Is Deindustrialization Inevitable?

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Is Deindustrialization Inevitable? MANUFACTURING DISCONTENT By Bob Baugh and Joel Yudken IS DEINDUSTRIALIZATION INEVITABLE? REBUILDING AMERICA’S INDUSTRIAL BASE IS ESSENTIAL FOR MAINTAINING OUR COUNTRY’S living standards and restoring the American Dream for future generations. Today we must borrow an unsustainable two billion dollars a day to pay for the goods we consume that we do not produce as a nation. Eventually, we must either produce more of what we consume, or be forced to consume less. Our national competitiveness is eroding despite the fact that American manufac- turing workers are the most productive in the throughout its history. It is a vital engine for world. As a high–wage country in a rapidly glo- economic growth, generating good jobs and balizing world, we must restore our competi- guaranteeing a high standard of living for tiveness by developing a national industrial America’s working families. It is a mainstay of strategy centered on innovation. Such a strat- state and local economies, providing both jobs egy requires raising the level of public and pri- and tax revenues for essential public services. vate investment, harnessing the distinctive tech- Manufacturing jobs create as many as four other nological and organizational capacities of U.S. jobs in local economies, and the earnings and manufacturing companies, and developing the benefits of those workers exceed those of work- skills of American workers. ers in services and other sectors. In addition, Manufacturing has been the foundation of manufacturing is the leading industrial sector the nation’s economic and national security in providing health care benefits. The sharp New Labor Forum 15(2): 55–64, Summer 2006 CopyrightIs Deindustrialization © Joseph S. Murphy Institute,Inevitable? CUNY New Labor Forum • 55 ISSN: 1095-7960/06 print DOI:10.1080/1095760600666645 increase in uninsured Americans, five million ing, nearly every subsector has suffered double- over the past four years, is directly related to digit employment declines—48 percent in tex- the decline of manufacturing employment. tiles, nearly 30 percent in computer and elec- Manufacturing is also the major driver of U.S. tronic parts and primary metals, and 23 per- productivity growth and technological innova- cent in machinery. tion. The crisis has spread throughout the economy to encompass both high–and low– A NATIONAL CRISIS end occupations. In 2003, engineering unem- ODAY, HOWEVER, AMERICAN MANUFACTURING ployment hit seven percent, a level that, even Tis under siege. Alarms should be going off in the worst of times in the early 1980s, never everywhere but the crisis is deliberately rose above three percent. From 2001 to 2004, drowned out by an economic orthodoxy that the Bureau of Labor Statistics estimates there tells us “globalization is inevitable” and “it’s was a loss of 221,000 technical and engineer- good for consumers.” Free market dogma pro- ing jobs: computer programmers, electrical and vides cover for government policies shaped by electronic engineers, and so on. Since January Wall Street, and multinational corporations that 2001, the U.S. economy lost 725,000 profes- are unraveling America’s working middle class. sional, business, and information service jobs, The fight for manufacturing is a fight for the and created only 70,000 jobs in architecture and economic heart and soul of our country. engineering, many of which are clerical. The past five years have been especially Manufacturing is the canary in the coal brutal, far different from earlier manufactur- mine for a “new economy” that has seen ing downturns. The nature of the decline is outsourcing spread to software, info tech, and structural, widespread, and deep. The 2001 re- financial services. The losses also have spread cession was precipitated by a manufac- turing depression that continues to this day. Since 1998, over 3.4 million manu- Since 1998, over 3.4 facturing jobs have been lost—2.9 mil- lion of those since 2001—with over half million manufacturing that total coming from union shops. In jobs have been lost—2.9 addition, since 1999, over 40,000 manu- facturing establishments have closed— million of those since medium and large plant closures have ac- 2001—with over half that counted for 90 percent of the job loss. The crisis hit everywhere and every- total coming from union one. State and local tax revenues with- ered, undermining important public ser- shops. vices. On a per capita basis, it has hit minorities, the south, and rural areas the hard- to the university level where engineering and est, as textiles, clothing, furniture and more sciences experienced declining enrollments, as closed or went offshore. Within manufactur- students turned away from degrees for which 56 • New Labor Forum B. Baugh and J. Yudken 20.0 19.0 18.0 17.0 16.0 Millions of jobs 15.0 14.0 13.0 Jan- Jan- Jan- Jan- Jan- Jan- Jan- Jan- Jan- Jan- Jan- Jan- Jan- Jan- Jan- Jan- 75 77 79 81 83 85 87 89 91 93 97 99 01 03 05 Figure 8. Manufacturing Employment 1975–2005. Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics there was no perceived opportunity. Just as pansions. The foreign direct investment (FDI) troubling is the precipitous decline in domes- flow into China reached $62 billion a year in tic manufacturing investment, which fell nearly 2004 and continues to soar. Seventy percent of 17 percent in real terms from its peak in 1998 China’s FDI is in manufacturing, with heavy and 2004, while investment in manufacturing concentration in export-oriented companies structures declined 44 percent over the same and advanced technology sectors. Contracted period. At the same time, many of the same (future) FDI projections are more than double firms are making record offshore investments the actual level today, with U.S.–based firms in R&D, engineering, design, and production leading the way. R&D, engineering, design are jobs. all part of the manufacturing investments and The investment flows portend future pro- jobs that the Chinese government is aggres- duction and exports to the United States. sively pursuing. Apologist claims that outsourcing is matched The startling loss of 40,000 manufactur- by insourcing (foreign investment in domestic ing establishments and over three million ex- manufacturing) are meant to mislead. The perienced workers underscores the damage to insourced investments are overwhelmingly a our national security. All of these establish- mere change of ownership that does not result ments and workers were part a greater indus- in new jobs and production facilities here. Not trial base that met both commercial and de- so in China, where these are startups and ex- fense needs. The factory floor serves as a source Is Deindustrialization Inevitable? New Labor Forum • 57 of experimentation, innovation, and product Ford and many others firms that initially development. Many of the engineers, scientists, downplayed the international challenge. In time and skilled workers that work on commercial they learned how to respond to the challenges products one week are the same ones that work of innovation, efficiency, and quality. Employ- on defense applications the next. This vital link ers, unions, and workers both struggled and co- between production and innovation, however, operated as they adapted new technology and is being severed as manufacturers move plants work organization practices. But this is not the offshore, a move aided and abetted by Penta- only path corporations took. gon policies to promote globalization of defense products. This trend is evident in a wide range of important industries, Th[e] vital link between from high-tech sectors such as micro- electronics, printed circuit boards, and production and advanced materials; to traditional sectors innovation…is being such as machine tools and ball bearings; to large “systems integrators” such as severed as manufacturers aerospace and shipbuilding. move plants offshore … The loss of skilled production work- ers, scientists, engineers, and technical and professional workers across the manufac- There was another response, the interna- turing sector means that the next best idea, the tionalization of production—a worldwide next innovation, the next generation of prod- search for cheap labor and subsidies. One ex- ucts, and the next investment will be made ample is Nike Corp., a company that has never somewhere else, not in the United States. manufactured a shoe in the United States. Phil Knight began Nike as a virtual company—mod- FROM INTERNATIONAL eled after his Stanford master’s thesis—that did COMPETITION TO design and marketing here while seeking Asian vendors and cheap labor for production. INTERNATIONALIZATION OF The same dynamic took hold in major PRODUCTION manufacturing industries like auto. While part- HE WORLD HAS CHANGED DRAMATICALLY FOR nerships were being built in domestic plants, TAmerican manufacturing over the past six the industry began internationalizing their pro- decades. Since the end of WWII we have gone duction. They sought cheap nonunion labor by from domestic production to international regionalizing production to Mexico. Even be- competition to the internationalization of pro- fore the 1995 North American Free Trade duction. Agreement (NAFTA), the company now In the 1980s international competition known as Delphi had 50,000 employees in brought a rude awakening for American manu- Mexico. But, in addition to cheap labor and facturing. Henry Ford II’s glib “mini cars, mini weak laws, there were other incentives in place profits” dismissal of Toyota came back to haunt for Nike, Delphi, and other firms. 58 • New Labor Forum B. Baugh and J. Yudken THE POLICY TRAP: TRADE, cent of the plant closing costs even though de- TAXES, AND HEALTH CARE ferral may permit it to avoid tax on the income from the overseas operations. Similarly, a com- ONG BEFORE NAFTA, WALL STREET AND MUL- pany can fund its foreign operations by bor- Ltinationals saw the internationalization of rowing money in the United States and mak- production as the way to maximize profits by ing an equity investment in its foreign subsid- any means necessary.
