s, Alan Sweezy and John Kenneth Galbraith came as instructors and many economists are passing their Ph.D grades: Joe Bain (1940), John Cassels (1934), Gardiner Means (1933), Richard Musgrave (1937), Paul Samuelson (1940), Paul Sweezy (1937), Robert Triffin (1938), Donald Wallace (1931), to mention just a few. These names testify the diversity of epistemological approaches and topical interests among the members of the Department. One may still wonder who then participate to the so-called Harvard Tradition in Industrial Organization (HTIO). Labels school or tradition seem inappropriate since Mason and Bain are the only two figures systematically evoked in the HTIO. Moreover, it does not enable us to grasp the specific role played by the Harvard Department of Economics. This latter can be considered as a research community in itself. Its members share courses, attend seminars, collaborate on research projects, meet up on administrative issues, edit academic review and supervise students’ researches. Still those links do not make a tradition. Therefore, without an emphasis on a unifying criterion, it is impossible to understand the reality behind the label of a HTIO. Here, we defend the thesis that the identification of a specific theoretical notion enables us to delimit a group of actors who participate to its establishment from the 1930s to the 1950s. This unifying concept is the possibility of tacit collusion in oligopoly. 8 See also, for instance, Stephen Martin book Industrial Organization in context (2010, 16) 9 Morgan and Rutherford (1998). 3 The original protagonist of our narrative is the “rising star” of Harvard, Edward Hastings Chamberlin10. The publication of his Ph.D dissertation (1927), The Theory of Monopolistic Competition (1933), provides the first economic analysis of oligopoly11. This concept is revolutionary in two respects. First, it allows economist to think in terms of a continuum of competitive situations between the two ideal cases of pure competition and pure monopoly. Second, Chamberlin analyzes the behavior of firms in oligopolistic market by making new assumptions regarding their strategic interactions. The notion of tacit collusion in oligopoly hinges on the assumption that firms have a “recognition of their mutual independence” (Chamberlin 1933, 46-47). Thus, competition not only refers to market structure but also to strategic behaviors of the competitors. One immediately understands why this concept is directly linked to the birth of Industrial Organization. It has been used to build the first
Recommended publications
  • BIS Working Papers No 136 the Price Level, Relative Prices and Economic Stability: Aspects of the Interwar Debate by David Laidler* Monetary and Economic Department
    BIS Working Papers No 136 The price level, relative prices and economic stability: aspects of the interwar debate by David Laidler* Monetary and Economic Department September 2003 * University of Western Ontario Abstract Recent financial instability has called into question the sufficiency of low inflation as a goal for monetary policy. This paper discusses interwar literature bearing on this question. It begins with theories of the cycle based on the quantity theory, and their policy prescription of price stability supported by lender of last resort activities in the event of crises, arguing that their neglect of fluctuations in investment was a weakness. Other approaches are then taken up, particularly Austrian theory, which stressed the banking system’s capacity to generate relative price distortions and forced saving. This theory was discredited by its association with nihilistic policy prescriptions during the Great Depression. Nevertheless, its core insights were worthwhile, and also played an important part in Robertson’s more eclectic account of the cycle. The latter, however, yielded activist policy prescriptions of a sort that were discredited in the postwar period. Whether these now need re-examination, or whether a low-inflation regime, in which the authorities stand ready to resort to vigorous monetary expansion in the aftermath of asset market problems, is adequate to maintain economic stability is still an open question. BIS Working Papers are written by members of the Monetary and Economic Department of the Bank for International Settlements, and from time to time by other economists, and are published by the Bank. The views expressed in them are those of their authors and not necessarily the views of the BIS.
