Boiling Point

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Boiling Point 25 February 2021 Macro Picture BOILING POINT Dario Perkins Market concern about “overheating” looks misplaced. In fact, running economies “hot” – for the first time in a generation – could bring huge benefits. The policy should boost supply potential (as in times of war) and create new policy space in the fight against deflation. There are risks to financial markets, conditioned to zero interest rates, but the alternative is worse – a large bubble. Chart 1: Now is the time to experiment with “high-pressure” economics 0.2 rolling 30-year US Phillips curve coefficient* 0.0 -0.2 -0.4 -0.6 -0.8 -1.0 -1.2 -1.4 -1.6 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020 Source: TS Lombard estimates, *change in inflation that comes from 1%pts increase in unemployment OVER STIMULATED There is growing concern about “overheating”, particularly in the US. President Biden will pass another large stimulus, while the end of the pandemic should unlock powerful pent-up demand. Yet it will take more than a brief period of US economic resurgence to generate sustained inflation – especially as the demand boost is front-loaded and the world lacks secular catalysts. SUPPLY RESPONSE Inflation-worriers are not only underestimating the amount of slack in the economy, but also the potential for a “high-pressure” environment to lift supply capacity. Central banks are certainly keen to “run the economy hot” because it would also buy them insurance against deflation risk, creating new policy space. We review the evidence for positive hysteresis, esp. during WW2. HEAT DANGERS Now is not the time to bet against the reflation trade, especially with vaccines yet to take effect. Prices could spike temporarily higher on “reopening”, even if there is no danger of a sustained inflation outbreak. While central banks will remain extremely dovish, any inflation scare is still a risk to financial markets, conditioned to permazero rates. But the alternative is worse – bubbles! 欄 Book a video meeting with our analysts here BOILING POINT Inflation anxiety has been a recurring theme since the start of the COVID-19 crisis, which is not surprising given the nature of the shock and the massive policy response. These worries have increased again recently, fueling another selloff in bond markets. While there has long been a particularly noisy “policy-is-doing-too-much” brigade, they have now recruited some unlikely protagonists, including Larry Summers and Olivier Blanchard. Both economists were demanding massive fiscal stimulus before the pandemic, but are now worried that the budgetary response is becoming too large, especially in the United States. President Biden is pushing for another big stimulus programme, the second since the elections. Summers and Blanchard join a significant minority of investors who believe this fiscal support has arrived at a point in the pandemic where it is no longer needed, risking “overheating” and a sustained inflation problem. While there is an element of truth to this narrative – with COVID-19 vaccines set to unleash a vigorous economic recovery in 2021-22 – we think the warnings about sustained inflation are overdone. US fiscal stimulus/pent-up demand will fade relatively quickly, while the authorities in other jurisdictions are doing far less to support their economies. The world lacks a secular inflation catalyst. The economists who are worried about overheating base their inflation forecasts on a rather deterministic view of supply potential, rooted in flawed “output gap” measures. There are good reasons to think this approach has systematically underestimated the economy’s capacity, which could mean – even with further stimulus – most economies will not run into genuine capacity constraints anytime soon. Moreover, “running the economy hot”, which is something the authorities have generally avoided since the 1980s, might also elicit a supply improvement, through a process of ‘positive hysteresis’. There is certainly room to boost productivity, after a decade of inexplicable weakness, and to raise overall employment rates, especially in countries were participation has been declining (including the US). We also look at evidence from the Second World War, when a “hot” economy absorbed massive military expenditure without “crowding out” private activity. Sure, WW2 was associated with bursts of inflation, but these were mainly the result of specific machine shortages, rather than broad-based capacity pressures. Central banks are keen to repeat the “high-pressure economy” experiment today, with officials hoping this will provide extra protection against the lower policy bound (by raising r*). But they will need sustained expansion – not just a temporary fiscal boost – to realize their objective. What are the risks associated with running the economy “hot”? In contrast to the situation a decade ago, today the discussion is centered on the prospects for inflation, not the fear of the imaginary bond vigilantes or the risk of