Frank Germann, Peter Ebbes, & Rajdeep Grewal

MTarkehtinge ac adCemichs ained pfra ctiMtioneras arlikke rematini unncognvin cOed afbofuti tche echierf mMarketiang toftficeer’sr (CsMO! ’s) performance implications. Whereas some studies propose that firms benefit financially from having a CMO in the C-suite, other studies conclude that the CMO has little or no effect on firm performance. Accordingly, there have been strong calls for additional academic research regarding the CMO’s performance implications. In response to these calls, the authors employ model specifications with varying identifying assumptions (i.e., rich data models, unobserved effects models, instrumental variable models, and panel internal instruments models) and use data from up to 155 publicly traded firms over a 12-year period (2000–2011) to find that firms can indeed expect to benefit financially from having a CMO at the strategy table. Specifically, their findings suggest that the performance (measured in terms of Tobin’s q) of the sample firms that employ a CMO is, on average, approximately 15% greater than that of the sample firms that do not employ a CMO. This result is robust to the type of model specification used. Marketing academics and practitioners should find the results intriguing given the existing uncertainty surrounding the CMO’s performance implications. The study also contributes to the methodology literature by collating diverse empirical model specifications that can be used to model causal effects with observational data into a coherent and comprehensive framework.

Keywords : chief marketing officer performance implications, marketing–finance interface, panel data, endogeneity, instrumental variable

Online Supplement : http://dx.doi.org/10.1509/jm.14.0244

n 2008, Nath and Mahajan reported that “[Chief market - data), Weinzimmer et al. (2003) find a positive correlation ing officer] presence in the Top Team between CMO presence and sales growth. It is also widely (TMT) has neither a positive nor a negative impact on believed that CMO presence raises the importance of mar - firm performance” (p. 65). In the words of Barta (2011), keting in the C-suite, which in turn should bring the cus - Ithis finding “has caused quite a stir [among marketers]” tomer to the boardroom and thereby improve firm perfor - because “firms with a CMO on the management team are mance (e.g., Kerin 2005; McGovern et al. 2004). Moreover, not more successful than firms without a CMO.” Moreover, using an event study of CMO announcements, Boyd, Frazier (2007, p. 3) 1 urged CMOs to “hide this publication” Chandy, and Cunha (2010) find that the impact of CMOs on because they are being “rapped for having zero impact.” In firm performance is contingent on the managerial discretion short, Nath and Mahajan’s (2008; hereinafter N&M) (lack available to them. In addition, using the same sample as in of) findings have made many marketers nervous (also see their 2008 study, Nath and Mahajan (2011) report that pow - Shoebridge 2007; Simms 2008). Yet their work has raised erful CMOs have a positive impact on sales growth. an important question: Do CMOs matter? However, researchers still seem unconvinced about the There is some evidence that suggests that CMOs should CMO’s performance implications, as evidenced by their positively influence firm performance. For example, using strong calls for additional research. For example, Boyd, data from 1987–1991 (in contrast, N&M use 2000–2004 Chandy, and Cunha (2010, p. 1174) assert that “the CMO remains a rather enigmatic creature in academic literature” 1It seems that Frazier (2007) had access to the prepublication and “the scarcity of … research … is lamentable.” Simi - version of Nath and Mahajan (2008). larly, Nath and Mahajan (2011, p. 74) urge for additional research to “shed further light on the issue of CMO pres - Frank Germann is Assistant Professor of Marketing, Mendoza College of ence.” Moreover, in summarizing the findings from a recent , University of Notre Dame (e-mail: [email protected] . Peter Ebbes is Associate Professor of Marketing, HEC Paris (e-mail: e)bbes@ CMO survey, Moorman (2013) reports that demonstrating hec. fr . Rajdeep Grewal is the Townsend Family Distinguished Professor the value of marketing remains a general challenge for of Ma)rketing, Kenan-Flagler Business School, University of North Caro - CMOs. Indeed, approximately 66% of the CMOs surveyed lina at Chapel Hill (e-mail: [email protected] . The authors thank Chelsea state that they are experiencing pressure from their chief ) DeBoer, Manisha Goswami, Lauren Harville, Bernard O’Neill, and Kim - executive officer (CEO) or board to prove the value of mar - berly Sammons for their research assistance and Shrihari Sridhar and keting. Moreover, due to their nonfindings regarding Sriram Venkataraman for their helpful feedback on an earlier version of the article. In addition, they gratefully acknowledge the constructive guid - CMOs’ performance implications, N&M is still oft-cited in ance of the JM review team. Peter Ebbes acknowledges research support the media (e.g., Whitler 2013). from Investissements d’Avenir (ANR-11-IDEX-0003/LabexEcodec/ANR- Against this backdrop, we build on N&M’s work and 11-LABX-0047). Christine Moorman served as area editor for this article. seek a more comprehensive examination than what is avail - able in the literature to model the causal effect of CMO

© 2015, American Marketing Association Journal of Marketing ISSN: 0022-2429 (print), 1547-7185 (electronic) 1 Vol. 79 (May 2015), 1 –22 presence on firm performance. Specifically, using N&M’s presence as exogenous; however, CMO presence is likely research as a starting point, we extend their work in three the result of a strategic firm decision, and treating CMO important directions: presence as an exogenous regressor might result in incon - sistent estimates. We address the potentially endogeneous 1. Time horizon : N&M included five years of data in their CMO effect by (a) exploiting the panel structure of the data study. Considering that executives’ performance effects and (b) using instrumental variables (IVs). take time to manifest (e.g., Hambrick and Fukutomi 1991; Miller and Shamsie 2001), we extend N&M’s sample by Our results are promising and suggest that CMO presence seven years (i.e., for a total of 12 years [2000–2011] vs. five causally influences firm performance. As Table 1 shows, we years [2000–2004]). first replicated N&M as closely as possible using the between- 2. Industries. N&M included a wide range of industries in effects model and data similar to N&M (Study 1a); as one their data set but excluded certain others (e.g., Food and would expect, doing so yielded the familiar (non)results. Kindred Products [e.g., General Mills]; Transportation Building on N&M, in Study 1b, we estimated additional mod - Equipment [e.g., Ford Motor Co.]; Miscellaneous Manufac - turing Industries [e.g., Mattel, Inc.]). We include these addi - els other than the between-effects model; the results reveal a tional industries in our analysis. positive and significant CMO effect in IV models that cor - 3. Model . We consider several econometric extensions over rect for the endogeneity of CMO presence. We then added N&M. First, N&M employed between-effects regression additional firms/industries (Study 2) and find a positive and and, thus, did not exploit the panel structure of their data. significant CMO effect across all models except the For relatively short time series (five years for N&M), using between-effects model. Next, in Study 3, we added several a between-effects model might be appropriate; however, years to our initial sample (i.e., 2000–2011 vs. 2000–2004), because we include considerably more years in some of our and the results agai n reveal a positive and significant CMO samples, we explicitly exploit the panel structure by includ - ing time and firm effects in our analyses, which corrects for effect in all but the between-effects model. Finally, in Study common unobserved time shocks and unobserved time- 4, we added additional industries and years to our initial invariant firm-specific factors, respectively. Second, on the sample; the CMO effect was again positive and significant basis of results from a residual test, N&M treated CMO in all models but the between-effects model.

TABLE 1 Overview Study 1a Study 1b Study 2 Study 3 Study 4 Industries Cross section of Same as Study 1a Studies 1a and 1b + Same as Studies 1a Same as Study 2 sampled industries additional industries and 1b Firms sampled Firms that report Firms that report Firms that report Firms that report Firms that report both both advertising and both advertising and both advertising and both advertising and and R&D with sales R&D with sales of R&D with sales of at R&D with sales of R&D with sales of at of at least $250 at least $250 least $250 million in at least $250 least $250 million in million in 2002 million in 2002 2002 million in 2002 2002 Firm 123 firms 123 firms 155 firms 123 firms 155 firms observations Time frame 2000–2004 2000–2004 2000–2004 2000–2011 2000–2011 Firm–year 615 (Sample 1) 615 (Sample 1) 775 (Sample 2) 1258 (Sample 3) 1604 (Sample 4) observations Models used Between-effects Between-effects Between-effects Between-effects Between-effects regression OLS OLS OLS OLS Random-effects Random-effects Random-effects Random-effects Fixed-effects Fixed-effects Fixed-effects Fixed-effects OLS with lagged DV OLS with lagged DV OLS with lagged DV OLS with lagged DV 2SLSRE 2SLSRE 2SLSRE 2SLSRE Random effects with Random effects with Random effects with Random effects with control functions control functions control functions control functions HT a HT a HT a HT a BB b BB b BB b BB b CMO effect on Not significant Significant and Significant and Significant and Significant and Tobin’s q positive in some positive in all but positive in all but positive in all but models the between-effects the between-effects the between-effects model model model aHausman and Taylor (1981). bBlundell and Bond (1998, 1999). Notes: In Study 1a, we attempted to replicate N&M as closely as possible. R&D = research and development, OLS = ordinary least squares, DV = dependent variable, and 2SLSRE = two-stage least-squares random effects.

2 / Journal of Marketing, May 2015 Thus, our findings suggest that firms can indeed expect to benefit financially from having a CMO at the strategy Model Specification and table. More specifically, our data and analyses suggest that Identification firm performance (i.e., Tobin’s q) for firms with a CMO is Our primary objective is to establish the causal link approximately 15% better than that of firms without a between CMO presence or absence (simply referred to as CMO. The positive and significant effect of CMO presence “CMO presence” hereinafter) and firm performance. One is confirmed when we use excess stock returns (i.e., might think that a simple model, such as that shown in a Jensen’s ) as an alternate performance metric. Equation 1, in which one regresses firm performance on the Beyond the substantive insight that CMOs provide dummy variable indicating CMO presence, would estimate value, our article also makes methodological contributions. this effect: b b Recognizing the nature of our data (i.e., secondary data on a (1) FP it = 0 + 1CMO it + it , large number of firms over several years), we identify and describe in detail four observational data modeling where FP it indicates the firm performance of firm i in year t, approaches that could be adopted to study complex market - CMO it = 1 if firm i had a CMO during year t and 0 otherwise,  ing strategy phenomena such as the CMO’s performance and the error term it represents unexplained variation in FP it . implications: (1) rich data models, (2) unobserved effects However, this simple model suffers from serious limita - models, (3) IV models, and (4) panel internal instruments tions. For example, performance is driven by many other models. We hope that our discussion will encourage readers variables, such as advertising spending and organizational  to see themselves as regression engineers—that is, under - culture, and these other variables might also influence stand the meaning of the model identifying assumptions— CMO presence. Information on these potentially important as opposed to “regression mechanics”—that is, estimate a variables is usually not available; it does not seem to be large number of models and report the best results (Angrist available in our data, in which, for example, we observe and Pischke 2009, p. 28). advertising spending but not . Thus, In what follows, we first briefly revisit N&M. We then an omitted variable bias exists that may result in issues of discuss our modeling framework, describe our data and endogeneity involving the CMO presence variable (e.g., samples, and present our findings. We conclude with a dis - Wooldridge 2002). This omitted variable bias also emanates cussion of our findings and the limitations of our research. from the recognition that CMO presence is likely based on a (nonrandom) strategic decision of a firm to maximize its performance; that is, firms hire a CMO because they Background believe that the CMO will help improve performance. Thus, We begin by providing the relevant aspects of N&M’s study one would need information on all input variables that go and then outline how we build on their research. N&M into the strategic CMO presence decision to correct for explore two related research questions: (1) What organiza - potential biases introduced by the nonrandom nature of tional factors are associated with CMO presence in TMTs? CMO presence. However, because information on all such (2) Does CMO presence affect firm performance? They input variables is usually not available—it is not in our find that several firm factors such as the level of innovative - case—the belief that CMO presence is based on a strategic ness (i.e., research and development [R&D] to sales ratio) firm decision again induces endogeneity concerns due to and differentiation (i.e., advertising to sales ratio) are asso - omitted variables. Thus, the causal effect of CMO presence ciated with the likelihood of CMO presence in the TMT. on firm performance is not identified in the simple model They also find that CMO presence has no statistical effect shown in Equation 1. In the words of Rossi (2014, p. 16), on firm performance, neither by itself nor when analyzed we have a strong case for “first-order” endogeneity. jointly with the various firm factors (e.g., interactions Recognizing the panel nature of our data, we consider between CMO presence and innovativeness). This nonfind - four potential approaches to model observational data to ing regarding the CMO’s performance implications forms establish the causal link between CMO presence and firm per - the crux of our research. formance: (1) rich data models, (2) unobserved effects mod - Over five years (2000–2004), N&M observed 167 firms els, (3) IV models, and (4) panel internal instruments models. 2 from a cross section of industries. They included all firms from the Compustat database with sales of at least $250 2 million in 2002, the midpoint of their observation period. To conceptually identify the causal effect of CMO presence on firm performance, it is useful to think of an ideal experiment (as From this set, they retained only firms without missing data discussed in Angrist and Pischke 2009, 2010) in which one ran - on variables such as advertising and R&D as well as their domly assigns the CMO position to half the firms (treatment two dependent variables, Tobin’s q and sales growth. An group) included and then tracks both types of firms (i.e., treatment executive listed in the TMT with the term “marketing” in and control groups) for several years to assess the impact of CMO his or her title implied CMO presence. As we discuss in our presence. In such an experiment, random assignment would likely “Samples and Measures” section, we carefully followed equalize the two groups in terms of unobserved variables, and the assignment of CMO would be random and no longer strategic N&M’s data collection approach. We note that, in addition (within the bounds of randomization as noted by Leamer 1983). to Tobin’s q and sales growth, we assess the CMO’s impact a Such an experiment is, of course, not practical; thus, we need to on excess stock return (i.e., Jensen’s ) and firm systematic investigate nonexperimental solutions that can be used with obser - and idiosyncratic risk. vational data.

