Understanding ASEAN - an Alternative Approach to International Relations Theory in Asia

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Understanding ASEAN - an Alternative Approach to International Relations Theory in Asia Portland State University PDXScholar Dissertations and Theses Dissertations and Theses 6-16-2018 Understanding ASEAN - An Alternative Approach to International Relations Theory in Asia Ryan Grimstad Driver Portland State University Follow this and additional works at: https://pdxscholar.library.pdx.edu/open_access_etds Part of the Political Science Commons Let us know how access to this document benefits ou.y Recommended Citation Driver, Ryan Grimstad, "Understanding ASEAN - An Alternative Approach to International Relations Theory in Asia" (2018). Dissertations and Theses. Paper 4436. https://doi.org/10.15760/etd.6320 This Thesis is brought to you for free and open access. It has been accepted for inclusion in Dissertations and Theses by an authorized administrator of PDXScholar. Please contact us if we can make this document more accessible: [email protected]. Understanding ASEAN An alternative approach to international relations theory in Asia by Ryan Grimstad Driver A thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Science in Political Science Thesis Committee: Bruce Gilley, Chair Lindsay Benstead David Kinsella Portland State University 2018 © 2018 Ryan Grimstad Driver Abstract The Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) was originally formed in 1967 by five members as a means to promote peaceful relations and prevent the spread of communist influence within their sovereign states. Since then the regional organization has doubled in size and now includes communist states amongst its membership as it seeks to establish itself as a strong economic and political hub for the greater region as two large military powers, China and the United States, vie for hegemonic influence. The American presence in the region must be governed by a firm understanding of ASEAN’s unique nature and goals. When compared to other regional organizations that formed over similar time periods, such as the European Union, ASEAN has not taken a cohesive path with less of a firm timeline for integrating institutions as it instead continues to reshape its policies in small iterative steps to evolve to the changing world. If our existing paradigms of the role of regional organizations do not match with the structure of ASEAN, we must establish a new toolset in order to guide future policies for involvement in the region. This thesis seeks to provide a clear description and thus understanding of the institutions and behavior of ASEAN as a regional organization. The questions posed include whether ASEAN conforms to the institutional and behavioral predictions of the major paradigmatic approaches to international theory, namely realism, liberalism, and constructivism. The thesis begins with a brief history of ASEAN over four distinct phases and an overview of regional organizations and international theory. The three dominant theories are then analyzed in their application to ASEAN in the areas of security, economics, and human rights. i Conclusions are drawn that each of the three theories has its value for descriptive insight, but all fall short in creating a holistic understanding of ASEAN. Therefore, I propose a new way of describing ASEAN as a reactive, isomorphic, and anti-fragile regional organization. The potential of this approach is that it utilizes tools latent in the existing theories to examine ASEAN’s nature. ii Table of Contents Abstract ................................................................................................................................ i List of Abbreviations ......................................................................................................... iv Chapter I: Shaping a Flexible Paradigm ..............................................................................1 Chapter II: Background and History of ASEAN .................................................................4 Chapter III: Regional Organizations and International Relations Theory .........................11 Chapter IV: Questions and Research Design .....................................................................25 Chapter V: Is ASEAN a Realist Security Community ......................................................37 Chapter VI: Is ASEAN a Liberal Economic Community ..................................................69 Chapter VII: Is ASEAN a Constructivist Rights community ............................................82 Chapter VIII: ASEAN as a Process .................................................................................105 Chapter IX: Implications for U.S. Policy Towards ASEAN ...........................................125 References ........................................................................................................................138 iii List of Abbreviations ACCT - ASEAN Convention on Counter-Terrorism ACSC - ASEAN Civil Society Conference ADMM - ASEAN Defence Ministers’ Meeting ADMM-Plus - Ten ASEAN member states, and eight Plus countries, Australia, China, India, Japan, New Zealand, ROK, Russian Federation, and the United States. AEC - ASEAN Economic Community AFTA - ASEAN Free Trade Area AHA Center - ASEAN Coordinating Centre for Humanitarian Assistance on Disaster Management AHRB - ASEAN Human Rights Body AICHR - Association of Southeast Asian Nations’ Intergovernmental Commission on Human Rights APEC - Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation APF - ASEAN Peoples’ Forum APSC - ASEAN Political and Security Community APT - ASEAN Plus Three: ASEAN, China, Japan, and South Korea ARF - ASEAN Regional Forum