the public sector “crowding out” private-investment. This is an important victory for MMT, which has successfully moved the parameters of the debate. Nevertheless, there is no shortage of pundits who think inflation could quickly spiral out of control, with some even trying to resurrect the spectre of hyperinflation. Their analysis is clearly wrong – it not only misdiagnoses the causes of extreme inflation episodes (for which we offer a brief reminder) but it also forgets that central banks have retained their independence and are contemplating only a relatively minor overshoot. The monetary authorities have plenty of policy ammunition to deal with an inflation outbreak, if needed. In fact, the more serious risk from a high-pressure economy is what it might mean for financial markets, with asset prices increasingly conditioned to the prospect of permazero interest rates. While central banks will do their best to support financial conditions by staying dovish and downplaying the risk of inflation, they might not be averse to a further rise in bond yields, unless it causes wider turbulence (which they would certainly respond to). But a lot of frothiness now in asset prices, a high-pressure economy might ultimately provide a healthier macro environment for financial markets too. Macro Picture | 25 February 2021 欄 Book a video meeting with our analysts here 2 1. OVER STIMULATED The debate about inflation, which has featured prominently in our discussions with investors over the past year, is becoming increasingly intense. This is partly a disagreement about the nature of the economic crisis. Is it a mainly a contraction in supply, caused by government shutdowns, or is it mainly a demand shock? (It is both…) Will the crisis fade quickly like a natural disaster, or linger with permanent macro scarring? And then there is the debate about the policy response. Since the start of the pandemic, there have always been some investors who felt the policy stimulus would eventually become too large, causing the world economy to “overheat”. Oddly, the policy-is-doing-too-much brigade have recruited some unlikely supporters, with Larry Summers and Olivier Blanchard – arch Keynesians – recently voicing their concerns about the magnitude of the stimulus effort in the US. The tipping point was President Biden’s latest spending proposals, which add to the massive fiscal programme Congress had already passed in December. The Summers/Blanchard opposition is noteworthy because both economists had previously been fiscal activists, arguing this was the appropriate response to secular stagnation. Chart 2: Too much US stimulus? Chart 3: The largest fiscal expansion ever 10.0 per cent of US GDP change in US fiscal position, per cent of GDP 8.0 S&L crisis 6.0 4.0 Dotcom 2.0 Great Depression 0.0 -2.0 Subprime -4.0 World War 2 -6.0 CBO End 2021 Next Biden Excess COVID-19 shortfall in stimulus personal 2020 saving -10.0 -5.0 0.0 Source: CB, TS Lombard Source: BEA, TS Lombard Overheating worries Concern about overheating is mainly centred on the size of President Biden’s budget easing relative to consensus estimates of the output gap. Congress looks set to approve tax and spending measures worth around 7% of GDP, in addition to the 4% of GDP relief programme it agreed after the US election. The CBO, meanwhile, estimates a US output gap of around 4% of GDP in 2020, which it thinks will shrink to around 2% in 2021, as the economy reopens. Some economists believe this fiscal easing is poorly targeted and arrives at a point in the pandemic where it is no longer needed, with vaccines set to unleash a wave of pent-up demand. In fact, given the swell of excess savings in the economy, there may already be an “overhang” of policy stimulus. By protecting people’s income during the pandemic and simultaneously restricting their spending opportunities, governments encouraged the build-up of a substantial stock of excess savings. When the pandemic ends, households might run down this buffer – the saving rate could even turn negative for a while – producing an extremely powerful economic boom. Unusually, we are in a situation where economists of entirely different persuasions seem to agree on the dangers of a sustained inflation outbreak. Keynesians, for example, are obsessed with the size of the US stimulus programme relative to some underlying measure of the output Macro Picture | 25 February 2021 欄 Book a video meeting with our analysts here 3 gap, while – at the other end of the economics spectrum – monetarists are worried about the unprecedented expansion in the money supply. The two developments are clearly related. By retaining their excess saving in highly liquid form, households and corporates have caused bank deposits to swell, producing a massive increase in the money supply. According to standard monetarist analysis, many households now hold a larger stock of liquid assets that they would normally desire, which they must eventually try to eliminate by spending more on good and services (or putting the cash into financial markets).