The Chief Marketing Officer Matters! / 3 a We discuss these models next, and we provide a summary other variables), and i = i + ui is the firm-level averaged of the models, including their identification assumptions, in error term. Table 2. The identifying assumptions of the between-estimator are similar to those of the OLS and random-effects model:  Rich Data Models data are available on all important variables, and explana - The first approach is to collect an extensive data set such tory variables are uncorrelated with the composite error term (that contains the missing variables). Although this that no conceivable control variable (or proxies of such a b variable) that correlates with both CMO presence and firm model can be used to estimate the CMO effect (i.e., 1), it is performance is omitted; we refer to these models as rich generally preferable to use the random-effects estimator— data models. Such a data set would result in the model particularly when the panel time-series dimension becomes shown in the following equation: longer—because it exploits between and within dimensions b b b of the data. To be consistent with N&M (see their Table 3), (2) FP it = 0 + 1CMO it + 2Xit + it , we estimate the between-effects model as well. where the matrix X captures the time-invariant and time- it Unobserved Effects Models variant control variables. 3 If such an extensive set of control variables were avail - Unobserved effects models control for omitted variables by able, ordinary least squares (OLS), which exploits both either using firm-specific fixed effects or a lagged depen - within and between dimensions of the data, could be used dent variable as a control variable. These models exploit the to estimate the model (Section 7.8; Wooldridge 2002). fact that panel data have multiple observations for every firm, which enables modeling firm-specific intercepts or Although we cannot claim with high confidence that no 5 important variable is missing in our data, we report OLS state dependence through a lagged dependent variable. Building on the model shown in Equation 2, the fixed- results (i.e., using Equation 2). a effects model includes the firm-specific intercept ; that is, Moreover, if one repeatedly observes the same firms i a b b over time, as we do in our panel data set, it is unrealistic to (4) FP it = i + 1CMO it + 2Xit + u it , assume that the error terms for the same firm from different a where are now fixed unknown constants and u is i.i.d. time periods are uncorrelated. Therefore, a popular alterna - i it over firms and time. tive to the model shown in Equation 2 is the random-effects a Typically, the firm-specific intercepts are not estimated; panel data model that assumes a composite error: = + a it i instead, the fixed-effects approach usually estimates the u , where is a firm-specific random error term that cap - it i model in deviations from firm-level means. Thus, the fixed- tures unobserved firm-level effects and u it is the random effects model does not require the assumption that CMO it is component that varies across firms and over time. Random a a uncorrelated with i. However, it does require the assumption effects i are assumed to be i.i.d. (usually a normal distribu - ¥ that E(CMO it uis ) = 0 for all s, t (and similarly for X it ) so tion) and capture all correlation of the error terms over that the regressors are strictly exogenous. Thus, the identi - time. Due to the random nature of firm-specific intercepts, fying assumptions underlying the fixed-effects model are the random-effects model exploits within and between vari - that (1) the omitted variable(s) is (are) time invariant (i.e., 4 ance more efficiently than OLS. the firm-specific intercept captures the omitted variable[s]) An alternative to the random-effects model is to only and (2) there is enough variance in the dependent variable exploit differences between firms, thereby ignoring the time- as well as the focal endogenous variable within firms to series information. Such a model, referred to as the between- allow estimation of its effect (i.e., the focal endogenous estimator model (e.g., Verbeek 2012, p. 382), requires variable— in our case, CMO presence—is identified only obtaining OLS estimates with firm-level means; that is, through within-firm variation). We note that after including b b b firm fixed effects, all time-invariant between-firm variation (3) FP i = 0 + 1CMO i + 2Xi + i, is removed. Typically, when the time dimension is short where FP i denotes the average financial performance for (e.g., as in Zhang and Liu 2012, in which they have seven firm i across the years of observation (and similarly for the daily observations for all units of analysis), the identifying  assumptions of a fixed-effects model are easy to justify. ¥ 3Here, it is necessary to assume that E(CMO ) = 0 and However, in our case, the sample period ranges from 5 to ¥ it it E(X it it ) = 0; (i.e., CMO it and X it are exogenous) and some other 12 years; thus, the identifying assumptions for the fixed- mild regularity conditions (e.g., Verbeek 2012, p. 373). In other effects model might not be easily defensible. Yet we believe words, we would need to assume that the set of control variables it is worth exploring this model’s results as one set of captures all unobserved variation that would otherwise be part of  results among others. We note that we also include time the error term correlating with CMO. All remaining unobserved fixed effects in the model to tease out any unique year-to- variation in the error term it only correlates with the DV (i.e., firm performance FP it ) but not systematically with CMO it or X it . 4As is common, we use feasible generalized least squares to 5In theory, one can specify a model with both firm-specific estimate the random-effects model, where it is typically required time-invariant effects and a lagged DV, as we do subsequently in ¥ ¥ that E(CMO u ) = 0 and E(X u ) = 0 for all s, t (i.e., strict Equation 7. However, estimating such a model requires strong it is ¥a it is ¥a exogeneity), and E( CMO i i) = 0 and E( Xi i) = 0 (e.g., Ver - assumptions (e.g., Nickell 1981), as we discuss in the “Panel Inter - beek 2012, p. 384). nal Instruments Models” section.

4 / Journal of Marketing, May 2015 l , - r t r l a e ) r s e t s s t e a s . l a e . c a s r o e h i a -

s e l ( t g a s s r s . h h n l , t o m

a . r s t t d p b i e r n h e s u t e s c e b

l

y t t l r t e u o ; a

s o c

e e o m s

e i e a m

s b h b l r - r b e l s o i r f r

o n t e d n

e e f e r c r m u e e a b e e t r a

b i n e i r a

r d s i e o e h r e s

h t e r a h r

a h o r p i a t v p t

t a i e e t i m g s

h v v o

o t

y a

t r t i r r n a l t r f

l

e

t l o o

a y e l

t t d v m ( d p d a o u v a

r

a O

h

t a r l x

c e b h o h d o n n d v l l i

o v r t n s

y r d T p m

, e m i r

r M g

n t t d a l a a

o l

i t e r i

a d r r W e

s a l

. h

i u r i

a n i n t o

, C s f o s ) t e e e e

o c t s c . e r

s

b r e r i i O o t a r /

l

t n e 4 n f n t

s r r y e s h O c a a u d e e e b

c n o y 8 o o e n t

m M e t i c r r b t

l l

h n h a A t e d n i c o

l 3 g s o M o i i p t

n a a

C

e r b n

a T r c

e

n e e c a o ) .

i e d a

e

g C r s l r

o a

g . s a h e a n x s )

i f t p n f c d r e t u

h u b n e

r

n v

l l i n c n s e e u t n i f o a e , i f a o

s

a f a

y a d o f b n o t

t u i i g o e y l w i h y e t 2 i n

s c r e v t t

i f t e r a a c n n o d o n e e l

e

i 1 i

d I u w e l

l a t h a d p a t r e e

t n d l e s t r e 0 o m e f w . o b v o o a

v

e l t f a d t r n e e n

e g l r o r t m 2 -

e l e , u t r h t n m v

e o n e e b g e o o n y u a r e

f

n o

i c l

l q n r k n e u S e b r i m x o d r s t o d i n a s

I r t e e s e e o e o e L m t p x e s e r m

n c i r e e

k n n s c n ( h c

d t e

r t i e e p a w r o t l e

o

O n

l t e

o o

t ( a o e

a i b

i

o i i d c e p

a h e d d r

r r t t e

c i e

t g a c m w r e ) v m s

g r e e

m t a e r o a l a r s h d m b r n i n a

l l i f e i o t e i

n e d d n M f o e

a

e f r V

e

i e u

e e e

: s s

t s h u u e b

r n y r y r d t a g t l

l e e m

s m d u r r r n r e n ( v

e r r e a o a r r g c c i

o , h h r n a a o a o o e o e o h h i h o e s a n n s T i l i N T c v c t v f i t t G t t c a c t t s m a i s y e r e l e d l r d l l a O b a s a e b u i v i

a t M i a V o o x d s i r I n

r

c

h C o e e a s e

l r e a s t o t t d v m

d b p v

o n a r e n l

s m i

n a i t r f p h i t e e o t e t -

a r l r n o ( l u

n t l

n a

b m e t i s b e s n a v

e a e d n

h e c

i ) e r o l t r l t l r n i e g i n c a b a n b a

s e

n t a u w i a v

a a s i g e p r n i i t q

r r m l r r e n e u e r l i n e a p t o a a d

y o b e r v

p R m i v v f r t

e

a l r e a s c u r l i l n a n i i a r r e c h f

a o v t a t n o f

r r

a - p T s c a t t .

u a o .

v e

o e t i . n

n a

e s i d D c y t m

a

d c d o h m g t r e n e i t i a i d o e r c t n e n

f i

k e i

t b

c n

d i a t h i u s h

y i i h w w d e t . f r r h c t c q e r i i i e e x n e u r m a a u e o c r v F v e a n b F f p w s o R e p t - i r . d . 2 n y - b S

n e e i l i a

t n t r v v u l h i m t E r

t n a t r o e l i e h d i

e L t e f d a a h i i n w

d

s s t t

n

B c e a e e w e b i o l

n e s f o

r h t i f h o t A t b i t s a t h

e a i

M i n e t

T

c t

a o y r

f

h i l l e t e f e u e r a a o g

. l p d d t

s o o v a . s n m x a - b e

n i

t a i n t t v n i t e t s e i a

i l e e d

o y i a

a - o i s

r t r l e o r b p p f i d l e i e s o e

a

p h a e a o r ; p p i t n v w

v x t e m r

d c

x

n e i e f

o n e p t m t h r a n

d e

t i

o

o e o

e n v

i

m

s i n d i e

f e t m h s c e s r s r t e a r y n d o m i p

u

d u r

e

u n a i f e a c o t

s h t n r s

o n g e r o S t t n s p f e

s n e c n e a l

i , a e a m r . e

n p s o i e m b g e i c n d e r v a c o e e d i i

i a n t c s i w a n v f t

i i f t t l d s i

r a n D n t

e a a t n c e p c t

m a d a e c e p a e i e

x b e n v e o r e

h e h e s

m e e f p t c e t h

i a f

e

d

t

d h s w s f s

v

d t e n t h - s s t e

t

e s o d t f a e

a e r

t a n c

m o

i n m i s o b g p r r g h f e r s t

i

a a i t i i f c d e t m a

f

e a n d

l c r o -

e a o

s

l e l o n a d e w t

n i d d

t e e p a s c e p

w m s r e e i t

x o e r i f s i s t t m o a n e i d f t a n - e b

i

u n c r e u a e w d e l h e s m k t d d e e t e p e r c m i s c h i r i e t v n n p m e i n i T d b s F w u A o t a A a r T s s r

t t s o c c t t t r

e r r r r e

c n a f f o f e o o o o f d e e l t t t t t f m e e e f i d b a a a a a - - t g e n a n s i - m m m m m g m r e i i i i i e e d t t t t t a o

a p e s s s s e s L d v e S x e e e e w n i E t d L a F e O R B s l e d d e

o v e a r t m p

e a s y l s s d t T

e b

c l h d o e c e o f n i f d U e R m

o . . 2 M 1

The Chief Marketing Officer Matters! / 5 t , . y s d e t f d t a e - i s

d n e n h t t s . a e h n e d t u e t s a t r

e s l n e r s a 7 n

a t g n i o t s c g t

u y u n

c l e j s e e f a s n a

n - s m c t n n

i o i r e t m e U e s (

t u c a o u r n

o e

d o e u i n m a d g i . t h m i f

o r t n n o r n h

t f e t t n r n h e o b u t d s

e d t e a i t d

r t e i n o . l l c n r s f r e p o

s u g i e e t e

b i e M o

o b t - u d

e d l t o n e

t e n

t f i o i s i g l t e c I a d m e u

d

m e i g e W i

i c p n

o w l

s

b d n f i i g r h r . t y u h t

b n e n i . f h o i e

t r l i

o t a u

m n a e ) a l t

i s s e m l x a o

o d l u h T d f s i r i i n s v g e o 2 t e

s

a s e

h c f t t h

u n l n q

a . t i o d k

i a e t c 0 y h f e e r x u a

l

e t l a

b v s

t e e o t f l l r

d e e 0

o

h c s o e r s

c t b a s e s d i s

o a t

i p i a 2

e d e r h l s g t

e

f n r ( n a t e o g n u n i , e n i e e

A a n o

s a s g e t n a h m

o s h s r t

r

n r

i a o c t e e i o h s i i n v d e s t

i l c

s u c t f o i a n a o g t s

a g t r s n

i

f

i i

a n

y u e b s d e v s d

a l j c d h s n u g u o e d l o

e l i i

t d i n

i l e a t a c e ; c

s

r e c l i i c h p i e t e a g s t l a a n c

o e t t y

i f t r o s r

d r n i a i i e

r m

e l f c u r t m b

h x t a s e t , r t

i o i a e p c o t r d

t o t t r s i i r t o p n r a m

e a n

o n a h v i

i t t l n i

n e f o

e t r u i

n u o i n e r u

n d t

e e t

y p

e p l e c n o t d

o e r s o s e a r p s e o r W d

O h r o e

m n o I

o n r p t t m a u v a n m g e o f o

i d

o d m a

u m a . d n a I o M s o r e

o e e u t o e e g r n e o

)

( u

o

w r v n c t

n . s s

s r g r n d

u d C h i o

r e n n 4 f a d m e t e m s i l t e

e s e s . i t l d

o

e n e

t ] c

o o r s

e t g s e t n a c i s 8 e t a i a d l e c i i d d d e a

d l n e t s a i

o s n l

r e a 1

r e b a e b i

f l n e n

c

r a e b a d d i s e

M a ) i i i e i t m e e o p n a e e e i g e v r n r g c a r

m e u b d e v u s h r o r i r

n t h i t i

m l e t p g p r

e t s r g r e t l o s u

a l o s q i

e

e p y

f e a a e e n s r f s

t a a o p a v e d a i e e e e l t h v n n

L v [ d h i c s o S e I v r p m r r i t o a h e c e e y t g c

r n n d n o n

o i o e - r g t e e c g d p a

m n o h i

o w t n a u n

y n

d w t i s a

r e l

, n d a s m l a p p d n e e h a o

v x t o e s

e l o r c -

i

r r s f e y t n a t

e t i s i

u i e g , a l b t n c t h

d

e n s d i n t ) n t m i u d o d h

u i e e t e s t s t s o a r c e i t

h ( i

(

, t r a t n

m o

n i h r e V ; u e e I h s p e I c

a t s s

e e

. . b t r l

e t a m

i a l a v h b o e e

o

n o c l o n b u d r o r d

n s s e i

s b r

i a a

a o p o

q i

i t s / )

c u c i r i p e s , e d

u

d f m r o e . f a a

s

h n n b

R e s V g e s v

o

n c I .

