Reflation, Reopening, and Readjustment

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Reflation, Reopening, and Readjustment Commentary 2021 Outlook: Reflation, Reopening, and Readjustment Dirk Hofschire, CFA KEY TAKEAWAYS Senior Vice President Asset Allocation Research • Most global economies enter 2021 in early-cycle recoveries, with a prospective economic reopening likely to lead to a broadening expansion as the year unfolds. Jacob Weinstein, CFA • The winter rise in virus cases represents a strong near-term headwind but is unlikely Research Analyst to cause a double-dip recession. Asset Allocation Research • Global monetary policy remains highly accommodative and supportive of asset Lisa Emsbo-Mattingly, CBE prices, but the fiscal policy outlook is more uncertain. Director of Research • Amid positive vaccine news, investors’ expectations for a full economic reopening Asset Allocation Research have underpinned a reflation trade driving Treasury yields and stock prices higher. Jenna Christensen • With higher asset valuations already reflecting positive expectations for reopening, Research Associate financial markets may be influenced heavily by the trajectory of policy, inflation, and Asset Allocation Research real interest rates; therefore, some volatility is likely. Cait Dourney, CFA Research Analyst Asset Allocation Research Macroeconomic backdrop: Constructive cycle progression despite winter doldrums The global business cycle will begin 2021 in recovery mode. • Most major economies exited brief but sharp recessions during the third quarter and have generally made improvements since the first half of 2020. • China’s progression is ahead of most other economies, in part because of its quicker emergence from lockdowns and the rapid recovery in global manufacturing (Exhibit 1, page 2). • The U.S. is in an early-cycle recovery phase, progressing toward a mid-cycle expansion. • Although activity remains below 2019 levels in most major economies, the prospect of a vaccine-related full reopening over the next year makes us constructive on the continued broadening of the economic expansion in 2021. EXHIBIT 1: Most global economies remain in the early-cycle recovery phase, though a rise in COVID-19 cases has moderat- ed the pace of growth. China has advanced to the mid-cycle phase of expansion. Business Cycle Framework Cycle Phases EARLY MID LATE RECESSION • Activity rebounds (GDP, IP, • Growth peaking • Growth moderating • Falling activity employment, incomes) • Credit growth strong • Credit tightens • Credit dries up • Credit begins to grow • Profi t growth peaks • Earnings under pressure • Profi ts decline • Profi ts grow rapidly • Policy neutral • Policy contractionary • Policy eases • Policy still stimulative • Inventories, sales grow; • Inventories grow; sales • Inventories, sales fall • Inventories low; sales improve equilibrium reached growth falls Infl ationary Pressures Red = High China U.S. Australia, Brazil, India Eurozone, UK, Canada + RECOVERY EXPANSION CONTRACTION Economic Growth – Japan, Korea, Mexico Relative Performance of Economically Sensitive Assets Green = Strong The diagram above is a hypothetical illustration of the business cycle. There is not always a chronological, linear progression among the phases of the business cycle, and there have been cycles when the economy has skipped a phase or retraced an earlier one. Source: Fidelity Investments (Asset Allocation Research Team), as of Nov. 30, 2020. The winter virus resurgence presents a near-term • The U.S. consumer is better poised to weather this headwind for economic improvement, but not one that near-term economic lull due to the approximate we expect will generate a double-dip recession. $1 trillion of excess savings built up over the past • Recent European restrictions were less stringent several months (Exhibit 3, page 3). and therefore less harmful to economic activity than • Although the savings is unequally distributed across those implemented in the spring, some countries U.S. households, the aggregate savings cushion