Recommended publications
  • Macroeconomic Overheating and Financial Vulnerability [PRELIMINARY DRAFT]
    Macroeconomic Overheating and Financial Vulnerability [PRELIMINARY DRAFT] Elena Afanasyeva,∗ Seung Jung Lee,y Michele Modugno,z and Francisco Palominox{ June 1, 2019 Abstract An overheated economy has the potential to lead to financial imbalances, which in turn could generate or amplify economic distress. We study the link between macroeconomic performance and financial imbalances, focusing on the experience of the United States since the 1960s. We first follow a narrative approach to review historical episodes of significant financial imbalances and find weak links between periods of strong growth and financial imbalances. We then look for evidence of a statistical link between measures of economic slack and financial system vul- nerability. Despite strong in-sample links, the gains from using the economic slack information to forecast financial vulnerability are typically limited out of sample. Measures of nonfinancial leverage constitute a notable exception, where the links are strong. In a non-linear setting of quantile regressions, measures of economic slack have a small effect on the distribution of finan- cial conditions. Overall, we find that macroeconomic overheating can contribute to the build-up of financial vulnerabilities only via the increase in nonfinancial sector leverage. JEL classification: C32; G21; N22. Keywords: Macroeconomic Overheating; Financial Vulnerability; Forecasting; Quantile Re- gression. ∗E-mail: [email protected]. yE-mail: [email protected]. zE-mail: [email protected]. xE-mail: [email protected]. {All authors are at the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. We thank Alex Martin for excellent research assistance. We thank Mark Carlson, Luca Guerrieri, Michael Kiley, Ed Nelson, and Michael Palumbo for their helpful comments.
    [Show full text]
  • Hyperinflation in Venezuela
    POLICY BRIEF recovery can be possible without first stabilizing the explo- 19-13 Hyperinflation sive price level. Doing so will require changing the country’s fiscal and monetary regimes. in Venezuela: A Since late 2018, authorities have been trying to control the price spiral by cutting back on fiscal expenditures, contracting Stabilization domestic credit, and implementing new exchange rate poli- cies. As a result, inflation initially receded from its extreme Handbook levels, albeit to a very high and potentially unstable 30 percent a month. But independent estimates suggest that prices went Gonzalo Huertas out of control again in mid-July 2019, reaching weekly rates September 2019 of 10 percent, placing the economy back in hyperinflation territory. Instability was also reflected in the premium on Gonzalo Huertas was research analyst at the Peterson Institute foreign currency in the black market, which also increased for International Economics. He worked with C. Fred Bergsten in July after a period of relative calm in previous months. Senior Fellow Olivier Blanchard on macroeconomic theory This Policy Brief describes a feasible stabilization plan and policy. Before joining the Institute, Huertas worked as a researcher at Harvard University for President Emeritus and for Venezuela’s extreme inflation. It places the country’s Charles W. Eliot Professor Lawrence H. Summers, producing problems in context by outlining the economics behind work on fiscal policy, and for Minos A. Zombanakis Professor Carmen Reinhart, focusing on exchange rate interventions. hyperinflations: how they develop, how they disrupt the normal functioning of economies, and how other countries Author’s Note: I am grateful to Adam Posen, Olivier Blanchard, across history have designed policies to overcome them.
    [Show full text]
  • Designing a European Unemployment Insurance Scheme
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Andor, László et al. Article — Published Version Designing a European unemployment insurance scheme Intereconomics Suggested Citation: Andor, László et al. (2014) : Designing a European unemployment insurance scheme, Intereconomics, ISSN 1613-964X, Springer, Heidelberg, Vol. 49, Iss. 4, pp. 184-203, http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10272-014-0500-4 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/106778 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Forum DOI: 10.1007/s10272-014-0500-4 Designing a European Unemployment Insurance Scheme With disparities in national unemployment rates reaching record levels, the debate on fi scal stabilisers in Europe has gained new momentum.
    [Show full text]
  • U.S. Economy in Slow Roll Toward Full Late-Cycle Phase
    leadership series NOVEMBER 2016 BUSINESS CYCLE UPDATE U.S. Economy in Slow Roll Toward Full Late-Cycle Phase Strengthening inflationary signals are directionally consistent with prior late-cycle phases Dirk Hofschire, CFA l Senior Vice President, Asset Allocation Research Lisa Emsbo-Mattingly l Director of Asset Allocation Research Jacob Weinstein, CFA l Senior Analyst, Asset Allocation Research Joshua Lund-Wilde, CFA l Research Analyst, Asset Allocation Research MORE IN KEY TAKEAWAYS THIS ISSUE • The late-cycle phase can often be characterized as an overheating stage for the economy, when Credit Standards Tightening as Spreads Narrow growth peaks and inflation accelerates. PAGE #3 • The low magnitude of growth and inflation has Wage Growth Continues to Accelerate prolonged this U.S. cycle, but similarities in the PAGE #3 direction of the cycle resemble historical late- cycle transitions. Asset Allocation Implications of Late Cycle PAGE #4 • U.S. inflation is poised to accelerate amid tighter U.S. Business Cycle: Consumer Supports Continued labor markets and higher oil prices. Expansion • With the global trade recession of 2015 in PAGE #5 the past, worldwide deflationary pressures are Global Deflationary Pressures Receding receding. PAGE #6 • The late-cycle phase historically has warranted China Enters Early Cycle smaller cyclical asset allocation tilts and has PAGE #6 favored inflation-resistant assets. Business Cycle Framework PAGE #7 Fidelity’s Asset Allocation Research Team employs a multi-time-horizon asset allocation approach that analyzes trends among three temporal segments: tactical (short term), business cycle (medium term), and secular (long term). This monthly report focuses primarily on the intermediate-term fluctuations in the business cycle, and the influence those changes could have on the outlook for various asset classes.