t a n

a h I ) a

l

t

a p

a e t n e o

. c

r i t n b o , ( o ) e t

t n V r

r o r I e a o t c 2 l m n a

s p m i . u n m 0 n b u D r e p n

e e u d t u o l 0 r o a h y f a a c l

o t t l x i e

2 b c l

l v t s

n n

f a e d a i a a o i n n e n

i o

a v t i t r i w e i r

t e g

l e l a g i n a . e s e r

a n d ) e c a h e i n i e e t n o F t r i v D o r 9 l f n r f c o r d 0 u

a l e r p e

0

t d e o e 2 2 e s - s , n l n h e o r i

e i r

t ) ) -

a

b d

o h n e l o e

i t s u

1 W t g E a E t e t a a e

i h d b p d t 9 E ,

m f o r t n x c

R a n . L r ,

e a i i e m e a 9 c a o o f e R n a g S y t o n d

d l

w h f . v m s B d 1 e l r

p i L f t a

a

S o s

n r o e

e r n n t t

u i

f a i g

c ( e S s i A

t o L n d n s n e e a

t v

h e o o i y n 2

r u t c

e

T l i e o n

e R n h S i h d t d

i t ,

o

t e e C o W s e i s b d e o s r 2 n

e s n a

t w w e s b r s . h c

n t n n t u o

t i

v t B , a )

l n e o e

n l e e a o n e

r

c e e d i

s 4 s s p e y e l a p i t d t p . s

s

e g h d e c i e s

s

i t u b l c

x n e f 8 a o t w a i s o n m

V

n f l n o c

t o s e i e d 1 s I e i l , a r b l d s a s

e e e

e f w

t h n e d

r t f e

- ) r c h a m o e

n a n x s s l a t n t

b r ( i o i d s o m

e d e h

n e i

i n e a p

a

o t r a ; o o t b o

e

n s

e s 1 i

l d u f )

d e e a n t e u n c n . r

t

e t e a x r m b o

r

s y n l t c e s i r o 8

t t t l m e ( n m a h f p a i e o e a a c n u t

i 1 e t

t V u w a f e o e

p

d

V I f e r s e t l s r a r

s

f I

n b m h i s e s n f f m a i a a

n a c e i t

i r a

e

e o m A r ( e

r c o c e

i

w h e y e s r b

i h h a

o g

f h , t t l r s t

t r t o l s a t .

u h i g i e s e

v m n e o e l

t c a e s d

i / a e e n d g p f l . h n

o n i i c a w D b i m . t u s i d n d t e

u d

o b a o d . r - m t n l m i t o e e

t e t c s n t a n n s

d a s r ( n i

a e r e n

o e a t g i r o n a e s a f

r

i e n r , r

h

e u r n c g s v n g t o a , s t n d e o i

m

o i s l a p

s a o

r i t u o l a y e e t . t i o

h l i o f t t s l t h n u r r , e v t i n s

t o a s t p

l p m

n

i c

h i o t a u a a 2 m r i p

l e e n

o x b f a i

a s i n

i d T a m 0 n h

n s o r g r w a t

o a i s s e i e p a o t

u f . e t i

d t 0 t s i

l

a a t g

o r a s

n t m l n . o i f h n h 2 e s l a i p u g n e d a d n a w t

t

s y

t

u o o o v n g u l e s

i e i n v

o n n d n o s e s t r i t s o

e

n

t i

e n

s e

t t l s n i a

a c m g a d t n d i m y s e b

i t i a o s s d c

d g

n

b n t r

e d n p t , n e ,

s u i a d h o n i e e

e o , o c s o

d s a e l h r r e i a a

t

a i r . , c h l t e c s

m e c t d t

e ) d c e r e r i p p s , a e e l

r

e f r f m s z e a s h r r s i f a n s i . e x f s u a o s n o ( i o e o V n d o

I a s u v R d t e d u e t i ( c T B e e n T n a o e

r l l s , o c i r e p b e

t W r e x

h ) d a g a p , t - i

v ) u e .

t t r n

n E

m s i e m g d ) s s d ) a S m o . e o a s u R n v w 1 a d a n o 9 f L i r e h

B r r s e d r u t ( s o 8 e S e e a

f h 9 o

o t s d S l l

o o

n f

h r z t m

e 9 L d t t 9 d

a e i n g 2

o n a d ; t l

o b a e ( e 1

n a a e 1 t S r n d

e t i i

d ( a i

o g a

l s g g a

, e 2 n t r a s e m m m n

p s h r ( i m m m a i i i a l i g m o n l 8 t e

l e t t t i t p t e o o y o o m t g s a r p l 9 e f

s i i r n s s s s e a i c s t t a n -

p t u -

a y o u 9 l i a e e m e d t t c s m

s E e a n o a o u a .

1 u g

n n m e a e b e ( i T a e m q

r f

e w H w q

u t f d t l u o s a i e n b e s T a t V r t

e

d f I l a , B h d a

l e

t i

c s

t d e d d

,

h n

t s s t s e t i s i

o r n t r i v n y i t o w e a a r t a

a l p

t d e i e a i e r r r n a m t d v c o

c a

m n

i t e n p s r c t S t E

n e e s s L e i e n m e l R y e t r i d t e b

S i e

e l S p

e n l m i 2 e e s L d d p

V y

l a l m u I l n h

x d r

o S T u e u t r e e

n T e s 2 r l o

s d a g

t m n o : u , h

n e d o o s ) s i a o s a

i n d d V

1 e n t r / P m i I t e a n s a

o a t 0 o h . . E A d s t ( v 4 M a b N 3

6 / Journal of Marketing, May 2015 l a i r t s 0 2 2 1 2 1 6 u 0 0 0 0 1 0 1 ...... d

1

n

I

d

r

a 0 5 4 3 9 3 7 d 5 n 0 2 0 0 3 7 1 1 ......

a

t

1

1 1 2 1

S

t

i

g

i

0 5 6 6 4 9 6 d 4 - 0 0 1 7 1 3 5 1 1 ...... o

1

3 8 2

w

t

7 –

e

h

t

0 8 5 2 1 2 2 6 1 3 t 0 3 0 1 0 0 2 4 8 a 1 ......

1

– 2 – s

e

u

l

a

v 0 4 3 7 5 7 6 6 7 4 2

0 1 1 1 2 0 0 1 7 1 n 1 ......

a

i

1

– –

2

d

e

m

0 2 7 2 3 3 9 0 5 0 0 1 e 0 0 0 0 0 0 2 0 4 0 0 h 1 ...... t

1 –

1

s

)

s

4 e

l

e s 0 5 4 7 0 8 6 1 3 4 8 1 l 0 e 0 0 1 1 0 1 3 1 9 5 1 6 1 p ...... u

l

1 – – – – – 2 1 1 6 1 a

m

– v

a

w

s S

a

0 7 1 0 1 5 7 2 4 r n 8 1 3 6

9 n 0 0 0 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 8 5 0 o

e ...... i

o 5 3 4 3 t

h

1 – – – – – –

t

4 a

l

d

e

r

e

e

r

a

s

r

0 1 8 1 8 1 1 6 5 9 0 5 0 0 ) a o 8 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 2 0 4 0 0

......

. . . .

C

B

1

1 (

t

(

s

q

c

0 2 3 0 3 6 3 0 4 0 1 i

s t ’

0 1 0 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 7 0 2 3 0 7

...... n

s

9 i

1

– –

– 6 0 5 1 i 3

4 b t

8

6

8

o

a

E T

t

L

d S

n B 0 4 8 0 5 7 3 7 2 7 2 9 0 0 0 0

a 6

e 0 0 0 0 2 0 0 0 1 0 1 4 0 5 0 0

A ...... ,

v

i

1 – – – –

– –

1 T h

t t

w

p

i

o

r r

g 0 3 8 3 6 7 2 0 3 3 6 7 3 0 0 0 0

c

5 0 1 1 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 4 0 5 0 0 s

s ......

e

e l

1 –

– – –

1

a

D

s

,

d

s

t 0 6 4 5 6 2 8 6 0 4 5 0 4 2 0 4 6 4

n

e 4 0 1 0 1 1 0 0 0 1 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 2 0

s a ......

s

1

– –

– –

a s

n

n

o

o

i

0 4 9 4 2 2 7 0 6 5 6 0 4 3 3

1 0 5 9 n t

r 3 0 2 0 1 0 0 1 2 0 4 0 1

1 1 0 0 1 6 3

a ......

...... u

l

t

1

– –

– –

e

e

r

r

,

r

n

o

o

0 6 8 3 7 2 5 5 2 i 4 5 4 0 1 6 0 0 8 1

t C 2

0 1 0 0 1 1 0 0 0 0 2 3 5 0 0 5 1 4 9 0

a

...... i

t

1

– –

1 2 2

n

1 –

e

r

e

f

f

i 0 4 6 2 6 1 2 3 6 4 3 4 3 3 5 6 0 8 0 0 1

1

d 0 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 3 0 4 0 0

......

,

1

1 n

o

i

t

a

v

o

n

n

)

i

s

,

e .

q

l

e

e s

’ y

v

n

o e

i n

l l

b

o

p ) g

i

o n

t

C n

T

m o I i

a

i s

, k r

t e t s d S

t

)

(

s

a e c f k M e n i

e

n

1 i

r

c s

s

c o t n a c & n

i

i O e

r

f s h

r

o – n s n i r c o

t c i N

i i i E

b e

t a

e t s t t e e t

r

n c

w ( r a

g i s C

n s a a b a

e t u n o

c

i o n e r

t t i e

o i t e r q q

r c

f a n o i

r v c i r m

a

t

i S n e w

g

t e r s

p

n p s s u

m t a n

d ’ ’ e o

d

s

e o

l

r i y

y r n s

l v e s l

n n a k r

( t s p s i i

l O u O e o e

o O r e t a

r t l f s a

g l o b t b

f F C

n i a u

M i o E O e a y

o o o o b n x

:

n d m

n

C I D C C O M L C R S S I T T T s a d a i D

i e

...... m r t

M M S M M

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 u o a

1

1 1 1 1 1 1

V N S

The Chief Marketing Officer Matters! / 7 year fluctuations (e.g., boom and bust cycles that uniformly (2009, p. 117) argue that finding IVs requires “a combina - influence all firms in our sample). 6 tion of institutional knowledge and ideas about processes Moreover, if one believes that current firm performance determining the variable of interest.” Likewise, Rossi is influenced by the past (e.g., past firm decisions, carry - (2014) notes that good IVs need to be justified using institu - over effects), the introduction of a lagged dependent tional knowledge because there is no true test for the quality variable might control for otherwise omitted variables and of IVs (for a discussion on statistical tests to examine the effects. Specifically, time-varying unobserved effects (as quality of instruments, see Rossi 2014). 7 opposed to time-invariant unobserved effects, as in the We use CMO prevalence among the sample firms’ peers fixed-effects model) can be captured by including the as our primary IV. We define peer firms as those sample lagged dependent variable (in our case, firm performance) firms that operate in the same primary two-digit Standard as an additional control variable in the model. We can rep - Industrial Classification (SIC) code(s) as the focal firm and resent such a model as follows: meet other criteria (e.g., sales greater than $250 million in b b b r 8 (5) FP it = 0 + 1CMO it + 2Xit + FP it –1+ it , 2002) for inclusion in our sample. Specifically, for each j = 1, …, J SIC code (where J = 44 in our sample), if there are where FP it – 1 is the firm performance of the previous time i = 1, 2, …, N j firms in the code, the peer influence variable period and is included in the set of control variables.  for firm i (considering that the firm only belongs to one pri - Including a lagged dependent variable as a control mary SIC code j) would be the number of firms with a variable in the model typically reduces the autocorrelation CMO in code j other than firm i divided by N j – 1. More - in the model (but does not necessarily eliminate it). Consid - over, if a firm belongs to multiple primary two-digit SIC ering the model shown in Equation 5, the identifying codes, we calculate a weighted average of CMO prevalence assumption for the CMO presence effect is that (1) the using the number of sample firms in each primary SIC code omitted variables are fully accounted for by the lagged as the weight to calculate the IV. Most firms are listed in dependent variable and (2) there is no serial correlation pre - multiple primary two-digit SIC codes, and these codes tend sent in the error term it . If these identifying assumptions to change over time within a firm; therefore, the value of are met, the model would correct for firm-specific, time- the peer CMO prevalence IV generally differs across firms varying omitted variables. Such a model exploits both and over time. within- and between-firm variance and can be estimated To verify that CMO prevalence among peer firms is a with OLS, as we do subsequently. good IV, we need to, on the one hand, demonstrate instru - IV Models ment relevance (i.e., that the IV predicts CMO presence) and, on the other hand, argue that the IV meets the exclu - If we cannot claim on theoretical grounds that the CMO sion restriction (i.e., establish that the IV does not correlate effect is uncorrelated with the error term it in Equation 2 with the error term that contains the omitted variables). In (e.g., due to omitted variables), an alternate approach is to find one or more IVs that correlate with the CMO variable terms of instrument relevance, we need to conceptually but not with the unobserved determinants of firm perfor - make the case that CMO prevalence among peer firms cor - mance (that form part of the error term); that is, we must relates with CMO presence of the focal firm. Our argument find IVs that meet the instrument relevance criterion and the exclusion restriction (e.g., Angrist and Pischke 2009). 7Two other methods are also often used that parallel the use of The exclusion restriction can be thought of as introducing IV approaches: (1) control functions and (2) matching approaches. an additional equation to Equation 2 to explain/predict Similar to IV methods, the control function approach requires that the exclusion restriction is met and uses information from the CMO presence: excluded variable to introduce a term for unobserved variables in g g g (6) CMO it = 0 + 1Zit + 2Xit + v it , the regression specification; thus, a control variable is introduced for the unobserved variables. Matching on the basis of the propen - where Z is the IV that is excluded from Equation 2. In sity score relies on creating an appropriate control group to com - itg addition 1 must be ≠ 0 and, similar to X it , Z it must be pare with the treatment group and, thus, eliminates the need for exogenous; that is, the IV must not be correlated with the instrumental variable(s). If treatment and control groups can be ¥ obtained through matching, a difference-in-difference estimator model error term in Equation 2 and E(Z it it ) = 0. can be used to obtain the causal effect of CMO presence. For a The use of a “good” IV enables one to “partition the comparison of instrumental variables, control function, and match - variation [in CMO presence] into that which can be ing procedures using propensity scores, see Heckman and regarded as clean or as though generated via experimental Navarro-Lozano (2004). methods, and that which is contaminated and could result in 8We used the Compustat Segments database to identify all pri - an endogeneity bias” (Rossi 2014, p. 655). Unfortunately, mary two-digit SIC codes to which our sample firms belonged in each sample year. We note that while all firms have one primary good IVs can be difficult to find. Thus, Angrist and Pischke two-digit SIC code assigned (referred to as principal two-digit SIC code hereinafter; see Tables WA1 and WA2 in the Web Appendix), 6 Time-invariant variables in X it are not allowed in the fixed- many firms belong to more than just one primary SIC code, and effects approach and are thus eliminated from the fixed-effects we use this information to calculate the IV. For example, in 2000, model during estimation. If interest lies in such regressors, this is a Procter & Gamble belonged to three primary two-digit SIC codes: high price to pay for choosing the fixed-effects model over, for 20 (Food and Kindred Products), 26 (Paper and Allied Products), example, the random-effects model. and 28 (Chemicals and Allied Products).