    [Show full text]
  • Economics of Competition in the U.S. Livestock Industry Clement E. Ward
    Economics of Competition in the U.S. Livestock Industry Clement E. Ward, Professor Emeritus Department of Agricultural Economics Oklahoma State University January 2010 Paper Background and Objectives Questions of market structure changes, their causes, and impacts for pricing and competition have been focus areas for the author over his entire 35-year career (1974-2009). Pricing and competition are highly emotional issues to many and focusing on factual, objective economic analyses is critical. This paper is the author’s contribution to that effort. The objectives of this paper are to: (1) put meatpacking competition issues in historical perspective, (2) highlight market structure changes in meatpacking, (3) note some key lawsuits and court rulings that contribute to the historical perspective and regulatory environment, and (4) summarize the body of research related to concentration and competition issues. These were the same objectives I stated in a presentation made at a conference in December 2009, The Economics of Structural Change and Competition in the Food System, sponsored by the Farm Foundation and other professional agricultural economics organizations. The basis for my conference presentation and this paper is an article I published, “A Review of Causes for and Consequences of Economic Concentration in the U.S. Meatpacking Industry,” in an online journal, Current Agriculture, Food & Resource Issues in 2002, http://caes.usask.ca/cafri/search/archive/2002-ward3-1.pdf. This paper is an updated, modified version of the review article though the author cannot claim it is an exhaustive, comprehensive review of the relevant literature. Issue Background Nearly 20 years ago, the author ran across a statement which provides a perspective for the issues of concentration, consolidation, pricing, and competition in meatpacking.
    [Show full text]
  • Fritz Machlup's Construction of a Synthetic Concept
    The Knowledge Economy: Fritz Machlup’s Construction of a Synthetic Concept Benoît Godin 385 rue Sherbrooke Est Montreal, Quebec Canada H2X 1E3 [email protected] Project on the History and Sociology of S&T Statistics Working Paper No. 37 2008 Previous Papers in the Series: 1. B. Godin, Outlines for a History of Science Measurement. 2. B. Godin, The Measure of Science and the Construction of a Statistical Territory: The Case of the National Capital Region (NCR). 3. B. Godin, Measuring Science: Is There Basic Research Without Statistics? 4. B. Godin, Neglected Scientific Activities: The (Non) Measurement of Related Scientific Activities. 5. H. Stead, The Development of S&T Statistics in Canada: An Informal Account. 6. B. Godin, The Disappearance of Statistics on Basic Research in Canada: A Note. 7. B. Godin, Defining R&D: Is Research Always Systematic? 8. B. Godin, The Emergence of Science and Technology Indicators: Why Did Governments Supplement Statistics With Indicators? 9. B. Godin, The Number Makers: A Short History of Official Science and Technology Statistics. 10. B. Godin, Metadata: How Footnotes Make for Doubtful Numbers. 11. B. Godin, Innovation and Tradition: The Historical Contingency of R&D Statistical Classifications. 12. B. Godin, Taking Demand Seriously: OECD and the Role of Users in Science and Technology Statistics. 13. B. Godin, What’s So Difficult About International Statistics? UNESCO and the Measurement of Scientific and Technological Activities. 14. B. Godin, Measuring Output: When Economics Drives Science and Technology Measurements. 15. B. Godin, Highly Qualified Personnel: Should We Really Believe in Shortages? 16. B. Godin, The Rise of Innovation Surveys: Measuring a Fuzzy Concept.
    [Show full text]
  • Computers and Economic Democracy
    Rev.econ.inst. vol.1 no.se Bogotá 2008 COMPUTERS AND ECONOMIC DEMOCRACY Computadores y democracia económica Allin Cottrell; Paul Cockshott Ph.D. in Economics, professor of Wake Forest University, Winston Salem, USA, [[email protected]]. Ph.D. in Computer Science, researcher of the Glasgow University, Glasgow, United Kingdom, [[email protected]].. The collapse of previously existing socialism was due to causes embedded in its economic mechanism, which are not inherent in all possible socialisms. The article argues that Marxist economic theory, in conjunction with information technology, provides the basis on which a viable socialist economic program can be advanced, and that the development of computer technology and the Internet makes economic planning possible. In addition, it argues that the socialist movement has never developed a correct constitutional program, and that modern technology opens up opportunities for democracy. Finally, it reviews the Austrian arguments against the possibility of socialist calculation in the light of modern computational capacity and the constraints of the Kyoto Protocol. [Keywords: socialist planning, economic calculation, environmental constraints; JEL: P21, P27, P28] El colapso del socialismo anteriormente existente obedeció a causas integradas en su mecanismo económico, que no son inherentes a todos los socialismos posibles. El artículo muestra que la teoría económica marxista, junto con la informática, proporciona el fundamento para adelantar un programa económico socialista viable y que el desarrollo de la informática y de Internet hace posible la planificación económica. Además, argumenta que el movimiento socialista nunca desarrolló un programa constitucional correcto y que la tecnología moderna abre nuevas oportunidades para la democracia.