    [Show full text]
  • 15.015 Macro and International Economics, Lecture 08 Summary
    Simon Johnson: One Page Summary 15.015, class #8: Crisis in Asia, 1997-98 RECAP: BBNN, with a focus on the NN curve (and inflation) Inflation is a sustained increase in wages and prices – think of it as an upwards and self- reinforcing “spiral”. A one-off adjustment in the price level is not inflation; inflation means that wages increase and prices continue to rise. An increase in the price of specific goods – for example, commodity prices – is not inflation. For a country that imports oil, for example, higher oil prices represent an adverse movement in the “terms of trade” – meaning that the country needs to export more in order to afford the same amount of oil. In BBNN space, this is a shift up and to the left of the BB curve, which is likely to result in a current account deficit. But this is not the same as inflation. There are two ways for inflation to appear in a developed economy, (a) through overheating, i.e., attempting to run the economy with unemployment below the “full employment” level, (b) because inflation expectations lose their anchor, so people expect a lot more inflation than has been the case in the recent past. “Full employment” is sometimes called the “natural rate of unemployment” or the “non- accelerating inflation rate of unemployment” (or NAIRU). Overheating means that the economy is above the full employment level, so wages tend to rise – and this pushes up prices, thus creating inflation. The NN curve slopes down because it shows combinations of the real exchange rate (e/w) and domestic spending (C+I+G) for which the economy has full employment.
    [Show full text]
  • What Ends Recessions?
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1994, Volume 9 Volume Author/Editor: Stanley Fischer and Julio J. Rotemberg, eds. Volume Publisher: MIT Press Volume ISBN: 0-262-05172-4 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/fisc94-1 Conference Date: March 11-12, 1994 Publication Date: January 1994 Chapter Title: What Ends Recessions? Chapter Author: Christina D. Romer, David H. Romer Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c11007 Chapter pages in book: (p. 13 - 80) Christina D. Romer and David H. Romer UNIVERSITYOF CALIFORNIA,BERKELEY AND NBER What Ends Recessions? 1. Introduction The Employment Act of 1946 set as the goal of government economic policy the maintenance of reasonably full employment and stable prices. Yet, nearly 50 years later, economists seem strangely unsure about what to tell policymakers to do to end recessions. One source of this uncer- tainty is confusion about how macroeconomic policies have actually been used to combat recessions. In the midst of the most recent recession, one heard opinions of fiscal policy ranging from the view that no recession has ever ended without fiscal expansion to the view that fiscal stimulus has always come too late. Similarly, for monetary policy there was disagreement about whether looser policy has been a primary engine of recovery from recessions or whether it has been relatively unimportant in these periods. This paper seeks to fill in this gap in economists' knowledge by analyzing what has ended the eight recessions that have occurred in the United States since 1950.
    [Show full text]
  • Argentina and Overheating: Monetary Policy and Inflation
    JEL code: E00, E31, E52 Argentina and Overheating: Monetary Policy and Inflation Mathew Bradbury, PhD. City University of New York Abstract: Argentina's default in 2001 signaled a commitment to heterodox approaches in macroeconomic policy making. Much debate has centered around the merits of this approach. In the decade post- default Argentina has maintained on of the highest growth rates in the region. And has claimed impressive gains in areas such as unemployment, poverty reduction and social spending. Commodity prices during the mid 2000s, strong demand from China, and insulation from the global financial crises all added to the fortunes of the Argentine economy. But, Argentina is widely considered to be at high risk of overheating. Government and private estimates of inflation diverge greatly. When private estimates of inflation are used the sustainability of the Argentine growth path comes under question. This paper provides an overview of inflation in Argentina and discusses the ways through which inflation may threaten it growth path. 1. Introduction Over the last decade Argentina, like many Latin American countries has expanded it's trade linkages. Its most significant partners are Brazil and China. This more integrated trade relationships with China have allowed many to bounce back quickly from the crisis. Soya products have tripled in price. Roughly 90% of Argentina's soya crop has a final destination of China. And China is committed to a long term investment of 1.5bn toward Argentina's agricultural production. Argentina enjoys not only this trade relationship but, after default in 2001, has been unable to develop strong linkages with international capital markets.