8 / Journal of Marketing, May 2015 here rests on two primary premises. First, we argue that the shocks that are common across industries; thus, we include focal firms face similar market conditions as the peer firms these effects in our model specifications. However, such because the firms operate in the same industry(ies). Second, exogenous shocks could also be specific to an industry in a we assert that the expectations of the focal firm and the peer given time period; for example, as the price of crude oil firms are similar because we limit our sample to large firms drops, the profitability of allied industries is reduced. Con - (more than $250 million in sales in 2002) that invest in both sequently, allied industries might cut their marketing spend - advertising and R&D, functions often related to the market - ing, and perhaps also the CMO position, as their focus ing department. Thus, similar market conditions and simi - shifts from managing demand to cost cutting (e.g., Graham, larity of expectations should make the instrument relevant. Harvey, and Rajgopal 2005). Therefore, we also examine a What remains to be argued is why our instrumental model specification in which we include time fixed effects variable meets the exclusion restriction—that is, why it is interacted with industry-specific fixed effects as an additional uncorrelated with the omitted variables that affect the focal analysis. In such a specification, the effect of CMO preva - firm’s financial performance. There are two types of omit - lence on firm performance is identified by cross-sectional ted variables of concern. First, there are firm-level variables variation in CMO prevalence and firm performance within such as organizational culture (as discussed previously). industries (SIC codes). Here, we argue that the peer firms collectively either cannot For our research, we use two IV approaches: First, observe or measure the focal firm’s omitted variable(s) or given the panel structure of our data, we use the two-stage cannot act on those variable(s) strategically. For example, least-squares random-effects estimator (2SLSRE). A poten - organizational processes and cultures that are difficult to tially more efficient IV estimator may be obtained by measure and quantify are embedded in an ’s appropriately for the discreteness of the CMO fabric and thus become difficult to imitate (e.g., Granovet - variable (e.g., Wooldridge 2002). Therefore, as a second IV ter 1985; Grewal and Slotegraaf 2007). Indeed, such pro - model, we implement an estimation approach that accounts cesses are often difficult for the firms themselves to imitate for the discreteness of the CMO variable. That is, we use a (e.g., for the case of Saturn, see Kochan and Rubinstein probit regression to estimate the first-stage regression 2000). Consequently, many firms have open secrets that are model in Equation 6 and then include the inverse Mills ratio a source of competitive advantage (Barney 1991). In addi - (IMR) as a control function in a second-stage random- tion, some sources of competitive advantage, such as patents, effects regression to estimate Equation 2 (see Wooldridge have legal protection and thus are difficult to imitate as well. 2002, procedure 18.4, p. 631). 10, 11 Furthermore, because most of our sample firms belong to several primary two-digit SIC codes, a large number of Panel Internal Instruments Models firms is used to calculate a focal firm’s CMO prevalence- 9 Our fourth set of models relies on the panel nature of the based instrument. Thus, it seems highly unlikely that peer data to obtain IVs (we use the term “internal instruments” firms will take collective action against a single competitor for instruments that arise from transformations of the and then also form other alliances similar in spirit to act included control variables in the main Equation 2 and against other competitors (which are also part of the other “external instruments” for instruments excluded from the alliances these firms form). We conclude that it is unlikely main Equation 2; see the “IV Models” section). Panel inter - that our instrument would relate to a focal firm’s omitted nal instruments models typically use some transformation variables (e.g., organizational culture) because (1) such of the endogenous variable (in our case, CMO presence) variables may be difficult to assess and (2) collective action and other included exogenous variables to obtain instru - is difficult to manage. Therefore, the instrument should be ments. Thus, no external instruments are required to esti - uncorrelated with the omitted variable and, thus, the error mate these models. We discuss and use the Hausman and term that contains the omitted variable, thereby meeting the Taylor (1981) and the Blundell and Bond (1998, 1999) exclusion restriction. approaches here. The second type of omitted variables of concern are exogenous shocks that may systematically influence firm 10 We include dummy variables for the primary two-digit SIC performance and CMO prevalence over time, thereby creat - codes (most firms belong to multiple primary two-digit SIC codes) ing a correlation between CMO prevalence and the error to which each focal firm belongs as control variables in the first- term (which contains the exogenous shocks). Such shocks stage regression (i.e., Equation 6) to account for SIC-based vari - could include economy-wide boom and bust cycles, in ance in CMO presence. These industry dummy variables are which the health of the economy tends to dictate organiza - exogenous because CMO presence is not the primary variable that tional marketing emphases (e.g., Srinivasan, Lilien, and determines the firms’ presence in an industry (two-digit SIC code). We note that the CMO effect remains positive and significant Sridhar 2011). Time fixed effects should be able to proxy when excluding these additional SIC-based control variables from Equation 6. 9In several instances, we only have a few sample firms forming 11 Following Wooldridge (2002, procedure 18.4, p. 631), we ¥ a peer group (i.e., primary two-digit SIC code industry). As a include CMO (pdf/cdf), where pdf/cdf is the IMR and (1 – ¥ robustness check, we dropped peer groups with fewer than seven CMO) (pdf/(1 – cdf)) in the second-stage model, where CMO = firms from our sample and repeated the IV models; our main find - 1 if the firm has a CMO and CMO = 0 otherwise. We note that this ing that the estimated CMO effect is positive and significant for approach requires normality assumptions for the model error Tobin’s q remained unchanged. terms.

The Chief Marketing Officer Matters! / 9 Hausman and Taylor (1981; hereinafter, HT) propose an 1991). However, the resulting GMM estimator has often alternative to the (firm-specific) fixed-effects model in the been found to be unreliable in empirical applications presence of endogenous variables. In particular, HT show because the lagged instruments tend to be weakly correlated that the panel structure of the data can be used to obtain IVs with subsequent first differences, especially when the without requiring the traditional exclusion restrictions. The endogenous variables (in our case, lagged firm performance HT approach is built on the same idea as the fixed-effects and CMO presence) are highly persistent (i.e., when there is model: it assumes that the omitted variable(s) is (are) time serial correlation in these variables; BB). Thus, we must invariant. Moreover, HT show that the idea can be extended rely on GMM estimators that break the persistence in the to construct mean-centered IVs that are computed from the data. Considering the various existing GMM estimators, set of regressors. The HT approach exploits both the within BB’s seems to be the most popular (for a critique, see and between dimensions of the data and allows for the Roodman 2009). In brief, the BB estimator considers Equa - inclusion of firm-specific random effects (HT; Verbeek tions 7 and 8 as a system of equations. That is, it uses the 2012). lagged differences of the dependent variable as instruments Building on the HT framework, Arellano and Bover for the equa tion in levels (i.e., Equation 7) as well as lagged (1995) and Blundell and Bond (1998, 1999; hereinafter, levels of the dependent variable as instruments for the equa - BB), among others, propose a more general IV framework tion in first differences (i.e., Equation 8; see also Arellano for panel data models based on generalized method of and Bover 1995) to control for the potential endogeneity of moments (GMM) estimation. These models are particularly the lagged dependent variable. The resulting system is usu - useful when both firm-specific intercepts and lagged depen - ally estimated with a GMM approach. The validity of the dent variables are included as control variables. In the BB (lagged) difference instruments for the levels equations depends on the assumption that changes in the dependent model, lagged measures and/or changes in lagged measures a are used as instruments for the lagged dependent variable variable are uncorrelated with i, which is the case when (in our case, firm performance) and other potentially the series is in a more or less steady state (e.g., Blundell and Bond 1999, pp. 7–8; Verbeek 2012, p. 403). endogenous variables. Considering the two unobserved heterogeneity models discussed previously (i.e., fixed- Overall Proposed Modeling Approach effects and lagged dependent variable models), an alternate specification to Equations 4 and 5 would be a model that The model specifications discussed previously rely on vary - includes both a firm-specific error term and a lagged depen - ing identifying assumptions and data requirements, as sum - dent variable; that is, marized in Table 2. Recognizing that there are many poten - b b b r a tial models available, we suggest that researchers explore (7) FP it = 0 + 1CMO it + 2Xit + FP it –1+ i + u it , the meaning of the various models’ identifying assumptions a in light of their context and then determine the appropriate where i and u it are both random terms defined as previ - specifications (as opposed to mechanically estimating many ously. potential models and then only reporting the model[s] that The estimation challenge of this model is that FP a it – 1 provide[s] the best results, thus becoming, in the words of depends on (i.e., the two are positively correlated) and i Angrist and Pischke [2009, p. 28], “regression mechanics”). FP is “endogenous” (in addition to CMO ). Moreover, it – 1 it For example, if researchers believe that they have an endo - the endogeneity of FP could bias the effect of the CMO it – 1 geneity problem of the first order and they can provide variable, 12 and even a fixed-effects estimation, which a strong theoretical arguments for a good IV, the IV approach would remove i, would not solve the problem because the should be preferred. Similarly, some assumptions may be within-transformed lagged dependent variable is correlated too strong for the specific situation a researcher faces (e.g., with the within-transformed error (Nickell 1981; Verbeek in our case, considering that we have a 12-year panel of 2012, p. 397). Thus, an alternative estimation approach is to annual firm data, it might be difficult to defend the fixed- take the first difference (which also removes the firm-spe - a effects assumption—i.e., that the cause for endogeneity of cific error term i), as shown in Equation 8: the CMO effect is time invariant), and thus such models b b (8) FP it – FP it –1= 1(CMO it – CMO it –1) + 2(X it –Xit –1) may be ruled out from a conceptual standpoint. b We also want to recognize that it is important to assess + 3(FP it –1– FP it –2) + (u it –uit –1). and discuss the robustness of the results to various identify - This model cannot be estimated using OLS because ing assumptions (e.g., using both internal and external FP it – 1 is correlated with u it – 1 . Instead, the endogeneity of instruments) and investigate the same phenomenon from the differenced lagged dependent variable can be addressed different vantage points. Indeed, it is conceivable that dif - by using lagged values of the dependent variable as IVs ferent models do not produce the same results. If that is the resulting in a GMM estimator (e.g., Arellano and Bond case, a careful conceptual justification is required for the identifying assumptions of the effect based on institutional knowledge. Thus, researchers should view themselves as 12 While the direction and magnitude of the potential bias in the CMO effect are difficult to predict beforehand, some evidence regression engineers as opposed to “regression mechanics” exists in the literature that suggests that the estimated CMO effect (Angrist and Pischke 2009, p. 28) and understand the mean - may be biased downward (i.e., we would underestimate the CMO ing of the model identifying assumptions for their context. effect; see Keele and Kelly 2006). Upon developing such an understanding, regression engi -

10 / Journal of Marketing, May 2015 neers should estimate and discuss a subset of models whose centages ranged between 39% and 44%. We note, however, identifying assumptions make the most sense given the data that although overall CMO prevalence across all firms and problem context (e.g., the models we summarize in remained fairly stable during the 12 sample years, it varied Table 2). If the findings are convergent and show robust - significantly within our respective sample firms. For exam - ness, they would strengthen belief in the conclusions ple, in Sample 4, the largest sample, 30% of the firms had drawn. However, if the findings are not convergent, careful no CMO during the entire 12 years, 7% of the firms had a analysis of the identifying assumptions is needed to assess CMO during the entire 12 years, and 63% of the firms had which results, if any, to believe or whether a different a CMO during some years but not during others. In addi - approach (e.g., a longer time series or additional control tion, considering Sample 1, our smallest and the sample variables) is necessary. closest to N&M’s sample, 41% of the firms had no CMO during the entire five years, 16% of the firms had a CMO during the entire five years, and 42% of the firms had a Samples and Measures CMO during some years and not during others. These num - In a first step, we aimed to replicate N&M’s sample as bers compare reasonably well with N&M’s, in which closely as possible. Thus, using the Compustat database and approximately 66% of the firms showed no variance in considering the five-year period 2000–2004, we identified CMO presence. We also conducted a simulation study, firms with sales of at least $250 million in 2002. From this described in detail in the Appendix, which suggests that our set, and in line with N&M, we retained only firms without data exhibit sufficient within-firm CMO variation over time missing data on the various factors (e.g., advertising, to estimate our models. R&D). Moreover, in N&M’s footnote 7, they provide a breakdown of their sample by principal two-digit SIC code. Measures We only retained firms with principal two-digit SIC codes We closely followed N&M’s data collection procedures, represented in N&M’s sample. Using N&M’s (p. 70) filters, collecting all variables, including the control variables. To and after repeated efforts, our first sample (referred to as do so, we used various secondary data sources, including Sample 1 subsequently) consisted of 123 firms for which we COMPUSTAT, company websites, firms’ 10-Ks, and proxy were able to collect complete data across the five sample statements retrieved via EDGAR, Bloomberg, and Capital years. In comparison, N&M’s sample comprises 167 firms. IQ. We included the following control variables in all our We note that N&M excluded several firms/SIC codes models: innovation, differentiation, corporate branding, for which complete data were available for 2000–2004. For total diversification, CEO tenure, outsider CEO, market example, N&M excluded firms from the Food and Kindred concentration, number of employees (log), chief operating Products industry (e.g., General Mills Inc., Hershey Co., Kel - officer (COO) presence, and return on assets. We also logg Co.), the Transportation Equipment industry (e.g., Ford included sales growth as an additional control variable in all Motor Co., General Motors Co., Oshkosh Corp.), and Miscel - models except those in which sales growth is the perfor - laneous Manufacturing Industries (e.g., Mattel Inc., Hasbro mance measure. For detailed information on the data collec - Inc., Callaway Golf Co.). Therefore, we created Sample 2, tion procedures and variables, see N&M (pp. 71–72). 14 which included these additional firms and principal two-digit SIC codes. The total number of firms included in Sample 2 is Performance Measures 155. Tables WA1 and WA2 in the Web Appendix compare The CMO is posited to have both short- and long-term perfor - our samples with N&M’s in terms of principal SIC codes. mance implications (e.g., Boyd, Chandy, and Cunha 2010). Moreover, since N&M’s study was conducted, addi - Thus, to assess whether and how CMO presence affects tional firm years have become available beyond 2004. At firm performance, we require a performance measure that is the time our research was initiated, the most recent year forward looking and cumulative. Moreover, given the cross with full secondary data available was 2011. We thus cre - section of firms (i.e., organizational heterogeneity) included in ated Samples 3 and 4 by adding as many firm years as pos - our sample, the measure also must be generalizable and com - sible to Samples 1 and 2. We note that the overall number of parable across (1) firms in many different industries and (2) firms is the same in Samples 1 and 3 (i.e., 123 firms) as firms that pursue different performance outcome goals. 13 well as Samples 2 and 4 (i.e., 155 firms). Historically, most of the academic (marketing) research investigating firm performance has employed accounting- CMO Presence

Considering Sample 4, our most complete sample, the per - 14 We excluded the two variables TMT marketing experience centage of firms with a CMO did not change significantly and TMT general management experience from our models for between 2000 and 2011: specifically, 35% of the sample two reasons. First, as in N&M’s case, biographical data were firms had a CMO in 2000, whereas 37% had one in 2011 available for only approximately 75% of the executives of the (the percentage of firms with a CMO ranged from 32% to sample firms. Second, virtually all TMT members had general 40% throughout our 12 sample years). These percentages management experience, so the variable showed no variation (i.e., it was 1 for almost all firms). We note, however, that when we are comparable to those reported by N&M: their CMO per - estimated our models including the TMT marketing experience variable (based on data for approximately 75% of the executives), 13 We list the names of the firms included in the four samples in the CMO effect remained positive and significant in all but the Tables WA3 and WA4 in the Web Appendix. between-effects model (using Sample 4).