have already moved to loosen their restrictions, and is the result of reduced spending and massive the global industrial upswing continues to benefit government transfers during the first half of the year. European manufacturing and exports. Personal savings rates averaged 20% from April • We expect new U.S. restrictions to be on the lighter through October—nearly three times as high as the end of the range of those taken in Europe and the rate at the end of 2019. overall economic impact to represent a stalling rather than a severe reversal of economic momentum in the very near term. Service activity has slowed amid the recent surge in virus cases, but manufacturing activity remains strong (Exhibit 2, page 3). 2021 Outlook: Reflation, Reopening, and Readjustment | 2 EXHIBIT 2: The recovery in manufacturing has persisted, EXHIBIT 3: U.S. consumers have amassed excess savings while service industry activity has slowed amid the new over the past several months; which should help them wave of virus cases. withstand a near-term economic setback. AART High Frequency Composite Indices Excess Personal Savings Breakdown Manufacturing Services Rise in Personal Income Decline in Spending Jan. 2020 = 100 $ Billons 130 1,200 100 1,000 90 $307B 800 80 600 70 400 60 $684B 200 50 0 Jul 20 Jan 20 Jan Jun 20 Apr 20 Oct 20 Oct Feb 20 Feb Sep 20 Mar 20 Mar Dec 20 Nov 20 Nov Aug 20 Aug May 20 May AART Services and Manufacturing Indices are proprietary indices based on Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Haver Analytics, Fidelity Investments high-frequency data from multiple and variable sources. Source: Haver (AART), as of Oct. 31, 2020. Analytics, Fidelity Investments (AART), as of Dec. 4, 2020. Policy environment: Supportive monetary, Fiscal-policy uncertainty contributes to the cloudy uncertain fiscal inflation outlook for 2021. Global monetary policy remains extremely • The U.S. Congress approved a roughly $900 accommodative, with the Federal Reserve and billion stimulus package in late December that will other central banks anchoring short-term interest help offset some of the near-term, virus-related rates around zero and expanding their balance economic weakness. sheets through quantitative easing (QE) and other • However, a growing budget crunch at the state and extraordinary programs (Exhibit 4, page 4). local level implies the possibility of a fiscal drag on • The QE tailwind is less forceful than it was at the the economy in 2021. beginning of the pandemic outbreak in the spring, • The Georgia Senate runoffs in early January will but it remains a supportive liquidity backdrop for determine which party controls the Senate in 2021, asset markets. which will shape fiscal policy for the remainder of • Near record-low Treasury yields also support higher the year. asset valuations, as all other types of assets look attractive by comparison. 2021 Outlook: Reflation, Reopening, and Readjustment | 3 EXHIBIT 4: Monetary policy from central banks around the EXHIBIT 5: Real yields bottomed in early September and world remains extremely accommodative. rose modestly since, as investors anticipated a reflationary Central Bank Balance Sheets economic backdrop. Real Yields in 2020 U.S. Eurozone Japan Total Weak growth Rising inflation Disinflation $ Billions (12-Month Change) Reflation Real Yields $8,000 % of Days (21-Day Rolling) Yield (%) 60% $7,000 0.75 0.50 $6,000 50% $5,000 0.25 40% $4,000 0.00 $3,000 30% -0.25 $2,000 -0.50 20% $1,000 -0.75 $0 10% -1.00 -$1,000 0% -1.25 Nov 07 Nov 08 Nov 09 Nov 10 Nov 11 Nov 12 Nov 13 Nov 14 Nov 15 Nov 16 Nov 17 Nov 18 Nov 19 Nov 20 Nov 1/2/20 1/30/20 2/27/20 3/26/20 4/23/20 5/21/20 6/18/20 7/16/20 8/13/20 9/10/20 10/8/20 11/5/20 12/3/20 Source: Federal Reserve, Bank of Japan, European Central Bank, Haver Shaded areas represent regimes with respect to the direction of real rates. Analytics, Fidelity Investments (AART), as of Nov. 30, 2020. The regimes are determined by the dominating factor between the change in 10-Year Treasury bond yields and 10-Year breakeven rates as implied by