    [Show full text]
  • OUTPUT STABILIZATION PROPERTIES of a EUROPEAN UNEMPLOYMENT BENEFIT SCHEME: WHAT IS KNOWN SO FAR Inês Sofia Alves Oliveira Da Rosa
    OUTPUT STABILIZATION PROPERTIES OF A EUROPEAN UNEMPLOYMENT BENEFIT SCHEME: WHAT IS KNOWN SO FAR Inês Sofia Alves Oliveira da Rosa Dissertation Master in Economics Supervised by Álvaro Aguiar 2019 Acknowledgments At the end of this stage, I would like to express my sincere thanks to all those who directly or indirectly contributed to the realization of this dissertation. Firstly, I would like to thank Professor Álvaro Aguiar, my supervisor, for the endless help, availability and patience, as well as for all the constructive criticism and knowledge shared during this process. Secondly, I want to thank my parents, my sister and Pedro, my boyfriend, for always supporting me in achieving my goals and pushing me to be the best version of myself. Finally, I would also like to thank all my colleagues and friends, especially Mafalda de Castro and Rita Reis, for the never-ending patience and support throughout this project. i Abstract The recent Great Recession rekindled the debate over the need for a transfers’ mechanism that allows for output stabilization inside the euro area, namely a European Unemployment Benefit Scheme. This question was firstly analysed in the contexts of the Theory of the Optimum Currency Areas and the Theory of Fiscal Federalism. Several Institutions and academics have since put forward proposals on this scheme as a mean to further increase the stabilization of the euro area, mainly against asymmetric shocks. This dissertation develops a simple common metric that is applied to five proposals in order to assess what is known, so far, about the stabilization capacity of further euro area fiscal integration (minimal fiscal union) in the form of a fiscal-transfers’ stabilizing mechanism, particularly a European Unemployment Benefit Scheme.
    [Show full text]
  • On the Design of a European Unemployment Insurance
    On the Design of a European Unemployment Insurance Ekaterina J¨urgens A thesis submitted for the degree of Master of Science in Economics to the University of Cologne Faculty of Management, Economics and Social Sciences First supervisor: Prof. Michael Krause, Ph.D. Second supervisor: Prof. Dr. Andreas Schabert Cologne April 2019 Abstract To make Eurozone more resistant to crises, a common European Unemployment Insurance (EUI) has been discussed as a shock absorption instrument on the union level. Such a EUI could have a large capacity to work as an automatic stabilizer and ensure regional risk-sharing in the monetary union. However, its implementation is associated with challenges, namely, the moral hazard effect and the need to align the national unemployment benefit (UB) schemes. By means of literature review and theoretical macroeconomic analysis, based on a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model with frictional labour markets, this paper evaluates whether a EUI could be a suitable shock absorption tool and how it should be designed to fit the purpose without hazardous side effects. A model of two countries is developed and calibrated to the core and periphery of the Eurozone to inspect the stabilization effects of a centralized unemployment insurance in case asymmetric shocks hit the union. It is demonstrated that a com- mon UB fund brings about substantial stabilization gains. Differences in labour market parameters and social security systems are not a major obstacle to imple- ment it. The transfer system enables adoption of countercyclical fiscal policy, while keeping UB payments much more stable throughout the cycle. This ensures an overall smoother consumption path.