ASC - ASEAN Security Community ASCC - ASEAN Social and Cultural Community ASEAN Plus Six: ASEAN, Australia, China, India, Japan, New Zealand, and South Korea ASEAN - Association of Southeast Asian Nations AU - African Union CSCE - Commission on Security and Cooperation in Europe CSO - Civil society organizations EU - European Union FTAAP - Free Trade Area of the Asia-Pacific iv HADR - Humanitarian Aid/Disaster Relief IGO - Intergovernmental organization IMF - International Monetary Fund IR - International relations MERCOSUR - Common Market of the Southern Cone NATO - North Atlantic Treaty Organization NCPO - National Council for Peace and Order NORAD - North American Aerospace Defense R2P - Responsibility to Protect RCEP - Regional Comprehensive Economic Partnership RHRM - Regional human rights mechanism RIGO - Regional intergovernmental organization RIT - Reactive isomorphic theory SEATO - Southeast Asia Treaty Organization SPDC - State Peace and Development Council TAC - Treaty of Amity and Cooperation TPP - Trans-Pacific Partnership USD - United States Dollar VAP - Vientiane Action Programme WPS - Women, Peace and Security ZOPFAN - Zone of Peace, Freedom, and Neutrality v Chapter I: Shaping a Flexible Paradigm In August 2017, the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) celebrated its fiftieth anniversary. Over its history ASEAN has accomplished two important goals by maintaining peace between ten diverse nations and the establishment of free-trade agreements between them. Since its formation the regional organization has evolved itself and its goals repeatedly as it seeks to adapt to the everchanging regional needs, and yet when compared to more institutionalized organizations such as the European Union (EU), ASEAN remains a loose collection of states each with their own cultural identities, values, and objectives. This is not a collection of like-minded states who seek greater levels of unification with the aspiration of establishing a more cohesive union, but rather separate states that see more to gain from cooperation than competition. The benefits come from reducing risks of conflict between members, maintaining strength of sovereignty by strict rules of anti-interventionism, and increasingly greater economic benefits from free trade agreements. The important role of the organization is underscored by the increasing level of commitment the United States has placed on its diplomatic involvement. In 2010 President Obama opened an ASEAN mission in Jakarta and followed that with hosting the ten heads of state at the first summit held in America in 2016. These efforts were to culminate in the formation of the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP), a multilateral free trade agreement between twelve nations that was to come to fruition in 2018 had the United States, having elected Donald Trump to office, not withdrawn leaving the region scrambling to push through a different initiative. While the enthusiasm towards the 1 region has lessened under the Trump administration’s more detached approach to foreign policy, the region nonetheless remains critical to global trade. Before it was eclipsed by the TPP, ASEAN had put forward the Regional Comprehensive Economic Partnership, a pact which is returning to high level talks as China, putting its weight behind the deal, is stepping in eagerly to fill the gap left by the United States in the region. Economically and politically this region is of great significance and its priority needs to be placed higher in United States foreign policy. To do so though, policymakers need to have a greater grasp on ASEAN and what its own aspirations are. Unfortunately, academic scholarship to date has failed in this regard as the dominant international relations theories seek to impose restrictive narratives upon what role a regional organization must play. Existing work is governed by narratives without accounting for the regional cultural and political values when they do not align with the paradigms of the established
Recommended publications
  • The Phenomenology of Gridlock
    Cornell Law Library Scholarship@Cornell Law: A Digital Repository Cornell Law Faculty Publications Faculty Scholarship 6-2013 The heP nomenology of Gridlock Josh Chafetz Cornell Law School, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarship.law.cornell.edu/facpub Part of the Legislation Commons, and the Politics Commons Recommended Citation Chafetz, Josh, "The heP nomenology of Gridlock" (2013). Cornell Law Faculty Publications. Paper 586. http://scholarship.law.cornell.edu/facpub/586 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the Faculty Scholarship at Scholarship@Cornell Law: A Digital Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Cornell Law Faculty Publications by an authorized administrator of Scholarship@Cornell Law: A Digital Repository. For more information, please contact [email protected]. SYMPOSIUM THE AMERICAN CONGRESS: LEGAL IMPLICATIONS OF GRIDLOCK THE PHENOMENOLOGY OF GRIDLOCK Josh Chafet4 Assertions that our legislative process is gridlocked-perhaps even "hopelessly" so-are endemic. So many more of our problems would be fixed, the thinking goes, if only our political institutions were functioning properly. The hunt for the causes of gridlock is therefore afoot. This Essay argues that this hunt is fundamentally misguided, because gridlock is not a phenomenon. Rather, gridlock is the absence of phenomena; it is the absence, that is, of legisla- tive action. Rather than asking why we experience gridlock, we should be asking why and how legislative action occurs. We should expect to see legislative action, the Essay argues, when there is sufficient public consensus for a specific course of action. "Sufficient," in this context, is determined with reference to ourspecific constitutionalstructure.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Towards a Third Generation of Global Governance Scholarship This Is the Final Typeset and Copyedited PDF Version. the Chapter