Treasury Inflation Protected Securities. Source: Bloomberg Finance L.P., Fidelity Investments (AART), as of Dec. 11, 2020. • If the Senate remains in Republican control and Reflation driven by reopening expectations: results in a divided government, fiscal policy will Expect some volatility too be less likely to experience significant changes and Positive vaccine developments and expectations for a would be less supportive of economic growth (and full economic reopening in 2021 generated a “reflation” inflation) in 2021. trade in financial markets during the final months of • A Democrat-controlled Senate would likely move to 2020. A reflation trade is marked by upward pressure legislate larger fiscal deficits and higher-multiplier on Treasury bond yields amid rising expectations for government spending. This scenario could generate an acceleration in nominal growth. greater inflation risk on a 12- to 18-month basis if • After a period of weak growth amid falling real a renewed fiscal push accompanies a widespread (inflation-adjusted) rates though the first two-thirds reopening of the economy. of 2020, real rates bottomed on September 1 and rose modestly from extremely low, negative levels (Exhibit 5). 2021 Outlook: Reflation, Reopening, and Readjustment | 4 EXHIBIT 6: Performance leadership has shifted amid a EXHIBIT 7: With Treasury yields near all-time lows, riskier reflation dynamic, with small caps and emerging-market assets appear to have priced in good news and are trading stocks outperforming since September. near the top of their historical ranges. Asset Performance During 2020 Percentile Valuation of U.S. Assets: Today Vs. History (1989–2020) 100% Jan 1– Sep 1– Aug 31, 2020 Dec 11, 2020 90% 80% U.S. Small Cap -5% 22% 70% EM Equities 2% 13% 60% 50% DM Equities -4% 10% 40% U.S. Value -10% 10% 30% High Yield 2% 4% 20% 10% U.S. Large Cap 11% 4% 0% Treasury bonds: Stocks: High-yield bonds: U.S. Growth 36% 1% Yield-to-maturity Price-to-earnings Yield-to-worst IG Bonds 7% 0% Treasury bonds represented by 10-year Treasuries.
Recommended publications
  • Neoliberalism and the Discontented
    1 NEOLIBERALISM AND THE DISCONTENTED GREGORY ALBO hen neoliberalism made its debut as a political project at the end of Wthe 1970s, it was taken for granted in most quarters of the Left that it was neither politically nor economically sustainable. The emerging New Right regimes of Ronald Reagan, Margaret Thatcher, Helmut Kohl and Bri- an Mulroney could intensify class conflict and spread the ideology of market populism, it was suggested, but they would leave no enduring institutional or political legacy. The monetarist and free market policies trumpeted by these governments – and incorporated into the policy arsenal of the international financial institutions – could only magnify the economic problems that had ended the postwar boom. The increasing complexity of post-Fordist tech- nologies and organization demanded far greater institutional capacities than capitalist markets and firms could supply on their own. Growing civil society movements were, moreover, beginning to forge a political accord with tradi- tional working-class unions and parties: a new egalitarian politics was being fashioned for the ‘new times’ to accommodate previously oppressed social identities. The political question of the day was, as Eric Hobsbawm was one of the foremost in arguing, the voting and programmatic agenda of such a ‘rational left’. The prospect of a ‘popular front’ government, built on a coalition of disciplined unions, new social movements, and social democratic parties sup- ported by communists, would serve as the foundation from which to bridge the neoliberal interlude. In 1986, two decades ago, Hobsbawm, speaking with respect to Britain, had already concluded that the neoliberals’ performance ‘utterly discredited, in the minds of most people, the privatizing “free mar- ket” ideology of the suburban crusaders who dressed up the right of the rich to get richer among the ruins as a way of solving the world’s and Britain’s problems.