The Chief Marketing Officer Matters! / 11 based measures such as sales growth or return on invest - Shervani, and Fahey 1998; Tuli and Bharadwaj 2009). ments (e.g., Buzzell and Gale 1987; Jacobson 1990). How - Therefore, it may be that CMO presence has risk-reducing a ever, in the words of Anderson, Fornell, and Mazvancheryl properties. Because both Tobin’s q and Jensen’s are risk- (2004, p. 174), “such measures … contain little or no infor - adjusted measures (e.g., Aksoy et al. 2008; Madden, Fehle, mation about the future value of a firm.” Indeed, accounting- and Fournier 2006; Montgomery and Wernerfelt 1988) and, based measures assume that previous investments affect in that sense, mask the effect of CMO presence on firm risk, only current-period earnings. Yet, in reality, most types of we also investigate the CMO’s direct impact on a firm’s firm investments (e.g., employing a CMO) affect future systematic and idiosyncratic risk. Systematic risk represents earnings as well (e.g., Geyskens, Gielens, and Dekimpe the degree to which a firm’s stock returns are a function of 2002). Similarly, firms in the same industry may differ in market returns and thus are undiversifiable. In contrast, their short-term objectives (e.g., one may emphasize prof - idiosyncratic risk represents risk specific to a firm that can itability and the other may stress growth), and thus, the be eliminated from an investment portfolio (e.g., Lintner goals of the CMOs should differ across firms. Moreover, 1965). Although there is an ongoing debate about the use - because of industry and firm differences in accounting prac - fulness of risk measures for predicting firm value (e.g., tices, a comparison of accounting-based measures (e.g., sales Fama and French 1992; McAlister, Srinivasan, and Kim growth, return on investment) across industries and firms is 2007), both idiosyncratic and systematic risk are important problematic (Anderson, Fornell, and Mazvancheryl 2004). aspects of shareholder value (for a detailed discussion, see Capital market–based measures overcome these chal - Tuli and Bharadwaj 2009), and we therefore include them lenges in several ways: (1) they capture both immediate and as two additional performance measures. future firm performance; (2) they are organizational goal Finally, we report the impact of CMO presence on sales agnostic, permitting performance comparison across firms growth to be consistent with N&M, who used both Tobin’s that pursue different performance goals (e.g., growth vs. q and sales growth as their performance measures. Follow - profits); and (3) they are less affected by accounting con - ing N&M, we calculate sales growth as the increase in sales ventions because they include the potential effect of as a proportion of the sales in the preceding year. However, accounting practice inconsistencies across industries when because it is an accounting- and not a capital market–based evaluating expected future revenue streams (e.g., Amit and measure, we maintain that sales growth is not a suitable Wernerfelt 1990). Thus, capital market–based measures measure for the context of this study. Table 3 presents the (rather than accounting-based measures) seem appropriate descriptive statistics. for the purpose of the study. Consistent with N&M, we employ Tobin’s q as our focal performance outcome measure. Tobin’s q, the ratio of Results a firm’s market value to the current replacement cost of its The CMO and Firm Tobin’s q assets (Tobin 1969), is a forward-looking, capital market– based measure of the value of a firm. It provides a measure Model-free evidence . We first present model-free evi - of the premium (or discount) that the market is willing to dence regarding the relationship between CMO presence pay above (below) the replacement costs of a firm’s assets, and Tobin’s q. Considering Sample 4, our largest sample, thus capturing any above-normal returns expected from a and the average Tobin’s q across all time periods (i.e., firm’s collection of assets (Amit and Wernerfelt 1990). 2000–2011), firms with a CMO in a given year, on average, Another appealing feature of Tobin’s q is that it adjusts for displayed a Tobin’s q of .75, whereas firms without a CMO expected market risk; in other words, because Tobin’s q displayed a Tobin’s q of .36. This difference is statistically combines capital market data with accounting data, it significant (t = 5.37), suggesting that firms do benefit from implicitly uses the correct risk-adjusted discount rate and having a CMO among the TMT (we note that we could thus minimizes distortion (e.g., Amit and Wernerfelt 1990; have also estimated this effect using the model shown in Montgomery and Wernerfelt 1988). Equation 1). We also plotted the average Tobin’s q values by In addition to Tobin’s q, we also consider the CMO’s year and CMO presence to capture the CMO effect in each impact on three other capital market–based performance time period. Figure 1 and Table 4 show the average Tobin’s a measures: Jensen’s , systematic risk, and idiosyncratic q values of firms with and without a CMO across the 12 a risk. Jensen’s (e.g., Aksoy et al. 2008; Jensen 1968; Lyon, years. Although the difference in Tobin’s q is not statisti - Barber, and Tsai 1999) is the intercept derived from a risk cally significant in each time period (except in 2000, 2001, model, usually the Fama–French (1993) three-factor model 2003, 2009, and 2010), Figure 1 again suggests that firms augmented with the momentum factor (Carhart 1997). indeed benefit from having a CMO at the strategy table: the a Jensen’s should be zero unless the firm has a value driver line depicting Tobin’s q of CMO firms is always above the not captured by the independent variables of the risk model line depicting Tobin’s q of non-CMO firms. Notably, the (e.g., Jacobson and Mizik 2009); in other words, it captures average Tobin’s q of both types of firms (i.e., CMO and risk-adjusted returns in excess of or below those predicted non-CMO firms) was significantly greater in 2000 than in by the risk model. subsequent years, likely the result of the Internet bubble. Conceptual and empirical evidence suggests that Model-based evidence . We begin our model-based analy - marketing-related investments serve to reduce firm risk sis by estimating a between-effects model using Sample 1 (e.g., McAlister, Srinivasan, and Kim 2007; Srivastava, (Study 1a in Table 5) to replicate N&M’s work as closely as

12 / Journal of Marketing, May 2015 FIGURE 1 Average Tobin’s q of Firms With and Without a CMO

1.8 1.6 CM O No CM O

q 1.4

s ’ n

i 1.2 b o

T 1.0

e

g .8 a r e

v .6 A .4 .2 0 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

Notes: Following N&M, the depicted Tobin’s q averages are derived from the respective firms’ raw Tobin’s q values less the median industry values of each firm’s principal two-digit SIC level.

TABLE 4 Average Tobin’s q of Firms With and Without a CMO Year 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 Tobin’s q (CMO) 1.71 1.28 .71 .86 .66 .45 .44 .39 .45 .59 .48 .41 Tobin’s q (no CMO) .9 .52 .55 .33 .28 .32 .16 .18 .25 .09 .13 .35 t-value 1.96 2.94 .87 2.14 1.61 .56 1.46 1.03 1.43 3.13 1.92 .30 possible. Like N&M, we find that the between-effects model increases from Sample 1 to Sample 4, the respective stan - indicates a nonsignificant CMO effect. Using the same sam - dard errors of the estimated CMO effect tend to decrease, ple (i.e., Sample 1), we then estimated the remaining models lending higher confidence in the estimated CMO effect. We (Study 1b in Table 5). The CMO effect remains statistically report the full model results for Sample 4, including control nonsignificant in the OLS, random-effects, fixed-effects, variables, in Table 6. For the full model results for Samples OLS with lagged dependent variable and HT models. How - 1–3, see Tables WA5–WA7 in the Web Appendix. 16 ever, we obtain a significant and positive CMO effect in the 2SLSRE, random-effects with control function, and BB The effect of outliers . Using various outlier diagnostics models. 15 (e.g., residual vs. fitted plots), we identified four firms with We then repeated our analyses using Sample 2 (Study 2 large lagged Tobin’s q values that are potential outliers. in Table 5). The CMO effect remains statistically nonsignifi - Specifically, considering 2000, Yahoo Inc., RF Micro Devices cant when using the between-effects model; however, it Inc., Tibco Software Inc., and Foundry Networks Inc. each becomes significant in all other model specifications. Sub - had lagged Tobin’s q values of greater than 15 (i.e., large sequently, we estimated our models using Sample 3 (Study Tobin’s q values in 1999, likely a result of the Internet bub - 3 in Table 5), and we obtain similar results to those obtained ble). Moreover, the company Move Inc. seems to have had an using Sample 2; that is, the CMO effect is positive and sig - unusually large sales growth value, also in 2000, which is nificant in all models except the between-effects model. likely the result of a lawsuit that year (e.g., see Move Inc.’s Finally, using Sample 4, our largest sample, we repeated our 2000 10-K report). The unusually large lagged Tobin’s q analyses and again obtain a positive and significant CMO effect in all models but the between-effects model (Study 4 16 We note that we also estimated our IV models using various in Table 5). Thus, the CMO effect is fairly robust in terms other instrument and sample configurations. Our conclusions did of sign and statistical significance across various model not change: the CMO effect remained positive and significant. For identifying assumptions. Moreover, as the sample size example, using Sample 4, (1) we only considered the sample firms’ principal SIC code (see Tables WA1 and WA2 in the Web Appendix ) to identify the firms’ respective sample peer group/calculate the 15 The instrument for CMO presence (i.e., CMO prevalence CMO prevalence IV and (2) to ensure that CMO prevalence is cal - among peer firms) emerged as a significant predictor of CMO culated using a representative sample of peer firms, we only presence in the first-stage regression across all samples. For exam - included sample firms that belong to principal SIC groups with 20 ple, considering Sample 1, CMO prevalence’s coefficient (z = or more firms in them. Considering Model 6 (2SLSRE), the CMO 5.90) and the F-test of excluded instruments/Cragg–Donald Wald effect was .76 (z = 3.14), and the F-test of excluded instruments/ F-statistic (F = 4.77, p < .0001) are both strongly significant. Cragg–Donald Wald F-statistic was 15.44 ( p < .0001).

The Chief Marketing Officer Matters! / 13 TABLE 5 Results—DV: Tobin’s q CMO Effect (SE) Studies 1a Study 3: Study 4: and 1b: Study 2: 123 Firms, 155 Firms, 123 Firms, 155 Firms, up to up to Model 5 Years, 5 Years, 12 Years, 12 Years, Model Type Number Models a n = 615 n = 775 n = 1258 n = 1604 Rich 1 OLS b .15 .27** .21*** .26*** data (.13) (.11) (.07) (.06) models 2 Between-effects c .02 .26 .15 .24 (.25) (.22) (.21) (.19) 3 Random-effects .21 .30*** .22*** .24*** (.13) (.11) (.08) (.06) Unobserved 4 Fixed-effects .17 .23* .18** .18*** heterogeneity (.15) (.13) (.08) (.07) models 5 OLS with lagged DV .08 .18* .14** .17*** (.12) (.10) (.07) (.06) IV models 6 2SLSRE .79** .81*** .75*** .77*** (.32) (.28) (.21) (.18) 7 Random-effects with control function d .83** 1.02*** .57** .55*** (.38) (.35) (.25) (.21) Panel 8 HT .21 .27** .21*** .21*** instruments (.14) (.12) (.08) (.07) models 9 BB e .96*** .60* .48*** .46** (.30) (.33) (.15) (.18) *p < .10. ** p < .05. *** p < .01. aFollowing N&M, we included the following control variables in the models: innovation, differentiation, corporate branding, total diversification, CEO tenure, outsider CEO, market concentration, number of employees (log), COO presence, return on assets, and sales growth. We also included year fixed effects in all models except the between-effects model. b We also estimated this model including industry-specific year fixed effects to ensure that industry-specific exogenous shbocks do not system - atically influence firm performance and CMO prevalence over time. The CMO effect remained positive and significant ( CMO = .22, t = 3.03; based on n = 1,604). Moreover, we also estimated the model (n = 1,604) using robust standard errors; the standard error changed from .062 to .065, and the CMO effect continued to be significant (t = 3.95 instead of t = 4.16). cModel used by N&M. We note that N&M also included the lagged DV as a control variable in their model. We excluded the lagged DV here but note that the CMO effect remains nonsignificant when including the lagged DV in the model. d We used the control function approach (e.g., Wooldridge 2002, procedure 18.4, p. 631): us¥ing a probit regression (DV = CMO presence; CMO prevalence in industry included as IV), we first calculated the IMR and then added the IMR CMO variables as well as the (1 – CMO)[(pdf/(1 – cdf)] variable to Model 3 (i.e., the random-effects model). eWe included the second and third lag of the CMO and Tobin’s q (t – 1) variables as instruments and note that the results are robust to other lag structures. In addition, the AR(2) test for autocorrelation of the residuals suggests that the differenced residuals do not exhibit significant AR(2) behavior. Notes: DV = dependent variable. observations from 1999 for the four aforementioned firms and significant in all but the between-effects model (OLS: b b may have an impact on the CMO (point) estimate of Mod - CMO = .27, t = 4.44; between-effects: CMO = .25, t = 1.35; b b els 5 (i.e., OLS with lagged dependent variable) and 9 (i.e., random-effects: CMO = .26, z = 4.02; fixed- effects: CMO = b BB) because we included the lagged Tobin’s q variable in .19, t = 2.88; 2SLSRE: CMO = .78, z = 4.30; random- effects b b these two models. Moreover, the large sales growth value with control function: CMO = .58, z = 2.79; HT: CMO = for the firm Move Inc. may affect all model results. .23, z = 3.49). We examined robustness to these potential outliers in two ways. First, we dropped the five firms with potential outliers The CMO and Other Measures of Market-Based from our sample (all years) and then reestimated Models 5 Performance a a and 9 using Sample 4. The estimated CMO effect remained Jensen’s . To assess the CMO’s impact on Jensen’s , we positive and significant in both models (OLS with lagged used the calendar–time portfolio approach and constructed b b dependent variable: CMO = .13, t = 2.79; BB: CMO = .38, a portfolio that buys (sells) stocks of our sample firms (i.e., z = 2.08), demonstrating that our estimation results in Table Sample 4) with (without) a CMO (e.g., Aksoy et al. 2008; 5 for Models 5 and 9 are robust to these potential outliers. Jacobson and Mizik 2009; Madden, Fehle, and Fournier Second, again using Sample 4, we reestimated the remain - 2006). Considering the 12 years of observed data, we rebal - ing models after removing Move Inc. (all years) from our anced this portfolio every month such that firms that had a initial sample. Again, the CMO effect remained positive CMO in month t but not in month t + 1 exited the portfolio