    Towards a Third Generation of Global Governance Scholarship This is the final typeset and copyedited PDF version. The chapter should be cited as: David Coen and Tom Pegram, ‘Towards a Third Generation of Global Governance Scholarship’, Global Policy, Global Policy, Volume 9, Issue 1 (February 2018), 107-113. Abstract Global governance is widely viewed as in crisis. Deepening interdependence of cross-border activity belies the relative absence of governance mechanisms capable of effectively tackling major global policy challenges. Scholars have an important role to play in understanding blockages and ways through. A first generation of global governance research made visible an increasingly complex and globalising reality beyond the interstate domain. A varied second generation of scholarship, spanning diverse subfields, has built upon this ‘signpost scholarship’ to generate insight into efforts to manage, bypass and even – potentially – transcend multilateral gridlock to address pressing transboundary problems. This article plots a course towards a ‘third generation’ of global governance research, serving to also introduce a special section which brings together leading scholars in the field of global governance, working across theoretical, analytical and issue-area boundaries. This collaborative endeavour proposes to advance a convergence, already underway, across a theoretically and empirically rich existing scholarship, distinguished by a concern for the complexity of global policy delivery. 1 Introduction Although its conceptual, analytical and theoretical boundaries may be hotly debated, global governance is widely viewed as a vital component to addressing transboundary common goods challenges, from large-scale violence to sustainable development, health to climate change, bio-pathogen containment to financial disruption. As Martin Wolf (2012) of the Financial Times suggests, humanity’s efforts to overcome the tragedy of the global commons ‘could prove to be the defining story of the century’.
    [Show full text]
  • Media and Gridlock
    Media and Gridlock Daniel F. Stone1 9th Media Economics Workshop - New Economic School October 2011 1Oregon State University I Anecdotal evidence: minority party tried to block major new policy proposals (social security, health care reform, jobs bill?) I Term `gridlock' only coined after 1980 elections I Binder (1999): hard evidence of increasing gridlock in 80s and 90s (term coined in 80s) I Cloture motions way up over time, especially in last two Congresses Gridlock in U.S. appears to have increased in recent years I Term `gridlock' only coined after 1980 elections I Binder (1999): hard evidence of increasing gridlock in 80s and 90s (term coined in 80s) I Cloture motions way up over time, especially in last two Congresses Gridlock in U.S. appears to have increased in recent years I Anecdotal evidence: minority party tried to block major new policy proposals (social security, health care reform, jobs bill?) I Binder (1999): hard evidence of increasing gridlock in 80s and 90s (term coined in 80s) I Cloture motions way up over time, especially in last two Congresses Gridlock in U.S. appears to have increased in recent years I Anecdotal evidence: minority party tried to block major new policy proposals (social security, health care reform, jobs bill?) I Term `gridlock' only coined after 1980 elections I Cloture motions way up over time, especially in last two Congresses Gridlock in U.S. appears to have increased in recent years I Anecdotal evidence: minority party tried to block major new policy proposals (social security, health care reform, jobs bill?) I Term `gridlock' only coined after 1980 elections I Binder (1999): hard evidence of increasing gridlock in 80s and 90s (term coined in 80s) Gridlock in U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • Why Gridlock Matters
    \\jciprod01\productn\N\NDL\88-5\NDL503.txt unknown Seq: 1 2-JUL-13 11:56 WHY GRIDLOCK MATTERS Michael J. Gerhardt* INTRODUCTION A week before the 2012 presidential election, I had the opportunity to speak with a former senator. I asked him about gridlock. I wondered what he would say to my law students who had lost hope in the legislative process because of the gridlock that defined the 112th Congress. He told me that they had good reason to have lost hope. He said that he conceived of the legislative process as a target; that the center of the target represented the areas that were most important to the country and the likeliest ones in which bipartisan agreement could be reached; and that the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act (“ACA” or “Affordable Care Act”),1 in which he said that President Obama had invested so much time and capital, was on the periph- ery, if not the outside, of the target. He explained that the ACA exceeded the scope of congressional power. He explained that opposing the ACA should be the top priority of legislators and citizens. When I asked him what issues were at the center of the target, he initially did not respond. After I politely pressed him for an answer, he eventually said that there was nothing more important than opposing the health care bill. For him, gridlock had become a constitutional necessity. The former senator’s position on gridlock is hardly unique. Indeed, more than a year before President Obama’s re-election, Antonin Scalia, the longest serving justice on the current Supreme Court, told the Senate Judici- ary Committee that, “Americans should learn to love gridlock .