    [Show full text]
  • Working Paper
    WP 2020-12 December 2020 Working Paper Charles H. Dyson School of Applied Economics and Management Cornell University, Ithaca, New York 14853-7801 USA Social Externalities and Economic Analysis Marc Fleurbaey, Ravi Kanbur, and Brody Viney It is the Policy of Cornell University actively to support equality of educational and employment opportunity. No person shall be denied admission to any educational program or activity or be denied employmen t on the basis of any legally prohibited discrimination involving, but not limited to, such factors as race, color, creed, religion, national or ethnic origin, sex, age or handicap. The University is committed to the maintenance of affirmative action prog rams which will assure the continuation of such equality of opportunity. 2 Social Externalities and Economic Analysis Marc Fleurbaey, Ravi Kanbur, Brody Viney ThisThis version: versio Augustn: Aug 6,us 2020t 6, 20201 Abstract This paper considers and assesses the concept of social externalities through human interdependence, in relation to the economic analysis of externalities in the tradition of Pigou and Arrow, including the analysis of the commons. It argues that there are limits to economic analysis. Our proposal is to enlarge the perspective and start thinking about a broader framework in which any pattern of influence of an agent or a group of agents over a third party, which is not mediated by any economic, social, or psychological mechanism guaranteeing the alignment of the marginal net private benefit with marginal net social benefit, can be attached the “externality” label and be scrutinized for the likely negative consequences that result from the divergence .These consequences may be significant given the many interactions between the social and economic realms, and the scope for spillovers and feedback loops to emerge.
    [Show full text]
  • Revisiting Stimulus and the Great Recession
    The Daily Dish Revisiting Stimulus and the Great Recession DOUGLAS HOLTZ-EAKIN | OCTOBER 21, 2020 Eakinomics: Revisiting Stimulus and the Great Recession There has been a steady drumbeat of calls for additional “stimulus” to counter the fallout of the COVID-19 recession. I want to stipulate that I think the case can be made for an appropriately structured fiscal bill, but the case is not being made in a compelling fashion. A key part of the argument has been that stimulus got cut off after the 2008-09 recession and doomed the economy to slow growth. A New York Times article, entitled “ Why the U.S. Risks Repeating 2009’s Economic Stimulus Mistakes,” is typical. “‘The initial response was good, but we need more,’ said Karen Dynan, who was chief economist at the Treasury Department in the Obama administration and now teaches at Harvard. The decision to pull back on spending a decade ago, she said, ‘really prolonged the period of weakness after the great recession.’” (This argument is most often made by former Obama Administration officials.) Maybe. But maybe there is another lesson from that era. The first is that if you are going to do fiscal stimulus, do fiscal stimulus. The American Recovery and Reinvestment Act (ARRA) contained some tax cuts and social safety net transfers of the typical stimulus ilk. But it contained a slew of provisions – e.g., health services information technologies and green investments – that were transformative in nature and core parts of the Obama domestic agenda. Transformation is not stimulus, which is just putting back in place what was previously there.
    [Show full text]
  • Deflation: Economic Significance, Current Risk, and Policy Responses
    Deflation: Economic Significance, Current Risk, and Policy Responses Craig K. Elwell Specialist in Macroeconomic Policy August 30, 2010 Congressional Research Service 7-5700 www.crs.gov R40512 CRS Report for Congress Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress Deflation: Economic Significance, Current Risk, and Policy Responses Summary Despite the severity of the recent financial crisis and recession, the U.S. economy has so far avoided falling into a deflationary spiral. Since mid-2009, the economy has been on a path of economic recovery. However, the pace of economic growth during the recovery has been relatively slow, and major economic weaknesses persist. In this economic environment, the risk of deflation remains significant and could delay sustained economic recovery. Deflation is a persistent decline in the overall level of prices. It is not unusual for prices to fall in a particular sector because of rising productivity, falling costs, or weak demand relative to the wider economy. In contrast, deflation occurs when price declines are so widespread and sustained that they cause a broad-based price index, such as the Consumer Price Index (CPI), to decline for several quarters. Such a continuous decline in the price level is more troublesome, because in a weak or contracting economy it can lead to a damaging self-reinforcing downward spiral of prices and economic activity. However, there are also examples of relatively benign deflations when economic activity expanded despite a falling price level. For instance, from 1880 through 1896, the U.S. price level fell about 30%, but this coincided with a period of strong economic growth.