14 / Journal of Marketing, May 2015 * : * * * d 9 * ) ) ) ) ) ) ) ) * ) ) * ) ) ) * )

e l 2 3 0 1 5 8 2 7 8 8 8 2 0 0 3 3 1 1 9 1 0 5 8 6 9 5 2 2 d e B 1 1 6 5 7 5 3 9 5 9 7 8 0 0 3 3 0 0 1 6 2 6 6 0 8 4 6 8

u

l d B 4 2 6 6 9 5 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 5 6 0 5 5 4 4 1

...... c

o

( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( (

1 – –

n

(

I

M

*

* * * * * *

:

* * * * * * * d

8

) ) * ) ) ) ) ) * ) * ) * ) * ) * * )

)

e

l

1 8 1 4 4 8 8 3 2 3 5 0 0 0 1 2 0 4 2 2 6 2 2 5

5 2

d

T

e

3 1 2 8 4 6 1 8 8 2 8 0 0 6 5 0 0 7 6 1 9 5 1 6

1 1

u

l d H 3 2 0 4 3 5 1 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 2 0 0 0 1 0 5 1 1 1 2 0

......

c

o

( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( (

– 5

1 –

1

1

n

(

I

M

h

t

*

* * * * * *

: i l n

* * * * * * * * d

7 m )

* ) * ) ) * ) ) ) * ) * ) * ) * ) * ) * )

o o

w e

i

l

r o 3 1 5 3 1 3 4 8 4 2 6 0 0 1 9 1 0 2 7 7 0 8 3 1 2

9 t d t

e s d 0 2 1 3 5 9 3 2 8 1 8 0 0 8 3 0 0 8 6 2 1 8 2 5 1

1 c u t n

l d 1 2 9 n 5 1 3 0 1 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 8 2 1 1 5 2

n c ......

o c

o

a

( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( (

e u –

5

1 – – –

1

1

n

C f

(

I

R M

F

f

E

*

* * * *

:

* *

* * * * * * * d

E

6

) * ) * ) ) * ) ) ) * ) * ) * ) * ) * ) * )

e

l R

1 9 6 0 1 3 8 4 9 0 1 3 0 0 9 9 2 0 6 4 1 6 7 0 1 3

d

e

S 2 8 4 6 9 4 6 3 6 8 3 8 0 0 8 3 0 0 6 6 2 0 6 2 7 8

u

l d

L 1 1 0 4 2 3 0 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 7 2 1 1 7 1

......

c

o

( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( (

S

– 1 5

1 – – –

1

1

n

(

I

2

M

q

s

n

i

V

*

*

* * * * * * *

:

h

b * * * * *

* * * * d

t D

5

)

i * ) * ) * ) ) * ) ) ) * ) * ) ) * * ) ) * ) * )

e

o l

2 8 7 1 8 2 2 8 1 9 6 2 0 0 6 9 2 0 5 2 2 8 9 3 5 5 3 8 E d

d w

T e

4 3 7 2 0 6 2 5 2 5 7 6 0 0 5 1 0 0 6 6 4 6 0 0 7 3 7 5 e

S

u

l d :

(

2 1 6 3 6 7 0 0 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 3 0 2 8 1 1 0 S g

...... c

o

t V ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( L

g

– 3 4 – –

– –

2

n

I n

a M

D

O

e

L

i

c

4

e

i

f

e

f

*

*

* * * * * *

:

l

* * * * * * * *

d e

d

4 s

* ) ) * ) ) ) ) * ) * ) * ) * ) * * )

p

)

t

e

6 o d

e

l

5

1 0 4 2 6 0 8 1 0 0 0 6 2 2 0 1 4 0 3 4 7 6

t

5 c

d

e

t

e C

m

i 4 0 1 3 4 6 1 8 3 9 0 0 4 7 0 0 7 6 2 0 4 7 6

1

e

u E

x

l

d

f i a 7 2 7 5 7 8 0 0 0 0 0 0 5 0 0 0 1 0 3 2 1 1 1 0

m f ......

L

c

o

F ( ( ( ( ( ( (

( ( ( (

S

– 5

1

1

1

n E

O

B

(

I

M

r

A

o

T

f

s

t

l *

*

* * * * *

:

* * * * * * * * * d

3 m s

u

) * ) * ) ) * ) ) ) * ) * ) * ) * ) * * )

)

e t

l

o

s

2 2 4 6 5 6 3 9 2 8 9 1 0 0 7 8 2 0 7 3 1 1 4 3 4

7

d c

e

d e 7 7 3 4 9 0 0 2 7 7 3 8 0 0 8 3 0 0 6 6 6 0 1 4 6

1

u e

l

d

f n 0 1 2 4 2 3 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 7 2 2 1 2 0

R ......

f c

o

a

( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( (

1 5

1 – – –

1 1

l

n

E

(

I

R

M

e

d

o

d

M

*

*

* *

:

e

l

n

* * * * *

l 2

d s

) * ) * ) ) ) ) ) * ) ) ) * ) * ) )

e

t

u l

u

8 4 6 7 8 0 3 2 0 6 8 6 0 0 3 7 1 1 4 0 2 5 0 2 1 7

l e

c

e

c F 2 1 2 3 9 7 5 3 5 5 8 6 0 0 9 4 0 0 3 2 9 9 2 8 4 8

e

w

d

f n 1 2 4 9 4 8 0 1 1 1 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 2 6 7 1 6 2 1

t

I f ......

o

e ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( (

t – 6 6

1 – –

4 3

E

(

M

B o

N

*

*

* * * * * *

:

* * * * * * * * * d

1

* ) * ) * ) ) * ) ) ) * ) * ) ) * ) * ) * )

e

l

5 8 6 1 8 4 2 3 5 3 1 7 0 0 7 1 2 0 0 6 8 6 9 7 9 2

S

d

e

7 4 7 4 8 0 1 6 8 6 9 6 0 0 5 2 0 0 6 6 5 1 6 3 5 6

L

u

l

d

2 1 3 3 8 0 8 0 2 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 7 2 5 1 2 0

......

O c

o

( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( ( (

– 4 5

– –

2 1

n

I

M

)

.

s e

l

t

b

e

a

s

i

r

s

s a

a

v

e

l

t

n

n

b n

o

o

e

a g

i

i

t

d

n

n

e

r

i

r

a

s n

c

t a r

d

u

e

t

n t c

V

n e

e p

n

a e e

c

n

e a c t

n f

r

O e

r f

h

(

d n

o

n

o m n

c t

i

i E

b e e

r

t

e

t e

e

r n

y =

w

o

t

C s n

a s

a

e i

d u o f

d .

i t

o l

t

c r e e o . V t e

r i

c r 1 i

e n

i n r n

. r

a f

z

t 5 e n

e

b

0 D i x

g i t

e

r e 0 p a

.

i p

0

t

a p e t

d s

: a

f s

. e

o

1 i

p

t

r

r s

v

.

s s i <

r

k

r

p s f O e

O

e < e e

o e r O

t n r

l o

f m

t a <

p i o

f

v

d

n a r

u o i o i E O M p *

r r a

o i

e

p * *

n n

N I * * * C I D C D O M F C C P P S C Y

The Chief Marketing Officer Matters! / 15 at the beginning of month t + 1 and firms that did not have a book ratio portfolio in month t , and MOM t is the momen - CMO in month t but then hired a CMO in month t + 1 entered tum factor in month t. µ a the portfolio at the beginning of month t + 1. We rebalanced The intercept p (i.e., Jensen’s ) of the model provides an estimate of excess returns. Under the null hypothesis of monthly (as opposed to, e.g., yearly) because of differences µ in fiscal year ends of our sample firms (e.g., some firms’ no excess returns, p will not be significantly different fiscal year ended in December, others in March). As before, from zero (e.g., Jacobson and Mizik 2009; Jensen 1968). Consistent with our previous findings, the intercept of the we used the firms’ 10-Ks and proxy statements to identify a CMO presence. Using value-weighted and continuous model is positive and significant ( = .004, t = 2.61), pro - monthly returns (e.g., Jacobson and Mizik 2009), we esti - viding strong corroborating evidence that firms benefit mated the following Fama–French (1993) three-factor model from having a CMO at the strategy table. augmented with the momentum factor (Carhart 1997) using Systematic and idiosyncratic risk . We obtained the sys - stock-market data obtained from the Center for Research in tematic and idiosyncratic risk measures by estimating the Security Prices and Kenneth French’s data library: Fama–French model (see Equation 9) separately for each µ b g d firm–year combination using daily stock-market data, (9) (R pt –Rft ) = p + p(R mt –Rft ) + p(SMB) t + p(HML) t which we again obtained from the Center for Research in q + p(MOM) t + pt , Security Prices and Kenneth French’s data library (e.g., Tuli and Bharadwaj 2009). We then used the two risk measures where R pt is the rate of return of our portfolio of CMO as the respective dependent variables in our nine models firms in month t, R ft is the monthly risk-free return in and report the results in Table 7. As with the previous analy -  month t, R mt is the monthly return on a value-weighted ses, we used Sample 4 for this analysis. market portfolio in month t, SMB t is the Fama–French size As the results indicate, CMO presence does not seem to portfolio in month t, HML t is the Fama–French market-to- have an impact on systematic risk of the firm across all

TABLE 7 Results—Other DVs; Based on Sample 4 CMO Effect (SE) DV: DV: DV: Model DV: Systematic Idiosyncratic Sales Model Type Number Models a Tobin’s q Risk Risk Growth Rich 1 OLS .26** .01 .001 –.00 data (.06) (.02) (.001) (.01) models 2 Between-effects b .24 .00 .0002 –.01 (.19) (.06) (.0002) (.02) 3 Random-effects .24** .02 .001 .00 (.06) (.02) (.001) (.01) Unobserved 4 Fixed-effects .18** .02 .0004 .02 heterogeneity (.07) (.02) (.001) (.01) models 5 OLS with lagged DV .17** .01 .0003 –.01 (.06) (.02) (.0004) (.01) IV models 6 2SLSRE .77** .01 .003* –.01 (.18) (.06) (.0016) (.03) 7 Random-effects with control function c .55** –.03 .002 .002 (.21) (.07) (.04) (.04) Panel 8 HT .21** .02 .001 .00 instruments (.07) (.04) (.001) (.01) models 9 BB d .46* .06 .0003 –.03 (.18) (.06) (.001) (.03) *p < .05. ** p < .01. aFollowing N&M, we included the following control variables in the models: innovation, differentiation, corporate branding, total diversification, CEO tenure, outsider CEO, market concentration, number of employees (log), COO presence, return on assets, and sales growth (except for the model in which DV is sales growth), and Tobin’s q (except for the model in which DV is Tobin’s q). We also included year fixed effects in all models except the between-effects model. bModel used by N&M. We note that N&M also included the lagged DV as a control variable in their model. We excluded the lagged DV here but note that the CMO effect remains nonsignificant when including the lagged DV in the model. c We used the control function approach (e.g., Wooldridge 2002, procedure 18.4, p. 631): us¥ing a probit regression (DV = CMO presence; CMO prevalence in industry included as IV), we first calculated the IMR and then added the IMR CMO variables as well as the (1 – CMO)[(pdf/(1 – cdf)] variable to Model 3 (i.e., the random-effects model). dWe included the second and third lag of the CMO and financial performance (t – 1) variables as instruments and note that the results are robust to other lag structures. In addition, the AR(2) test for autocorrelation of the residuals suggests that the differenced residuals do not exhibit significant AR(2) behavior. Notes: DV = dependent variable.