Recommended publications
  • India's Deindustrialization in the 18Th and 19Th Centuries
    India’s Deindustrialization in the 18th and 19th Centuries by David Clingingsmith Jeffrey G. Williamson Harvard University August 2005 We are grateful for advice and criticism from Leah Platt Boustan, Greg Clark, Ron Findlay, Bishnupriya Gupta, Peter Harnetty, Debin Ma, Patrick O’Brien, Kevin O’Rourke, Şevket Pamuk, Leandro Prados, Ananth Seshadri, T. N. Srinivasan, Tirthanker Roy, Tony Venables, and participants in the Harvard Economic History Tea, the 5th World Cliometrics Conference (Venice: June 2004), and the Stockholm School of Economics (Stockholm: October 2004). We also thank Javier Cuenca Esteban and Bishnupriya Gupta for sharing their data. Clingingsmith acknowledges support from the Project on Justice, Welfare, and Economics at Harvard University. Williamson acknowledges support from the National Science Foundation SES-0001362, and the productive work environment in the University of Wisconsin–Madison Economics Department, where he was on leave from Harvard when much of this paper was written. Abstract India was a major player in the world export market for textiles in the early 18th century, but by the middle of the 19th century it had lost all of its export market and much of its domestic market. India underwent secular deindustrialization as a consequence. While India produced about 25 percent of world industrial output in 1750, this figure had fallen to only 2 percent by 1900. We ask how much of India’s deindustrialization was due to local supply-side influences, such as the political and economic fragmentation of the 18th century, and how much to world price shocks. We use an open, three-sector model to organize our thinking about the relative role played by domestic and foreign forces.
    [Show full text]
  • The Great Divergence the Princeton Economic History
    THE GREAT DIVERGENCE THE PRINCETON ECONOMIC HISTORY OF THE WESTERN WORLD Joel Mokyr, Editor Growth in a Traditional Society: The French Countryside, 1450–1815, by Philip T. Hoffman The Vanishing Irish: Households, Migration, and the Rural Economy in Ireland, 1850–1914, by Timothy W. Guinnane Black ’47 and Beyond: The Great Irish Famine in History, Economy, and Memory, by Cormac k Gráda The Great Divergence: China, Europe, and the Making of the Modern World Economy, by Kenneth Pomeranz THE GREAT DIVERGENCE CHINA, EUROPE, AND THE MAKING OF THE MODERN WORLD ECONOMY Kenneth Pomeranz PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PRINCETON AND OXFORD COPYRIGHT 2000 BY PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS PUBLISHED BY PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS, 41 WILLIAM STREET, PRINCETON, NEW JERSEY 08540 IN THE UNITED KINGDOM: PRINCETON UNIVERSITY PRESS, 3 MARKET PLACE, WOODSTOCK, OXFORDSHIRE OX20 1SY ALL RIGHTS RESERVED LIBRARY OF CONGRESS CATALOGING-IN-PUBLICATION DATA POMERANZ, KENNETH THE GREAT DIVERGENCE : CHINA, EUROPE, AND THE MAKING OF THE MODERN WORLD ECONOMY / KENNETH POMERANZ. P. CM. — (THE PRINCETON ECONOMIC HISTORY OF THE WESTERN WORLD) INCLUDES BIBLIOGRAPHICAL REFERENCES AND INDEX. ISBN 0-691-00543-5 (CL : ALK. PAPER) 1. EUROPE—ECONOMIC CONDITIONS—18TH CENTURY. 2. EUROPE—ECONOMIC CONDITIONS—19TH CENTURY. 3. CHINA— ECONOMIC CONDITIONS—1644–1912. 4. ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT—HISTORY. 5. COMPARATIVE ECONOMICS. I. TITLE. II. SERIES. HC240.P5965 2000 337—DC21 99-27681 THIS BOOK HAS BEEN COMPOSED IN TIMES ROMAN THE PAPER USED IN THIS PUBLICATION MEETS THE MINIMUM REQUIREMENTS OF ANSI/NISO Z39.48-1992 (R1997) (PERMANENCE OF PAPER) WWW.PUP.PRINCETON.EDU PRINTED IN THE UNITED STATES OF AMERICA 3579108642 Disclaimer: Some images in the original version of this book are not available for inclusion in the eBook.