    [Show full text]
  • Ebook Download Lectures on Inequality, Poverty and Welfare 1St
    LECTURES ON INEQUALITY, POVERTY AND WELFARE 1ST EDITION PDF, EPUB, EBOOK Antonio Villar | 9783319455617 | | | | | Lectures on Inequality, Poverty and Welfare 1st edition PDF Book Arthur Lewis Charles L. There is little doubt that good child care can help children succeed and that one way income support can help children succeed is by enabling their parents to purchase better child care. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press. Economic theory Political economy Applied economics. Presidents of the International Economic Association. Growing evidence shows that low income can have lasting adverse effects on children and that bolstering family income can help poor children catch up in a range of areas. Figure 5. In some ways people had got used to the idea that India was spiritual and religion-oriented. Retrieved 26 April The school had many progressive features, such as distaste for examinations or competitive testing. The key approach consists in linking inequality and poverty measurement with welfare evaluation. Resources, Values, and Development. His influential monograph Collective Choice and Social Welfare , which addressed problems related to individual rights including formulation of the liberal paradox , justice and equity, majority rule, and the availability of information about individual conditions, inspired researchers to turn their attention to issues of basic welfare. In the Bengal famine, rural laborers' negative freedom to buy food was not affected. In order for citizens to have a capacity to vote, they first must have "functionings". In addition to his important work on the causes of famines, Sen's work in the field of development economics has had considerable influence in the formulation of the " Human Development Report ", [15] published by the United Nations Development Programme.
    [Show full text]
  • Intellectual Property and the Development Divide
    Seattle University School of Law Digital Commons Faculty Scholarship 1-1-2006 Intellectual Property and the Development Divide Margaret Chon Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.law.seattleu.edu/faculty Part of the Intellectual Property Law Commons Recommended Citation Margaret Chon, Intellectual Property and the Development Divide, 27 CARDOZO L. REV. 2821 (2006). https://digitalcommons.law.seattleu.edu/faculty/558 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Seattle University School of Law Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Scholarship by an authorized administrator of Seattle University School of Law Digital Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY AND THE DEVELOPMENT DIVIDE Margaret Chon* "The ends and means of development require examination and scrutiny for a fuller understanding of the development process; it is simply not adequate to take as our basic objective just the maximization of income or wealth, which is, as Aristotle noted, 'merely useful and for the sake of something else.' For the same reason, economic growth cannot sensibly be treated as an end in itself. Development has to be more concerned with enhancing the lives we lead and the freedoms we enjoy." -Amartya Sen, Development as Freedom' " * Professor and Dean's Distinguished Scholar, Seattle University School of Law. This Article was incubated in various venues, including the Pacific Intellectual Property Scholars (PIPS) Conference (2003 and 2005), the
    [Show full text]
  • The Institutionalist Reaction to Keynesian Economics
    Journal of the History of Economic Thought, Volume 30, Number 1, March 2008 THE INSTITUTIONALIST REACTION TO KEYNESIAN ECONOMICS BY MALCOLM RUTHERFORD AND C. TYLER DESROCHES I. INTRODUCTION It is a common argument that one of the factors contributing to the decline of institutionalism as a movement within American economics was the arrival of Keynesian ideas and policies. In the past, this was frequently presented as a matter of Keynesian economics being ‘‘welcomed with open arms by a younger generation of American economists desperate to understand the Great Depression, an event which inherited wisdom was utterly unable to explain, and for which it was equally unable to prescribe a cure’’ (Laidler 1999, p. 211).1 As work by William Barber (1985) and David Laidler (1999) has made clear, there is something very wrong with this story. In the 1920s there was, as Laidler puts it, ‘‘a vigorous, diverse, and dis- tinctly American literature dealing with monetary economics and the business cycle,’’ a literature that had a central concern with the operation of the monetary system, gave great attention to the accelerator relationship, and contained ‘‘widespread faith in the stabilizing powers of counter-cyclical public-works expenditures’’ (Laidler 1999, pp. 211-12). Contributions by institutionalists such as Wesley C. Mitchell, J. M. Clark, and others were an important part of this literature. The experience of the Great Depression led some institutionalists to place a greater emphasis on expenditure policies. As early as 1933, Mordecai Ezekiel was estimating that about twelve million people out of the forty million previously employed in the University of Victoria and Erasmus University.