    [Show full text]
  • How Partisan Gridlock in State Legislatures Encourages the Use of Citizen Initiatives
    blogs.lse.ac.uk http://blogs.lse.ac.uk/usappblog/2015/11/23/how-partisan-gridlock-in-state-legislatures-encourages-the-use-of-citizen-initiatives/ How partisan gridlock in state legislatures encourages the use of citizen initiatives. While partisan gridlock has become a common occurrence in the US Congress, this is also often the case in many state legislatures. In new research, Frederick J. Boehmke, Tracy L. Osborn, and Emily U. Schilling look at one consequence of legislative rules that encourage legislative paralysis – the increasing use of ballot initiatives by citizens. Using data from the American states, they find that as ‘pivotal legislators’ – gatekeepers whose support is needed to overcome a legislative filibuster or gubernatorial veto – become ideologically farther away from the state’s median voter, initiative use increases due to those lawmakers thwarting legislative action to secure preferred outcomes in the form of ballot measures. In the early 20th century, Progressive reformers pushed for institutions of direct legislation, such as the initiative, referendum and recall, as a means to return power to the people and to place a check on elected officials. In this way, the direct initiative process in the American states offers a potential cure for legislative inaction. In the current era of increased legislative polarization and gridlock, such institutions may be more important than ever. In new research, we find that the initiative process can indeed provide an important alternate mechanism for making policy. Yet, the initiative process can potentially both hinder and encourage legislative obstructionism. We show that more burdensome hurdles for legislative action in the American states lead citizens to sponsor more ballot measures in order to alter policy outside the legislative arena.
    [Show full text]
  • Gridlock, Lobbying, and Democracy Joseph P
    University of Cincinnati College of Law University of Cincinnati College of Law Scholarship and Publications Faculty Articles and Other Publications College of Law Faculty Scholarship 2017 Gridlock, Lobbying, and Democracy Joseph P. Tomain University of Cincinnati College of Law, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: http://scholarship.law.uc.edu/fac_pubs Part of the Law and Politics Commons Recommended Citation Joseph P. Tomain, Gridlock, Lobbying, and Democracy, 7 Wake Forest J.L. Pol'y 87 (2017) This Article is brought to you for free and open access by the College of Law Faculty Scholarship at University of Cincinnati College of Law Scholarship and Publications. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Articles and Other Publications by an authorized administrator of University of Cincinnati College of Law Scholarship and Publications. For more information, please contact [email protected]. GRIDLOCK, LOBBYING, AND DEMOCRACY JOSEPH P. TOMAINt the Supreme Court vacancy left by W Antoninith the refusalScalia, theto fillSenate adds another layer of gridlock in Washington.' In the recent past, congressional gridlock has threatened to shut down the legislative process by such maneuvers as creating a faux debt crisis and by regularly assailing the president and the executive branch over so-called job-killing regulations.' Through these efforts, obstructionist Republicans have attempted a gridlock hat-trick by trying to shut down each of the three branches of government-at least as far as the headlines go.' The political reality, however, is more nuanced, and gridlock is more complicated than commentators often claim-and not to the public benefit.