    [Show full text]
  • Deindustrialization in Cities of the Global South
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by White Rose Research Online This is a repository copy of Deindustrialization in cities of the global south. White Rose Research Online URL for this paper: http://eprints.whiterose.ac.uk/160159/ Version: Published Version Article: Schindler, S., Gillespie, T., Banks, N. et al. (4 more authors) (2020) Deindustrialization in cities of the global south. Area Development and Policy. pp. 1-22. ISSN 2379-2949 https://doi.org/10.1080/23792949.2020.1725393 Reuse This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) licence. This licence allows you to distribute, remix, tweak, and build upon the work, even commercially, as long as you credit the authors for the original work. More information and the full terms of the licence here: https://creativecommons.org/licenses/ Takedown If you consider content in White Rose Research Online to be in breach of UK law, please notify us by emailing [email protected] including the URL of the record and the reason for the withdrawal request. [email protected] https://eprints.whiterose.ac.uk/ Area Development and Policy ISSN: 2379-2949 (Print) 2379-2957 (Online) Journal homepage: https://www.tandfonline.com/loi/rard20 Deindustrialization in cities of the Global South Seth Schindler, Tom Gillespie, Nicola Banks, Mustafa Kemal Bayırbağ, Himanshu Burte, J. Miguel Kanai & Neha Sami To cite this article: Seth Schindler, Tom Gillespie, Nicola Banks, Mustafa Kemal Bayırbağ, Himanshu Burte, J. Miguel Kanai & Neha Sami (2020): Deindustrialization in cities of the Global South, Area Development and Policy, DOI: 10.1080/23792949.2020.1725393 To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1080/23792949.2020.1725393 © 2020 The Author(s).
    [Show full text]
  • Michigan State Presentation
    Restoring Prosperity The State Role in Revitalizing America’s Older Industrial Cities I What is the Restoring Prosperity Initiative? II What are the findings of the report? How can states restore prosperity to older III industrial cities? The Restoring Prosperity Initiative has developed an empirically-based inventory of struggling older industrial cities by josephpetepickle Cleveland by compujeramey Milwaukee Based on this research, the Initiative proposes a policy agenda for revitalizing older industrial cities Hartford by ChadBriggs Detroit In the coming months and years, we will help to organize a network of state and local reformers in target states to advance this agenda The Restoring Prosperity report, the initiative’s first major product, advances three primary messages Given their assets, the moment is ripe for the revival of older industrial urban economies Cleveland States have an essential role to play in the revitalization of older industrial cities, but they need a new urban agenda for change Providence The overall benefits of city revitalization—for families, for suburbs, for the environment, and ultimately for states—are potentially enormous I What is the Restoring Prosperity Initiative? II What are the findings of the report? How can states restore prosperity to older III industrial cities? I What are the findings of the report? We have identified 65 cities in 24 states that are underperforming economically Several forces are contributing to the underperformance of these cities But, the moment is right for change Based
    [Show full text]
  • Robie Kholilurrahman Politics of Premature Deindustrialization: the Case of Indonesia POLITICS of PREMATURE DEINDUSTRIALIZATION
    Robie Kholilurrahman Politics of Premature Deindustrialization: The Case of Indonesia POLITICS OF PREMATURE DEINDUSTRIALIZATION: THE CASE OF INDONESIA1 Robie Kholilurrahman Abstract: The available literature on the issue of premature deindustrialization in developing countries has been mainly economic, i.e., explaining the economic causes of the phenomenon, such as trade liberalization (e.g., Bogliaccini 2013); and technological progress (e.g., Rodrik 2016). With this focus, the literature generally understands deindustrialization as an inevitable and secular trend of current economic development at the global level. This paper utilizes Indonesia's experience with premature deindustrialization to argue that the current established literature overlooks political causes--such as the breakdown of state capacity and authority, on the one hand, and capital being set loose, on the other; and failure in tackling the economic-political reform dilemma following the democratic transition. This omission undermines the role of agency and the possibility of overcoming this current problematic situation. Moreover, using a counter-factual analysis by comparing Indonesia’s experience with how other countries affected by the 1997 crisis handled the IMF situation and how Indonesia itself handled another commodity (oil) boom in the 1970s, this paper further argues that premature deindustrialization would have not occurred even if the economic causes were there, had the political causes not also occurred—thus putting back the politics into the equation. Key Words: Premature Deindustrialization; State-Capital Relation; Democratic Transition 1 This is a draft in progress for Arryman research paper which will be presented on May 12, 2018 at Buffett Institute. An earlier draft was submitted for Professor Riedl’s Comparative Politics Proseminar II, Winter 2018.