    [Show full text]
  • What We Know and Do Not Know About the Natural Rate of Unemployment
    Journal of Economic Perspectives—Volume 11, Number 1—Winter 1997—Pages 51–72 What We Know and Do Not Know About the Natural Rate of Unemployment Olivier Blanchard and Lawrence F. Katz lmost 30 years ago, Friedman (1968) and Phelps (1968) developed the concept of the "natural rate of unemployment." In what must be one of Athe longest sentences he ever wrote, Milton Friedman explained: "The natural rate of unemployment is the level which would be ground out by the Wal- rasian system of general equilibrium equations, provided that there is imbedded in them the actual structural characteristics of the labor and commodity markets, in- cluding market imperfections, stochastic variability in demands and supplies, the cost of gathering information about job vacancies and labor availabilities, the costs of mobility, and so on." Over the past three decades a large amount of research has attempted to formalize Friedman's long sentence and to identify, both theo- retically and empirically, the determinants of the natural rate. It is this body of work we assess in this paper. We reach two main conclusions. The first is that there has been considerable theoretical progress over the past 30 years. A framework has emerged, organized around two central ideas. The first is that the labor market is a market with a high level of traffic, with large flows of workers who have either lost their jobs or are looking for better ones. This by itself implies that there must be some "frictional unemployment." The second is that the nature of relations between firms and workers leads to wage setting that often differs substantially from competitive wage setting.
    [Show full text]
  • Modigliani's and Sylos Labini's Contributions to Oligopoly Theory
    The Origin of the Sylos Postulate: Modigliani’s and Sylos Labini’s Contributions to Oligopoly Theory by Antonella Rancan CHOPE Working Paper No. 2012-08 December 2012 The Origin of the Sylos Postulate: Modigliani’s and Sylos Labini’s Contributions to Oligopoly Theory* Antonella Rancan University of Molise (Italy) Email: [email protected] December 2012 * The paper benefited from a period of research at Duke University working on Modigliani’s Papers. I wish to thank the Hope Center and the David M. Rubenstein Rare Book, Manuscript, and Special Collections Library for financial support within the Economists’ Paper Project. I also thank the Special Collection Library staff for their kind availability. The paper was presented at the 2011 ESHET and STOREP conferences. I am especially grateful to the readers and discussants of different versions for their useful comments and suggestions. The Abstract of The Origin of the Sylos Postulate: Modigliani’s and Sylos Labini’s Contributions to Oligopoly Theory* Abstract Paolo Sylos Labini’s Oligopoly Theory and Technical Progress (1957) is considered one of the major contributions to entry-prevention models, especially after Franco Modigliani’s famous formalization. Nonetheless, Modigliani neglected Sylos Labini’s major aim when reviewing his work (1958), particularly his demonstration of the dynamic relation between industrial concentration and economic development. Modigliani addressed only Sylos’ microeconomic analysis and the determination of the long-run equilibrium price and output, concentrating on the role played by firms’ anticipations. By doing so he shifted attention from Sylos' objective analysis to a subjective approach to oligopoly problem. This paper discusses Sylos’ and Modigliani’s differing approaches, derives the origin of the Sylos postulate and sets Modigliani’s interpretation of Sylos’ oligopoly theory in the context of his 1950s research into firms’ behaviour under uncertainty.