    [Show full text]
  • Academy of Finland 59 Box 5.8 Elearning 60 Box 6.1 Case of Ahlström and Altim Control Ltd
    39378 The World Bank 1818 H Street, N.W. Washington, D.C. 20433 USA Public Disclosure AuthorizedPublic Disclosure Authorized Finland Finland has been ranked number one for the fourth time since 2000 in the World Economic Forum’s Global Competitiveness Index. as a “…The country owes its strong showing to one of the most innovative Knowledge Economy business environments in the world, particularly critical to driving Elements of Success and Lessons Learned productivity in the country, given its advanced stage of development. This is coupled with a very healthy macroeconomic environment, at a Public Disclosure AuthorizedPublic Disclosure Authorized time when many other industrial countries are struggling in this area. Edited by The willingness of Finnish governments to run budget surpluses, so as to Carl J. Dahlman be able to meet future social commitments linked to the aging of the Jorma Routti population is particularly impressive. This approach to macroeconomic policy highlights a degree of political maturity in Finnish society worthy Pekka Ylä-Anttila of emulation. Furthermore, Finland has an institutional environment that is among the world’s finest: the business community operates in a climate Public Disclosure AuthorizedPublic Disclosure Authorized of respect for the law, unusually low levels of corruption, and an openness and transparency which other countries would do well to study.” Dr. Augusto Lopez-Claros, Chief Economist and Director, Global Competitiveness Programme, World Economic Forum in The Global Competitiveness Report 2005–2006, Executive Summary, pages xiv–xv. Houndmills, UK: Palgrave Macmillan. Public Disclosure AuthorizedPublic Disclosure Authorized i-xiv_Finland_FM.qxd 2/8/06 4:21 PM Page i Finland as a Knowledge Economy Elements of Success and Lessons Learned Edited by Carl J.
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Prosperity Recaptured: the Finnish Path from Crisis to Rapid
    Economic Prosperity Recaptured The Finnish Path from Crisis to Rapid Growth Seppo Honkapohja, Erkki A. Koskela, Willi Leibfritz, and Roope Uusitalo The MIT Press Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England ( 2009 Massachusetts Institute of Technology All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reproduced in any form by any elec- tronic or mechanical means (including photocopying, recording, or information storage and retrieval) without permission in writing from the publisher. For information about special quantity discounts, please e-mail special_sales@mitpress .mit.edu This book was set in Palatino on 3B2 by Asco Typesetters, Hong Kong. Printed and bound in the United States of America. Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Economic prosperity recaptured : the Finnish path from crisis to rapid growth / Seppo Honkapohja . [et al.]. p. cm. — (CESifo book series) Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN 978-0-262-01269-0 (hardcover : alk. paper) 1. Finland—Economic conditions—1981– 2. Finland—Economic policy. I. Honkapohja, Seppo, 1951– HC340.2.E26 2009 330.948970034—dc22 2008041709 10987654321 1 Introduction The period since the late 1980s is seen in economic history as a time of major changes in both the European and world economies. There have been several notable developments. The breakdown of socialism in Eastern and East-Central Europe was a dramatic event in the European political landscape. It also initiated major structural changes in Europe. The most significant changes naturally occurred within the former so- cialist countries themselves, but the neighboring countries were also affected. Economic integration in the European Union (EU) deepened with the creation of the single-market program.
    [Show full text]
  • Denmark: 2020
    EUROPEAN COMMISSION Brussels, 26.2.2020 SWD(2020) 503 final COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT Country Report Denmark 2020 Accompanying the document COMMUNICATION FROM THE COMMISSION TO THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT, THE EUROPEAN COUNCIL, THE COUNCIL, THE EUROPEAN CENTRAL BANK AND THE EUROGROUP 2020 European Semester: Assessment of progress on structural reforms, prevention and correction of macroeconomic imbalances, and results of in-depth reviews under Regulation (EU) No 1176/2011 {COM(2020) 150 final} EN EN CONTENTS Executive summary 3 1. Economic situation and outlook 7 2. Progress with country-specific recommendations 15 3. Reform priorities 19 3.1 Public finances and taxation 19 3.2. Financial sector 22 3.3. Labour market, education and social policies 27 3.4. Competitiveness, reforms and investment 36 3.5. Environmental sustainability 45 A. Overview table 50 B. Commission debt sustainability analysis and fiscal risks 55 C. Standard tables 56 D. Investment guidance on Just Transition Fund 2021-2027 for Denmark 62 E. Progress towards the Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs) 64 References 69 LIST OF TABLES 3.2.1. Financial soundness indicators, all banks in Denmark 23 3.4.1. Selected indicators on digitisation of businesses, 2019 (% of enterprises) 42 C.1. Financial market indicators 56 C.2. Headline Social Scoreboard indicators 56 C.3. Labour market and education indicators 57 C.4. Social inclusion and health indicators 58 C.5. Product market performance and policy indicators 59 C.6. Green growth 60 LIST OF GRAPHS 1.1. GDP growth and contributions 7 1.2. Contributions to potential growth 8 1.3. Goods and services inflation 9 1.4.
    [Show full text]