    [Show full text]
  • The Role of Educational Attainment in Migration Probability and Destination Selection for the Metropolitan Rust Belt, 1980-2000
    Utah State University DigitalCommons@USU All Graduate Theses and Dissertations Graduate Studies 8-2012 The Role of Educational Attainment in Migration Probability and Destination Selection for the Metropolitan Rust Belt, 1980-2000 Paul D. Jacobs Utah State University Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.usu.edu/etd Part of the Sociology Commons Recommended Citation Jacobs, Paul D., "The Role of Educational Attainment in Migration Probability and Destination Selection for the Metropolitan Rust Belt, 1980-2000" (2012). All Graduate Theses and Dissertations. 1301. https://digitalcommons.usu.edu/etd/1301 This Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the Graduate Studies at DigitalCommons@USU. It has been accepted for inclusion in All Graduate Theses and Dissertations by an authorized administrator of DigitalCommons@USU. For more information, please contact [email protected]. THE ROLE OF EDUCATIONAL ATTAINMENT IN MIGRATION PROBABILITY AND DESTINATION SELECTION FOR THE METROPOLITAN RUST BELT, 1980-2000 by Paul D. Jacobs A thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of MASTER OF SCIENCE in Sociology Approved: _________________________ __________________________ Christy Glass E. Helen Berry Major Professor Committee Member _________________________ __________________________ Michael B. Toney Mark R. McLellan Committee Member Vice President for Research and Dean of the School of Graduate Studies UTAH STATE UNIVERSITY Logan, Utah 2012 ii Copyright © Paul Jacobs 2012 All Rights Reserved iii ABSTRACT The Role of Educational Attainment in Migration Probability and Destination Choice for the Metropolitan Rust Belt, 1970-2000 by Paul Jacobs, Master of Science Utah State University, 2012 Major Professor: Dr. Christy Glass Department: Sociology The U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • Deindustrialization in 18Th and 19Th Century India: Mughal Decline, Climate Shocks and British Industrial Ascent*
    Deindustrialization in 18th and 19th Century India: Mughal Decline, Climate Shocks and British Industrial Ascent* David Clingingsmith Jeffrey G. Williamson Weatherhead School of Management Department of Economics Case Western Reserve University Harvard University 11119 Bellflower Road, Room 281 Cambridge MA 02138 Cleveland, Ohio 44106-7235 and CEPR and NBER 216-368-4294 617-495-2438 [email protected] [email protected] *We are grateful for advice and criticism from William Bernstein, Leah Platt Boustan, Huw Bowen, William Clarence-Smith, Greg Clark, Ron Findlay, Bishnupriya Gupta, Peter Harnetty, Debin Ma, Bob Margo, Patrick O’Brien, Kevin O’Rourke, Şevket Pamuk, Leandro Prados, Om Prakash, Ananth Seshadri, T. N. Srinivasan, Tirthanker Roy, Tony Venables, two anonymous referees for this journal and participants in the Harvard Economic History Tea and Workshop, the 5th World Cliometrics Conference (Venice: June 2004), the Stockholm School of Economics (Stockholm: October 2004), and the GEHN Conference on Imperialism (Istanbul: September 2005). We also thank Javier Cuenca Esteban and Bishnupriya Gupta for sharing their data. Clingingsmith acknowledges support from the Project on Justice, Welfare, and Economics at Harvard University. Williamson acknowledges support from the National Science Foundation and from the Harvard Faculty of Arts and Sciences. Abstract India was a major player in the world export market for textiles in the early 18th century, but by the middle of the 19th century it had lost all of its export market and much of its domestic market, primarily to Britain. The ensuing deindustrialization was greatest c1750-c1860. We ask how much of India’s deindustrialization was due to local supply-side forces -- such as political fragmentation and a rising incidence of drought, and how much to world price shocks.