    [Show full text]
  • Common Currency in East Asia: an Analysis of Currency Convergence
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Research Online @ ECU Edith Cowan University Research Online ECU Publications 2011 1-1-2011 Common Currency in East Asia: An Analysis of Currency Convergence Lee K. Lim Edith Cowan University Follow this and additional works at: https://ro.ecu.edu.au/ecuworks2011 Part of the Finance and Financial Management Commons This is an Author's Accepted Manuscript of: Lim, L. K. (2011). Common Currency in East Asia: An Analysis of Currency Convergence. International Journal of Business Studies, 19(1), 53-67. Available here This Journal Article is posted at Research Online. https://ro.ecu.edu.au/ecuworks2011/133 INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL OF BUSINESS STUDIES – SPECIAL EDITION VOL 19 NO 1, JUNE 2011: pages 53 to 67 COMMON CURRENCY IN EAST ASIA: AN ANALYSIS OF CURRENCY CONVERGENCE Lee K Lim* The recent global financial crisis of 2007-2009 and fears of a sovereign debt crisis in some European countries have fuelled the debates among economic analysts and policy makers on the future directions of monetary and exchange rate arrangements in the East Asian region. This paper applies both the cluster analysis and time series tests to determine whether increased trade and financial integration has led to currency convergence in the region over the period January 1990 to June 2010. The countries included in this study are the high-performing East Asian economies, namely China, Hong Kong, Japan, South Korea, Taiwan and the five founding ASEAN member countries. The Chinese yuan is found to be more suited than the Japanese yen as the anchor currency in East Asia.
    [Show full text]
  • A Theory of Political Gridlock
    Theoretical Economics 12 (2017), 555–586 1555-7561/20170555 A theory of political gridlock Juan Ortner Department of Economics, Boston University This paper studies how electoral incentives influence the outcomes of political ne- gotiations. It considers a game between two political parties that have to bargain over which policy to implement. While bargaining, the parties’ popularity varies over time. Changes in popularity are partly exogenous and partly driven by the parties’ actions. There is an election scheduled at a future date and the party with more popularity at the election date wins the vote. Electoral incentives can have substantial effects on bargaining outcomes. Periods of gridlock may arise when the election is close and parties have similar levels of popularity. Keywords. Bargaining, elections, political gridlock, inefficient delay. JEL classification. C73, C78, D72. 1. Introduction An important element of political negotiations—especially negotiations over high- profile or landmark legislation—is that agreements can have consequences that go well beyond implemented policies. As Binder and Lee (2013) put it, “Negotiation in Congress is never solely about policy; politics and policy are always intertwined.” Beyond policy considerations, political parties usually weigh whether compromising on a given issue is in their best electoral interest. Reaching an agreement can lead to changes in the par- ties’ level of support among voters, and these changes can be of crucial importance in determining electoral outcomes. The goal of the current paper is to study how such elec- toral incentives affect the outcomes of political negotiations. The results shed light on the circumstances under which electoral considerations can lead to periods of gridlock and political inaction.
    [Show full text]
  • Federalism in Eastern Europe During and After Communism
    James Hughes Federalism in Eastern Europe during and after Communism Book section Original citation: Originally published in Fagan, Adam and Kopecký, Petr, (eds.) The Routledge Handbook of East European Politics. Routledge, London, UK. ISBN 9781138919754 © 2018 Routledge This version available at: http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/69642/ Available in LSE Research Online: March 2017 LSE has developed LSE Research Online so that users may access research output of the School. Copyright © and Moral Rights for the papers on this site are retained by the individual authors and/or other copyright owners. Users may download and/or print one copy of any article(s) in LSE Research Online to facilitate their private study or for non-commercial research. You may not engage in further distribution of the material or use it for any profit-making activities or any commercial gain. You may freely distribute the URL (http://eprints.lse.ac.uk) of the LSE Research Online website. This document is the author’s submitted version of the book section. There may be differences between this version and the published version. You are advised to consult the publisher’s version if you wish to cite from it. Federalism in Eastern Europe during and after Communism James Hughes Chapter 10 Forthcoming in Adam Fagan and Petr Kopecky eds. The Routledge Handbook of East European Politics. Routledge 2017 One of the earliest political visionaries of federalism in Eastern Europe,interwar Polish leader Józef Piłsudski, famously remarked to former socialist comrades that “we both took
    [Show full text]
  • Emerging Powers and Emerging Trends in Global Governance
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Stephen, Matthew D. Article — Accepted Manuscript (Postprint) Emerging Powers and Emerging Trends in Global Governance Global Governance Provided in Cooperation with: WZB Berlin Social Science Center Suggested Citation: Stephen, Matthew D. (2017) : Emerging Powers and Emerging Trends in Global Governance, Global Governance, ISSN 1942-6720, Brill Nijhoff, Leiden, Vol. 23, Iss. 3, pp. 483-502, http://dx.doi.org/10.1163/19426720-02303009 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/215866 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu This article was published by Brill in Global Governance, Vol. 23 (2017), Iss. 3, pp. 483–502 (2017/08/19): https://doi.org/10.1163/19426720-02303009.