16 / Journal of Marketing, May 2015 models. In contrast, the result from the 2SLSRE model smaller, and (3) firms whose CEO has relatively shorter (Model 6) suggests that CMO presence has a positive tenure. We present the results in Table 8. impact on idiosyncratic risk of the firm. Notably, however, ¥ CMO sales growth . The positive and significant inter - none of the other models reveals a significant positive or action between CMO presence and sales growth seems con - negative CMO effect on idiosyncratic risk. Thus, we are sistent with extant strategy and marketing literature. For faced with a situation in which we do not obtain convergent example, Day and Wensley (1988) propose that firms real - findings across models that are based on various identifying ize greater benefit from generating and acting on customer- assumptions, as discussed previously. Instead of disregard - oriented information in high-growth scenarios (also see ing the nonsignificant (or significant) results, we must now Slater and Narver 1994). Considering that the CMO has carefully assess the identifying assumptions of the various long been viewed as the most direct steward of a firm’s cus - models used and decide which result(s), if any, to believe. tomers (e.g., Boyd, Chandy, and Cunha 2010) as well as the Previously, we argued that the CMO presence variable is voice of the customer in the C-suite (e.g., McGovern et al. likely endogenous, and we believe that we have made a 2004), it can be expected that the CMO’s performance strong case for our IV. Moreover, the Hausman test suggests impact is elevated in higher sales-growth firms. that the 2SLSRE model is preferred over the rich data mod - ¥ els, supporting the notion that CMO presence is endoge - CMO number of employees . We find that the positive nous. Thus, an IV model is likely to have the most reason - effect of CMO presence declines as the number of employ - able identifying assumptions, and we therefore consider the ees increases. Literature suggests that as the number of finding obtained from the 2SLSRE model noteworthy. employees increases, the size of the TMT also increases However, because the CMO effect is (positive but) not sig - (e.g., Haleblian and Finkelstein 1993). Moreover, the larger nificant in the random-effects with control function model, the TMT, the less power each individual TMT member our other IV model, we cannot conclude with high certainty tends to have (e.g., Finkelstein, Hambrick, and Canella that CMO presence indeed has a positive effect on idiosyn - 2009). Thus, as the number of employees increases, the cratic risk, a point we further address in the “Discussion” CMO’s influence on organizational strategic direction section. might decrease, providing support for the observed negative interaction effect. The CMO and Firm Sales Growth ¥ CMO CEO tenure . We find that the positive effect of To be consistent with N&M, we also assessed the CMO’s CMO presence also decreases as the tenure of the CEO impact on sales growth. We again use Sample 4 as well as increases. This finding is consistent with extant literature all nine models and report the results in Table 7. We find that suggests that CEO power and influence increases with that CMO presence does not appear to have a (main) effect CEO tenure and, conversely, that other TMT members’ on a firm’s sales growth, consistent with N&M’s findings. power and influence is negatively related to CEO tenure We also estimated the model after removing the observa - (e.g., Hill and Phan 1991). Thus, the longer the CEO is in tions for Move Inc., because of the company’s unusually place, the less impact the CMO should have on the direc - large sales growth in 2000 (see previous discussion); the tion and strategy of the firm, in support of decreased perfor - results did not change in any meaningful way. We also note mance implications of the CMO. that CMO presence does not appear to have a lagged effect (one or two years) on sales growth. As outlined previously, Other performance outcome measures . We next we maintain that sales growth is not a suitable measure to assessed moderating effects considering the other perfor - capture the performance implications of the CMO. Thus, mance outcome measures, systematic and idiosyncratic we speculate that these nonfindings are at least partially a risk, as well as sales growth. As Table 8 shows, a negative function of the sales growth measure (1) not being able to and marginally significant interaction between CMO pres - capture future performance implications of the CMO and ence and differentiation emerged when systematic risk was (2) being an organizational goal agnostic measure. the dependent variable. Moreover, a positive and significant interaction between CMO presence and differentiation Do Certain Firms Benefit More (or Less) from a emerged in the model in which sales growth was the depen - CMO? dent variable. Although the interaction was not significant We next examined whether the effect of CMO presence is when considering Tobin’s q as the outcome measure (see moderated by firm-specific characteristics—that is, whether Table 8), the finding is consistent with N&M’s prediction some firms benefit more or less from having a CMO. We that firms pursuing relatively high levels of differentiation again used Sample 4 for this analysis. We first focus on should benefit more from having a CMO in the C-suite than Tobin’s q as the outcome measure and subsequently exam - firms pursuing lower levels of differentiation (N&M did not ine the other outcome measures, that is, systematic and find empirical support for this hypothesis). Quite correctly idiosyncratic risk, as well as sales growth. We present in our opinion, N&M argue that strategies of differentiation results from the 2SLSRE model here but note that the increase the need to identify market opportunities quickly. results were consistent across all models (results are avail - Moreover, they maintain that strategies of differentiation able from the authors). In brief, Tobin’s q seems to be rely heavily on marketing capabilities and that having a improved by CMO presence in the TMT for (1) firms with CMO among the TMT should help develop and foster such relatively higher sales growth, (2) firms that are relatively capabilities.

The Chief Marketing Officer Matters! / 17 TABLE 8 Results—Interaction Effects; Based on Sample 4 and Model 6 (2SLSRE) CMO Effect (SE) Variable a DV: Tobin’s q DV: Systematic Risk DV: Idiosyncratic Risk DV: Sales Growth CMO .77*** .04 .003** –.02 (.16) (.05) (.001) (.02) ¥ CMO Sales growth .73*** –.11 .005** Omitted (.24) (.08) (.002) ¥ CMO Differentiation 1.24 –1.12* –.02 .89** (2.04) (.67) (.02) (.38) ¥ CMO Innovation –1.18 –.10 –.006 .15 (.80) (.27) (.007) (.15) ¥ CMO Return on assets –.04 .18 .001 .13 (.40) (.13) (.004) (.08) ¥ CMO Number of employees –.16*** –.01 –.0005 –.001 (.05) (.02) (.0004) (.01) ¥ CMO Market concentration –.0002 –.0001 –.0000 –.00 (.0001) (.0001) (.0000) (.00) ¥ CMO Diversification .10 .02 –.0001 –.01 (.14) (.05) (.001) (.03) ¥ CMO Corporate branding –.07 –.01 –.0004 –.03 (.14) (.05) (.001) (.03) ¥ CMO Outsider CEO –.12 –.02 .002* –.05* (.14) (.05) (.001) (.03) ¥ CMO CEO tenure –.003*** –.0004 –.0000 –.0002 (.001) (.0003) (.0000) (.00014) ¥ CMO COO –.06 –.06 .001 –.04 (.13) (.04) (.001) (.03) *p < .10 ** p < .05. *** p < .01. ¥ aWe excluded the CMO Sales growth interaction from Model 4 (DV: Sales Growth) because sales growth is the DV of that model. We also note that we included the interactions between CMO and the respective year dummies in all the models. In addition, the variance inflation factors of the coefficients are less than 5 across all models, indicating that multicollinearity is not a concern. Notes: DV = dependent variable.

Considering idiosyncratic risk as the performance out - in Table 8 treating not only the CMO variable but also the come measure, we also find a positive and significant inter - four firm strategy variables as endogenous. We used peer action between CMO presence and sales growth. Recall that firm variables (e.g., differentiation prevalence among peer we also find a positive interaction between CMO presence firms) as instruments for the firm strategy variables follow - and sales growth when considering Tobin’s q as the perfor - ing the same procedure and logic as for the CMO presence mance outcome measure. Thus, both Tobin’s q and idiosyn - instrument. The results again suggest that Tobin’s q seems cratic risk seem to be increased by CMO presence in firms to be improved by CMO presence in the TMT for (1) firms with relatively higher sales growth. We posit that the joint with relatively higher sales growth, (2) firms that are rela - effect of CMO presence and sales growth on idiosyncratic tively smaller, and (3) firms whose CEO has relatively risk can at least be partially explained by the notion that shorter tenure. Moreover, as before, systematic risk seems CMOs tend to be risk seeking (e.g., Lord 2014). Indeed, to be decreased (and sales growth increased) by CMO pres - when a firm experiences high growth, its CMOs might be ence in the TMT for firms that are relatively more differen - even more risk prone, in support of the observed positive tiated. Finally, as before, we find a positive and significant interaction effect. interaction effect between sales growth and CMO presence when idiosyncratic risk is the dependent variable. Double selection . We also took into consideration a potential double selection effect as we examined the inter - actions. That is, the selection of a CMO and the selection of Discussion a firm strategy (differentiation, innovation, diversification, and branding strategy) may be occurring at the same time, The CMO Is Not Dead! thus resulting in double selection effects. To address this Recent business press articles have suggested that CMOs potential issue, we reestimated the 2SLSRE models shown are increasingly “powerless and peripheral” (e.g., Turpin

18 / Journal of Marketing, May 2015 2012, titled “The CMO Is Dead”). Our findings, which include in the risk model, followed by identifying addi - seem to be quite robust, question such conclusions. In short, tional control variables, and then reestimating the various our findings suggest that firms benefit from having a CMO models. Indeed, we used the same control variables in the among the TMT. Considering our largest sample (Sample risk model as we did in the Tobin’s q and sales growth 4), the CMO’s effect on Tobin’s q ranges from .17 to model, which we adopted from N&M. However, N&M approximately .77, depending on model specification. Thus, developed their model with Tobin’s q and sales growth as on the basis of the smallest CMO effect estimate (i.e., .17), the dependent variables, and not risk. Therefore, it is possi - our data and analyses suggest that Tobin’s q of firms that ble that our risk model excludes important control employ a CMO is approximately 15% larger than that of variables. firms that do not employ a CMO. 17 The CMO effect also seems to be moderated by firm-specific characteristics, Limitations including sales growth, number of employees, CEO tenure, Although we believe that we have broken new ground with and, to a lesser degree, differentiation strategies of the firm. this work, there are clear limitations, some of which pro - Moreover, our results indicate that, in addition to Tobin’s q, vide fruitful avenues for further research and discussion. CMO presence has a positive impact on excess stock a First, simply adding a CMO to the TMT will most likely not returns (i.e., Jensen’s ). In contrast, CMO presence does improve the performance of a firm; rather, the positive not seem to have a direct impact on a firm’s sales growth. effect that we observe in our study likely derives from the We note that these findings reinforce the importance of the role of marketing in our sample firms. Webster, Malter, and marketing–finance interface, in that it is only through market– Ganesan (2003), for example, suggest that CMO presence based measures that the significance of the CMO is is a credible signal that the firm is likely to appreciate the observed. marketing concept, and N&M propose that CMO presence Beyond the substantive insights, we hope that our is an indicator of marketing’s influence in the firm. Thus, if research also makes a methodological contribution to the firms employ a CMO, marketing is likely to play a more broader marketing strategy literature. Modeling phenomena prominent role in the firm, and that could be the source of as complex as the CMO’s performance implications, in our the performance effects we find. We note that the role of opinion, requires not only using a diverse set of models but marketing in the firm should, of course, be heavily influ - also careful consideration of the identifying assumptions enced by the CMO. Further research could examine underlying these models. Moreover, if the results are sensi - whether this prediction holds and, for example, attempt to tive to identifying assumptions (i.e., if different models give measure a firm’s market orientation (by means of, e.g., con - different results), researchers should discuss the identifying tent analyzing annual reports [e.g., Noble, Sinha, and assumptions and speculate on why the findings might be Kumar 2002]) and then analyze whether market orientation sensitive to these assumptions. mediates the CMO’s positive impact on firm performance. Here, we find that the positive effect of CMO presence Second, as we mentioned previously, our insights on Tobin’s q is consistent across a diverse set of models, regarding the CMO’s effect on idiosyncratic risk are limited each with different identifying assumptions. Given these given the lack of convergent findings. We hope that future convergent findings, our confidence in the identified posi - studies will further explore the CMO’s impact on firm risk. tive and significant CMO effect on Tobin’s q is high. We Third, our results are based on larger firms (i.e., firms with also find that the positive effect of CMO presence on firm more than $250 million in sales) that invest in both R&D idiosyncratic risk only manifests in the 2SLSRE model. We and advertising. We do not find a significant correlation believe that we have made a strong case for our choice of between firm size and CMO presence. Thus, we believe IV, namely, CMO prevalence among peer firms; in addition, that our results should hold even for smaller firms, although the Hausman test suggests that CMO presence is endoge - extrapolation outside the data range on which the models nous. Thus, it is possible that the nonfindings for idiosyn - were estimated should be done with caution. However, our cratic risks using the other models suffer from an endogene - results should not be generalized to firms that do not invest ity bias, but the 2SLSRE model corrects for that bias. in advertising and R&D. However, because the CMO effect is not significant in the random-effects with control function model, our other IV Conclusion model, we cannot conclude with high certainty that CMO Many CMOs struggle to prove their worth to other mem - presence indeed has a positive effect on idiosyncratic risk. bers of their top management team. Perhaps accordingly, We hope that researchers will further explore the CMO’s the average tenure of a CMO is estimated to be two years, impact on firm risk. For example, a potentially fruitful compared with five years for CEOs (e.g., N&M). Against study might entail reassessing the control variables we this backdrop, there have been strong calls among acade - mics and practitioners alike to shed more light on the per - 17 To arrive at these performance gain estimates, we computed formance implications of CMO presence (e.g., Boyd, two predicted values of Tobin’s q, one for firms with a CMO and one for those without a CMO, using the coefficients from Model 5 Chandy, and Cunha 2010). The key finding of our study is b (e.g., CMO = .17) and setting the other independent variables at that firms seem to benefit from having a CMO among the their sample mean. We then calculated the percentage difference TMT; we hope that this seemingly robust finding will help between the two predicted values. cement the presence of a CMO at the strategy table.

The Chief Marketing Officer Matters! / 19 For example, if a firm changes its CMO status during the Appendix: Simulation Study: fifth year, we could observe the following scenario: Within-Firm CMO Variability 000010000000 (i.e., a CMO is present in the fifth year but We conducted a simple simulation study to investigate the not in years 1–4 and years 6–12). We set p equal to the impact of various degrees of within-firm CMO variability observed CMO prevalence in our empirical application on four of the estimators that we use—namely, the OLS, (~.4) and vary q in 20 steps from .05 to 1 (i.e., in increments between-effects, fixed-effects, and random-effects estima - of .05). We did not include q = 0 because the fixed-effects tors. We consider the following data-generating model in estimator for CMO would not be identified in that case. our simulation: We consider the following three scenarios regarding b b b (A1) yit = 0i + 1CMO it + 2Xit + it , between versus within unobserved variation: s2 sb2 where y it is the dependent variable (e.g., Tobin’s q), CMO it 1. = 1 and = 1 (relatively equal within and between is 1 if firm i has a CMO in time period t and 0 otherwise, unobserved variation), s2 sb2 and X it is an exogenous regressor that varies across firms 2. = 1.5 and = .5 (relatively more within unobserved variation), and and over time. We do not consider endogeneity here and s2 s2 b 3. = .5 and b = 1.5 (relatively more between unobserved treat both CMO it and X it as exogenous. The parameter 0i is  a random intercept that varies across i. We set the true variation). b b ¥ parameters as follows: 1 = 1, 2 = –1, and the regressor X it Thus, we have a total of 20 3 = 60 experimental con - is independent and normally distributed across i and t with ditions. For each experimental condition, we generate 100 b mean 0 and variance 1 and has a small correlation (multi - data sets using Model A1 and estimate 1 with OLS, b collinearity) with CMO of .2. The error terms and between-effects, fixed-effects, and random-effects. We ana - it b 0i it are i.i.d. from a normal , with E( 0i ) = 10 and E( lyzed the root mean square error (RMSE) and the bias of s2 s2 ) = 0, and variances b and , respectively. The error the estimated CMO effect for each estimator. it b terms represent the unobserved between-firm variation ( 0i ) Figures A1 and A2 summarize our findings for Scenario  and unobserved within-firm variation ( it ). We change the 1 (we only report detailed results based on Scenario 1 here ratio of the two variances of the error terms to represent sit - but note that the pattern of results based on Scenarios 2 and s2 s2 uations in which there is relatively more within ( > b) 3 were similar; detailed results are available from the s2 s2 versus between ( b > ) unobserved variation. We use the authors). 18 As Figure A1 shows, the RMSE of the fixed- same sample size as in our empirical application (i.e., Sam - ple 4: 155 firms and 12 time periods).  18 For each experimental condition, we generate L = 100 simulated   data sets. For each data set = 1, …, L, we compute K estimators We generate the CMO variable as follows: With proba - b bility p, the firm has a CMO for all time periods, and with for 1 using OLS, between-effects, fixed-effects, and random-effects. SL bk Then, the RMSE for the kth estimator is RMSE k = (1/L) = 1 ( ˆ1 – probability q, the firm switches its CMO status one time b bk )2, where ˆ  is the estimate of the CMO effect of the kth esti - during the 12-year observation period (we note that several 1 1  b mator (e.g., the FE estimator) in the th simulated data, and 1 is of our sample firms switch CMO status more than once dur - the true value of the CMO effect used in the simulation study to SL bk] b1 ing the 12 years; however, to be conservative, we assume generate the data. Similarly, BIAS k = [ (1/L) = 1 ˆ1 – . A good that firms switch CMO status at most one time in this simu - estimator has a bias of 0 and a low RMSE; the best estimator here lation study). We randomly decide (with equal probabili - has the lowest RMSE. ties) in which time period the firm changes its CMO status. FIGURE A2 s2 s2b FIGURE A1 BIAS Based on Scenario 1: = 1 and = 1 s2 s2 RMSE Based on Scenario 1: = 1 and b = 1  .45 .5  .4 .40 OLS Between FE RE OLS Between FE RE .3 .35 .2

.30 S A

E .1 I S

.25 B

M 0 R .20 –.1 .15 –.2 .10 –.3 .05 –.4 0 –.5 .05 .15 .25 .35 .45 .55 .65 .75 .85 .95 .05 .15 .25 .35 .45 .55 .65 .75 .85 .95

Notes: Between = between-effects model; FE = fixed-effects model; Notes: Between = between-effects model; FE = fixed-effects model; RE = random-effects model. RE = random-effects model.