    [Show full text]
  • Globalization and Deindustrialization in the Third World Before The
    Inaugural Lecture Universitat Pompeu Fabra October 8 2008 Globalization and the Great Divergence Jeffrey G. Williamson Harvard University and the University of Wisconsin Motivation In David Landes’ (1998) words, why is the Third World periphery in the South so poor, and the industrial OECD core in the North so rich? The competing explanations or fundamentals: Culture: Polyani 1944; Landes 1998; Clark 2007 Geography: Diamond 1997; Sachs 2000, 2001; Easterly & Levine 2003 Institutions: North & Weingast 1989; AJR 2001, 2002, 2005 Problems Fundamentals don’t change very much over time. So, what explains the timing of the great divergence between Core and Periphery? Why did the gap open so fast 1800-1913? One possible explanation: the world was -- Closed and anti-global pre-1800 Open and pro-global 1800-1913 Closed and anti-global 1913-1950 Open and pro-global 1950-2008 Four Big Facts Fact 1: Rise in the Core-Periphery Income Per Capita Gap The rise of the North-South gap Rise in the Core-Periphery Income Per Capita Gap 1820-1998 14 12 10 Western Europe/Africa 8 Western Europe/Asia Western Europe/Latin 6 America Parity 4 2 Source: Maddison (2001, Table B-21) 0 1820 1870 1913 1950 1973 1998 … and extending backwards with real wages Table 1. The Great Divergence: Income Per Capita Gaps 1775-1913 1775 1820 1870 1913 Western Europe 100 100 100 100 Southern Europe 75.2 62.4 52.7 47.3 Eastern Europe 70.0 58.1 48.8 42.0 Latin America 75.2 55.3 37.9 40.9 Asia 56.4 42.6 27.5 20.0 Africa 46.1 34.8 22.7 15.5 Poor Periphery Average 64.6 50.6 37.9 33.1 Four Big Facts Fact 1: Rise in the Core-Periphery Income Per Capita Gap Fact 2: De-Industrialization in the Poor Periphery Do Industrial Countries Get Richer? Current GDP per capita 1820-1950 and Industrialization 50 or 70 Years Before Per Capita Levels of Industrialization 1750-1953 1750 1800 1860 1913 1953 European Core 8 8 17 45 90 Asian and Latin American Periphery 7 6 4 2 5 Ratio Core/Periphery 1.1 1.3 4.3 22.5 18 Source: Bairoch (1982, Table 4, p.
    [Show full text]
  • Deindustrialization: Causes and Implications Robert Rowthorn and Ramana Ramaswamy
    IV Deindustrialization: Causes and Implications Robert Rowthorn and Ramana Ramaswamy The advanced economies have experienced a secular decline in the share of manufacturing employment—a phenomenon referred to as deindustrialization. This paper argues that, contrary to popular perceptions, deindustrialization is not a negative phenomenon, but is the natural consequence of the industrial dynamism in an already developed economy, and that North-South trade has had little to do with deindustrialization. The paper also discusses the implications of deindustrialization for the growth prospects and the nature of labor market arrangements in the advanced economies. [JEL: 01, 03, Fl, F43] hree broad developments have been of concern to as Lawrence and Slaughter (1993), Krugman and Tthe advanced economies in recent years: the shrink- Lawrence (1994), Bhagwati (1995), and Krugman ing share of manufacturing employment, the stagnation (1996) have argued that the decline in unskilled wages of average real wages and the rise in inequality of earn- and the growing inequality of earnings between skilled ings since 1973 in the United States, and the massive and unskilled labor in the last two decades in the rise in unemployment since the early 1970s in much of United States have little to do with the growing trade Europe.1 These developments have coincided with a pe- links with the developing countries. Their arguments riod of unusually rapid growth in trade and capital are that manufactured imports from the developing movements—particularly between the advanced and countries constitute only a small fraction of U.S. developing countries. The coexistence of these phe- GDP—just over 2 percent in 1994, and that there is nomena has tended to foster the perception of a causal very little evidence of Stolper-Samuelson effects in the link from "globalization" to the labor market problems United States—that is, of a trade-induced decline in the confronting the advanced economies.