    [Show full text]
  • Federalism and Decentralization – a Critical Survey of Frequently Used Indicators
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Research Papers in Economics Joint Discussion Paper MAGKS Göttingen Series in Economics Kassel Aachen by the Universities of Siegen Marburg Aachen · Gießen · Göttingen Kassel · Marburg · Siegen Gießen ISSN 1867-3678 No. 21-2008 Lorenz Blume and Stefan Voigt Federalism and Decentralization – A Critical Survey of Frequently Used Indicators This paper can be downloaded from http://www.uni-marburg.de/fb02/makro/forschung/magkspapers/index_html%28magks%29 Coordination: Bernd Hayo • Philipps-University Marburg Faculty of Business Administration and Economics • Universitätsstraße 24, D-35032 Marburg Tel: +49-6421-2823091, Fax: +49-6421-2823088, e-mail: [email protected] Federalism and Decentralization – A Critical Survey of Frequently Used Indicators1 Lorenz Blume * and Stefan Voigt # Abstract: The economic effects of federalism are unclear: some papers find that federalism has strong positive effects on a number of economically relevant variables, others find negative effects. The results often crucially hinge upon the proxies for federalism used. In this paper, we critically survey the existing indicators for both federalism and fiscal decentralization. We argue that federalism is a constitutional institution whereas decentralization is (the outcome of) a policy choice and that the two ought to be systematically distinguished because decentralization can also occur in non-federally structured states. We further argue that institutional details are very important with regard to federalism and that dummy variables usually capture only very specific aspects of the institutional details. We use factor analysis to test whether the latent variables behind the observed indicators support these assumptions.
    [Show full text]
  • The Possible Use of Asian Monetary Unit (AMU) - Comment
    A3 Conference : Monetary and Financial Cooperation in the Region May 24, 2012, RIETI, Tokyo Japan The Possible Use of Asian Monetary Unit (AMU) - Comment - Jung-Sik Kim Yonsei University, Seoul Korea [email protected] I. Summary of the Paper 1 1. AMU is different from euro and similar to ECU • Euro-zone has experienced some troubles and the creation and use of single common currency in East Asia might not be feasible in short run. • AMU is a composite currency of 13 East Asian currencies 2. AMU could be used as a surveillance indicator of misalignment of bilateral exchange rate or nominal bilateral equilibrium exchange rate (Ogawa and Shimizu(2010) Summary of the Paper 2 • Causes of misalignment : Fear of appreciation in East Asia and accumulation of foreign reserve by mercantilism and asymmetric intervention • AMU deviation index (AMUDI) is highly related to trade balance in the region • Because of the less convergence of fundamentals in East Asia, Asian currencies could not keep narrow margin • Large margin is needed for the countries which have large trade deficits Summary of the Paper 3 3. Create AMU-3 for trade settlement currency • CMIM’s weight : Japan, China, Korea : 32:32:16 • Create CLS bank for AMU-3 trade settlement • CLS bank could promote local currency settlement or invoicing II. Lessons from Euro-Zone Crisis • OCA criteria (fiscal transfer or factor movement etc.) does not work when there is asymmetric Shock • Difficult to make agreement for fiscal deficit criteria • Without monetary and exchange rate policies, countries
    [Show full text]