20 / Journal of Marketing, May 2015 effects estimator is largest for small values of q; that is, ased estimate of the CMO effect (Scenarios 2 and 3 yielded when most firms (up to approximately q = 15%) do not almost identical results). change CMO status across the 12 time periods. However, In our empirical application (considering Sample 4), 37% when approximately 20% of the firms change CMO status of the firms do not switch CMO status and 63% of the firms once during the 12 time periods, the between-effects esti - switch CMO status once or more. In our simulation study, mator has the largest RMSE. For Scenarios 2 and 3 (results the fixed-effects, random-effects, and (to a lesser degree) not shown), we find similar patterns: the fixed-effects esti - OLS estimators always behave well for levels of q > 60%. mator has the largest RMSE for values of q up to 45% and The between-effects estimator, however, has a fairly high 10%, respectively. Notably, the random-effects estimator RMSE for all levels of q. Whether fixed-effects, random- always has the lowest RMSE, and OLS always has a lower effects, and OLS estimators are more or less efficient than RMSE than the between-effects estimator. Moreover, Fig - between-effects estimators in the end is an empirical ques - ure A2 shows that, across all values of q, the CMO effect is tion. However, our simulation results indicate that fixed- estimated in an approximately unbiased way by all four effects, random-effects, and OLS estimators indeed seem to estimators. That is, even when only 5% of the firms switch be more efficient than the between-effects estimator given CMO status once, we still obtain an approximately unbi - the context of our CMO study.

REFERENCES Aksoy, Lerzan, Bruce Cooil, Christopher Groening, Timothy L. Fama, Eugene F. and Kenneth R. French (1992), “The Cross Section Keiningham, and Atakan Yalçın (2008), “The Long-Term of Expected Stock Returns,” Journal of Finance , 47 (2), 427–65. Stock Market Valuation of Customer Satisfaction,” Journal of ——— and ——— (1993), “Common Risk Factors in the Returns Marketing , 72 (July), 105–122. on Stocks and Bonds,” Journal of Finance Economics , 33 (1), Amit, Raphael and Birger Wernerfelt (1990), “Why Do Firms 3–56. Reduce Business Risk?” Academy of Management Journal , 33 Finkelstein, Sydney, Donald C. Hambrick, and Albert A. Cannella (3), 520–33. Jr. (2009), Strategic Leadership: Theory and Research on Anderson, Eugene W., Claes Fornell, and Sanal K. Mazvancheryl Executives, Top Management Teams, and Boards . New York: (2004), “Customer Satisfaction and Shareholder Value,” Jour - Oxford University Press. nal of Marketing , 68 (October), 172–85. Frazier, Mya (2007), “CMOs Rapped for Having Zero Impact on Angrist, Joshua D. and J ӧrn-Steffen Pischke (2009), Mostly Harm - Sales,” Advertising Age , 78 (July), 1. less Econometrics: An Empiricist’s Companion . Princeton, NJ: Geyskens, Inge, Katrijn Gielens, and Marnik G. Dekimpe (2002), Princeton University Press. “The Market Valuation of Internet Channel Additions,” Jour - ——— and ——— (2010), “The Credibility Revolution in Empiri - nal of Marketing , 66 (April), 102–119. cal Economics: How Better Research Design Is Taking the Con Graham, John R., Campbell R. Harvey, and Shiva Rajgopal out of Econometrics,” Journal of Economic Literature , 24 (2), (2005), “The Economic Implications of Corporate Financial 3–30. Reporting,” Journal of Accounting and Economics , 40 (1–3), Arellano, Manuel and Stephen R. Bond (1991), “Some Tests of 3–73. Specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo Evidence and an Granovetter, Mark (1985), “Economic Action and Social Struc - Application to Employment Equations,” Review of Economic ture: The Problem of Embeddedness,” American Journal of Studies , 58 (2), 277–97. Sociology , 91 (3), 481–510. ——— and Olympia Bover (1995), “Another Look at the Grewal, Rajdeep and Rebecca J. Slotegraaf (2007), “Embedded - Instrumental-Variable Estimation of Error-Components Mod - ness of Organizational Capabilities,” Decision Sciences , 38 (3), els,” Journal of Econometrics , 68 (1), 29–51. 451–88. Barney, Jay (1991), “Firm Resources and Sustained Competitive Haleblian, Jerayr and Sydney Finkelstein (1993), “Top Manage - Advantage,” Journal of Management , 17 (1), 99–120. ment Team Size, CEO Dominance, and Firm Performance: The Barta, Thomas (2011), “Do Firms Need CMOs?” (accessed March Moderating Roles of Environmental Turbulence and Discre - 3, 2014), [available at http://www.thomasbarta.com/do-firms- tion,” Academy of Management Journal , 36 (4), 844–63. need-cmos/]. Hambrick, Donald C. and Gregory D.S. Fukutomi (1991), “The Blundell, Richard and Stephen Bond (1998), “Initial Conditions Seasons of a CEO’s Tenure,” Academy of Management Review , and Moment Restrictions in Dynamic Panel Data Models,” 16 (4), 719–42. Journal of Econometrics , 87 (1), 115–43. Hausman, Jerry A. and William E. Taylor (1981), “Panel Data and ——— and ——— (1999), “GMM Estimation with Persistent Panel Unobservable Individual Effects,” Econometrica , 43 (6), Data: An Application to Production Function Estimation,” 1377–98. Working Paper Series No. W99/4, The Institute for Fiscal Stud - Heckman, James and Salvador Navarro-Lozano (2004), “Using ies, London. Matching, Instrumental Variables, and Control Functions to Boyd, D. Eric, Rajesh K. Chandy, and Marcus Cunha Jr. (2010), Estimate Economic Choice Models,” Review of Economics and “When Do Chief Marketing Officers Affect Firm Value? A Statistics , 36 (1), 30–57. Customer Power Explanation,” Journal of Marketing Hill, Charles W.L. and Phillip Phan (1991), “CEO Tenure as a Research , 47 (December), 1162–76. Determinant of CEO Pay,” Academy of Management Journal , Buzzell, Robert D. and Bradley T. Gale (1987), The PIMS Princi - 34 (3), 707–717. ples . New York: The Free Press. Jacobson, Robert (1990), “Unobservable Effects and Business Carhart, Mark M. (1997), “On Persistence in Mutual Fund Perfor - Performance,” Marketing Science , 9 (1), 74–85. mance,” Journal of Finance , 52 (1), 57–82. ——— and Natalie Mizik (2009), “The Financial Markets and Cus - Day, George S. and Robin Wensley (1988), “Assessing Advan - tomer Satisfaction: Reexamining Possible Financial Market tage: A Framework for Diagnosing Competitive Superiority,” Mispricing of Customer Satisfaction,” Marketing Science , 28 Journal of Marketing , 52 (April), 1–20. (5), 810–19.

The Chief Marketing Officer Matters! / 21 Jensen, Michael C. (1968), “The Performance of Mutual Funds in Noble, Charles H., Rajiv K. Sinha, and Ajith Kumar (2002), “Mar - the Period 1945–1964,” Journal of Finance , 23 (2), 389–416. ket Orientation and Alternative Strategic Orientations: A Lon - Keele, Luke and Nathan J. Kelly (2006), “Dynamic Models for gitudinal Assessment of Performance Implications,” Journal of Dynamic Theories: The Ins and Outs of Lagged Dependent Marketing , 66 (October), 25–39. Variables,” International Journal of Public Opinion Research , Roodman, David (2009), “A Note on the Theme of Too Many 14 (2), 186–205. Instruments,” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Strategy , 71 Kerin, Roger A. (2005), “Strategic Marketing and the CMO,” in (1), 135–58. “Marketing Renaissance: Opportunities and Imperatives for Rossi, Peter E. (2014), “Even the Rich Can Make Themselves Improving Marketing Thought, Practice, and Infrastructure,” Poor: A Critical Examination of IV Methods in Marketing Journal of Marketing , 69 (October), 12–14. Applications,” Marketing Science , 33 (5), 655–72. Kochan, Thomas A. and Saul A. Rubinstein (2000), “Toward a Shoebridge, Neil (2007), “A Title Worthy of Respect,” BRW , Stakeholder Theory of the Firm: The Saturn ,” (August 9), 25–26. Organization Science , 11 (4), 367–86. Simms, Jane (2008), “Marketers Lack Influence in the Boardroom,” Leamer, Edward E. (1983), “Let’s Take the Con out of Economet - BrandRepublic , (January 8), (accessed January 19, 2014), rics,” American Economic Review , 73 (1), 31–43. [available at http://www.brandrepublic.com/news/ 776449/ Lintner, John (1965), “The Valuation of Risk Assets and the Selec - Marketers-lack-influence-boardroom/?DCMP=ILC-SEARCH]. tion of Risky Investments in Stock Portfolios and Capital Bud - Slater, Stanley F. and John C. Narver (1994), “Does Competitive gets,” Review of Economics and Statistics , 47 (1), 13–37. Environment Moderate the Market Orientation–Performance Lord, Joanna (2014), “20 Traits of Successful CMOs,” Marketing - Relationship?” Journal of Marketing , 58 (January), 46–55. Land, (February 11), (accessed October 25, 2014), [available at Srinivasan, Raji, Gary L. Lilien, and Shrihari Sridhar (2011), http://marketingland.com/20-traits-successful-cmos-2-73629. “Should Firms Spend More on Research and Development and Lyon, John D., Brad M. Barber, and Chih-Ling Tsai (1999), Advertising During Recessions?” Journal of Marketing , 75 “Improved Methods for Tests of Long-Run Abnormal Stock (May), 49–65. Returns, Journal of Finance , 54 (1), 165–201. Srivastava, Rajendra K., Tasadduq A. Shervani, and Liam Fahey Madden, Thomas J., Frank Fehle, and Susan Fournier (2006), (1998), “Market-Based Assets and Shareholder Value: A “Brands Matter: An Empirical Demonstration of the Creation Framework for Analysis,” Journal of Marketing , 62 (January), of Shareholder Value Through Branding,” Journal of the Acad - 2–18. emy of Marketing Science , 34 (2), 224–35. Tobin, James (1969), “A General Equilibrium Approach to Mone - McAlister, Leigh, Raji Srinivasan, and MinChung Kim (2007), tary Theory,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking , 1 (1), 15– “Advertising, Research and Development, and Systematic Risk 29. of the Firm,” Journal of Marketing , 71 (January), 35–48. Tuli, Kapil R. and Sundar G. Bharadwaj (2009), “Customer Satis - McGovern, Gail J., David Court, John A. Quelch, and Blair Craw - faction and Stock Returns Risk,” Journal of Marketing , 73 ford (2004), “Bringing Customers into the Boardroom,” Har - (November), 184–97. vard Business Review , 82 (11), 70–80. Turpin, Dominique (2012), “The CMO Is Dead,” Forbes , (October Miller, Danny and Jamal Shamsie (2001), “Learning Across the 3), (accessed September 1, 2014), [available at http:// www. Life Cycle: Experimentation and Performance Among the Hol - forbes. com/sites/onmarketing/2012/10/03/the-cmo-is-dead/]. lywood Studio Heads,” Journal , 22 (8), Verbeek, Marno (2012), A Guide to Modern Econometrics , 4th ed. 725–45. Chichester, UK: John Wiley & Sons. Montgomery, Cynthia A. and Birger Wernerfelt (1988), “Diversifi - Webster, Frederick E., Alan J. Malter, and Shankar Ganesan cation, Ricardian Rents, and Tobin’s q,” RAND Journal of Eco - (2003), “Can Marketing Regain Its Seat at the Table?” Market - nomics , 19 (4), 623–32. ing Science Institute Report No. 03-003. Moorman, Christine (2013), “The CMO Survey—August 2013,” Weinzimmer, Laurence G., Edward U. Bond, Mark B. Houston, (accessed January 18, 2014), [available at http:// cmosurvey. and Paul C. Nystrom (2003), “Relating Marketing Expertise on org/ results/survey-results-august-2013/]. the Top Management Team and Strategic Aggressiveness to Nath, Pravin and Vijay Mahajan (2008), “Chief Marketing Offi - Financial Performance,” Journal of Strategic Marketing , 11 cers: A Study of Their Presence in Firms’ Top Management (2), 133–59. Teams,” Journal of Marketing , 72 (January), 65–81. Whitler, Kimberly (2013), “Do CMOs Impact Firm Performance?” ——— and ——— (2011), “Marketing Influence in the C-Suite: A Forbes , (June 25), (accessed March 3, 2014), [available at Study of Chief Marketing Officer Power in Firms’ Top Man - http:// www.forbes.com/sites/kimberlywhitler/ 2013 / 06/ 25/ do- agement Teams,” Journal of Marketing , 75 (January), 60–77. cmos-impact-firm-performance/]. Nickell, Stephen J. (1981), “Biases in Dynamic Models with Fixed Wooldridge, Jeffrey M. (2002), Econometric Analysis of Cross Effects,” Econometrica , 49 (6), 1417–26. Section and Panel Data . Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Zhang, Juanjuan and Peng Liu (2012), “Rational Herding in Microloan Markets,” Management Science , 58 (5), 892–912.

22 / Journal of Marketing, May 2015