    [Show full text]
  • The Impact of the Technological Revolution on Labour Markets and Income Distribution
    Department of Economic & Social Affairs FRONTIER ISSUES 31 JULY 2017 The impact of the technological revolution on labour markets and income distribution CONTENTS Executive Summary .................................................... 1 1. Introduction ....................................................... 3 2. A new technological revolution? ....................................... 4 A. Technological progress and revolutions ............................. 4 B. Economic potential of the new technological breakthroughs ............. 7 3. Long term and recent trends .......................................... 8 A. Productivity trends .............................................. 8 B. Sectoral employment shifts and work conditions ..................... 11 C. Income inequality .............................................. 14 4. How does technological innovation affect labour markets and inequality? ..... 17 A. Job destruction and job creation ................................. 17 B. Occupational shifts, job polarization and wage inequality .............. 20 C. Technology and globalization .................................... 21 D. Technology and market structures. .22 E. Technology and the organization of work ........................... 23 F. Technology and the informal sector ............................... 23 G. Technology and female labour force participation .................... 24 5. Looking ahead: What will technology mean for labour and inequality? ........ 26 A. The future of technological progress ............................... 26
    [Show full text]
  • Deindustrialization and the Shift to Services Does the Employment Shift to Services Imply That the U.S
    Deindustrialization and the shift to services Does the employment shift to services imply that the U.S . is losing its industrial base? Data show the industrial sector as a whole in healthy shape, but a few manufacturing industries in deep trouble RONALD E. KUTSCHER AND VALERIE A. PERSONICK Much discussion and concern recently has been focused on terms has not declined appreciably over the last two decades the deindustrialization of the United States and the need for (except cyclically), and the most recent projections by the a national industrial policy. t The well-reported growth in Bureau of Labor Statistics show manufacturing employment employment in the service sector and the relative decline in recovering most of its current recession-related losses . Fur- employment in manufacturing industries implies to some a thermore, while employment in manufacturing is still off its decrease in our industrial capacity . The deindustrialization previous peak, the same is not true for output. Manufactur- argument points to a lack of investment in basic production, ing production in real terms has bounced back from the plant closings and layoffs, and the large negative merchan- recession and by 1984 had reached a new peak level, hardly dise trade balance as evidence that the United States is proof of a loss of our industrial base.z losing its manufacturing base . While little evidence of deindustrialization is present at But precisely how can deindustrialization be defined? the macro or aggregate level, an additional finding is that for Does the shift to a service economy imply the erosion of an about 20 manufacturing industries, including steel, leather, industrial base? Should deindustrialization be described as a and tires, the past 15 years have seen steady declines in both loss of manufacturing jobs or should production changes output and employment .
    [Show full text]
  • 38. Deindustrialization and Premature Deindustrialization Fiona Tregenna* in Ghosh, J., R
    38. Deindustrialization and premature deindustrialization Fiona Tregenna* in Ghosh, J., R. Kattel and E. Reinert (eds.) Elgar Handbook of Alternative Theories of Economic Development, 2016. INTRODUCTION Classical development economics, especially structuralist approaches, regard the manu- facturing sector as having special properties as an engine of economic growth. From this perspective, industrialization is the key route for developing economies to catch up with developed economies. These theoretical and policy approaches rose to prominence in the 1950s and 1960s, for instance in the approach advanced by the Economic Commission for Latin American and the Caribbean (ECLAC). At that time, industry was growing in most developed as well as developing economies. However, this has since been reversed, with de- industrialization setting in initially in advanced economies and subsequently in many middle- income and even lower- income economies as well. De- industrialization is intensifying over time, setting in at lower levels of income per capita, as well as at lower shares of manufacturing in countries’ employ- ment and gross domestic product (GDP), than earlier. While de- industrialization always refers to some sort of problems or decline in manu- facturing, there are alternative definitions of it. In an early study of de- industrialization, Bluestone and Harrison (1982, 6) define it as ‘systematic disinvestment in a nation’s core manufacturing industries’. Singh (1977) conceptualizes de- industrialization in terms of an ‘efficient’ manufacturing sector, which he defines as manufacturing being able to export enough to meet a country’s import requirements at acceptable levels of employment, output and exchange rate. De- industrialization is usually defined as a fall in the share of manufacturing in total employment (see, e.g., Rowthorn and Ramaswamy 1997; Saeger 1997; Alderson 1999; Rowthorn and Coutts 2004; Dasgupta and Singh 2006; Palma 2005, 2008).
    [Show full text]