    [Show full text]
  • Mill's "Very Simple Principle": Liberty, Utilitarianism And
    MILL'S "VERY SIMPLE PRINCIPLE": LIBERTY, UTILITARIANISM AND SOCIALISM MICHAEL GRENFELL submitted for degree of Ph.D. London School of Economics and Political Science UMI Number: U048607 All rights reserved INFORMATION TO ALL USERS The quality of this reproduction is dependent upon the quality of the copy submitted. In the unlikely event that the author did not send a complete manuscript and there are missing pages, these will be noted. Also, if material had to be removed, a note will indicate the deletion. Dissertation Publishing UMI U048607 Published by ProQuest LLC 2014. Copyright in the Dissertation held by the Author. Microform Edition © ProQuest LLC. All rights reserved. This work is protected against unauthorized copying under Title 17, United States Code. ProQuest LLC 789 East Eisenhower Parkway P.O. Box 1346 Ann Arbor, Ml 48106-1346 I H^S £ S F 6SI6 ABSTRACT OF THESIS MILL'S "VERY SIMPLE PRINCIPLE'*: LIBERTY. UTILITARIANISM AND SOCIALISM 1 The thesis aims to examine the political consequences of applying J.S. Mill's "very simple principle" of liberty in practice: whether the result would be free-market liberalism or socialism, and to what extent a society governed in accordance with the principle would be free. 2 Contrary to Mill's claims for the principle, it fails to provide a clear or coherent answer to this "practical question". This is largely because of three essential ambiguities in Mill's formulation of the principle, examined in turn in the three chapters of the thesis. 3 First, Mill is ambivalent about whether liberty is to be promoted for its intrinsic value, or because it is instrumental to the achievement of other objectives, principally the utilitarian objective of "general welfare".
    [Show full text]
  • 35 Measuring Oligopsony and Oligopoly Power in the US Paper Industry Bin Mei and Changyou Sun Abstract
    Measuring Oligopsony and Oligopoly Power in the U.S. Paper Industry Bin Mei and Changyou Sun1 Abstract: The U.S. paper industry has been increasingly concentrated ever since the 1950s. Such an industry structure may be suspected of imperfect competition. This study applied the new empirical industrial organization (NEIO) approach to examine the market power in the U.S. paper industry. The econometric analysis consisted of the identification and estimation of a system of equations including a production function, market demand and supply functions, and two conjectural elasticities indicating the industry’s oligopsony and oligopoly power. By employing annual data from 1955 to 2003, the above system of equations was estimated by Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) procedure. The analysis indicated the presence of oligopsony power but no evidence of oligopoly power over the sample period. Keywords: Conjectural elasticity; GMM; Market power; NEIO Introduction The paper sector (NAICS 32-SIC 26) has been the largest among the lumber, furniture, and paper sectors in the U.S. forest products industry. According to the latest Annual Survey of Manufacturing in 2005, the value of shipments for paper manufacturing reached $163 billion or a 45% share of the total forest products output (U.S. Bureau of Census, 2005). Thus, the paper sector has played a vital role in the U.S. forest products industry. However, spatial factors such as the cost of transporting products between sellers and buyers can mitigate the forces necessary to support perfect competition (Murray, 1995a). This is particularly true in markets for agricultural and forest products. For example, timber and logs are bulky and land-intensive in nature, thus leading to high logging service fees.
    [Show full text]
  • GEORGE J. STIGLER Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, 1101 East 58Th Street, Chicago, Ill
    THE PROCESS AND PROGRESS OF ECONOMICS Nobel Memorial Lecture, 8 December, 1982 by GEORGE J. STIGLER Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, 1101 East 58th Street, Chicago, Ill. 60637, USA In the work on the economics of information which I began twenty some years ago, I started with an example: how does one find the seller of automobiles who is offering a given model at the lowest price? Does it pay to search more, the more frequently one purchases an automobile, and does it ever pay to search out a large number of potential sellers? The study of the search for trading partners and prices and qualities has now been deepened and widened by the work of scores of skilled economic theorists. I propose on this occasion to address the same kinds of questions to an entirely different market: the market for new ideas in economic science. Most economists enter this market in new ideas, let me emphasize, in order to obtain ideas and methods for the applications they are making of economics to the thousand problems with which they are occupied: these economists are not the suppliers of new ideas but only demanders. Their problem is comparable to that of the automobile buyer: to find a reliable vehicle. Indeed, they usually end up by buying a used, and therefore tested, idea. Those economists who seek to engage in research on the new ideas of the science - to refute or confirm or develop or displace them - are in a sense both buyers and sellers of new ideas. They seek to develop new ideas and persuade the science to accept them, but they also are following clues and promises and explorations in the current or preceding ideas of the science.
    [Show full text]