    [Show full text]
  • Lessons from Koizumi-Era Financial Services Sector Reforms Naomi Fink
    Lessons from Koizumi-Era Financial Services Sector Reforms Naomi Fink Discussion Paper No. 80 Naomi Fink Founder and CEO, Europacifica Consulting Discussion Paper Series APEC Study Center Columbia University November 2016 Case Study: Financial Services Sector Reform in Japan APEC Policy Support Unit 27th July 2016 Prepared by: Naomi Fink, Europacifica Consulting & RMIT University Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation Policy Support Unit Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation Secretariat 35 Heng Mui Keng Terrace Tel: (65) 6891-9600 Fax: (65) 6891-9690 Email: [email protected] Website: www.apec.org Produced for: Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation APEC Policy Support Unit APEC#[APEC publication number] This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial- ShareAlike 3.0 Singapore License. To view a copy of this license, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-sa/3.0/sg/. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of APEC Member Economies. Table of Contents LESSONS FROM KOIZUMI-ERA FINANCIAL SERVICES SECTOR REFORMS ........................... 1 FINANCIAL SERVICES SECTOR REFORM IN JAPAN .......................................................................... 1 Executive Summary ................................................................... Error! Bookmark not defined. 1. The need for structural reform in Japan .............................................................................. 2 1.1. Political economy of the Japanese financial sector: .............................................
    [Show full text]
  • Neoliberalism and the Discontented
    NEOLIBERALISM AND THE DISCONTENTED GREGORY ALBO hen neoliberalism made its debut as a political project at the end of Wthe 1970s, it was taken for granted in most quarters of the Left that it was neither politically nor economically sustainable. The emerging New Right regimes of Ronald Reagan, Margaret Thatcher, Helmut Kohl and Brian Mulroney could intensify class conflict and spread the ideology of market populism, it was suggested, but they would leave no enduring insti- tutional or political legacy. The monetarist and free market policies trum- peted by these governments – and incorporated into the policy arsenal of the international financial institutions – could only magnify the economic problems that had ended the postwar boom. The increasing complexity of post-Fordist technologies and organization demanded far greater institu- tional capacities than capitalist markets and firms could supply on their own. Growing civil society movements were, moreover, beginning to forge a political accord with traditional working-class unions and parties: a new egalitarian politics was being fashioned for the ‘new times’ to accommodate previously oppressed social identities. The political question of the day was, as Eric Hobsbawm was one of the foremost in arguing, the voting and programmatic agenda of such a ‘rational left’. The prospect of a ‘popular front’ government, built on a coalition of disciplined unions, new social movements, and social democratic par- ties supported by communists, would serve as the foundation from which to bridge the neoliberal interlude. In 1986, two decades ago, Hobsbawm, speaking with respect to Britain, had already concluded that the neoliber- als’ performance was ‘utterly discredited, in the minds of most people, the privatizing “free market” ideology of the suburban crusaders who dressed up the right of the rich to get richer among the ruins as a way of solving the world’s and Britain’s problems.
    [Show full text]
  • Income, Liquidity, and the Consumption Response to the 2020 Economic Stimulus Payments Scott R
    Income, Liquidity, and the Consumption Response to the 2020 Economic Stimulus Payments Scott R. Baker, R. A. Farrokhnia, Steffen Meyer, Michaela Pagel, and Constantine Yannelis NBER Working Paper No. 27097 May 2020, Revised in September 2020 JEL No. D14,E21,G51 ABSTRACT The 2020 CARES Act directed large cash payments to households. We analyze house-holds’ spending responses using high-frequency transaction data from a Fintech non-profit, exploring heterogeneity by income levels, recent income declines, and liquidity as well as linked survey responses about economic expectations. Households respond rapidly to the re-ceipt of stimulus payments, with spending increasing by $0.25-$0.40 per dollar of stimulus during the first weeks. Households with lower incomes, greater income drops, and lower lev-els of liquidity display stronger responses highlighting the importance of targeting. Liquidity plays the most important role, with no significant spending response for households with large checking account balances. Households that expect employment losses and benefit cuts dis-play weaker responses to the stimulus. Relative to the effects of previous economic stimulus programs in 2001 and 2008, we see faster effects, smaller increases in durables spending, larger increases in spending on food, and substantial increases in payments like rents, mortgages, and credit cards reflecting a short- term debt overhang. We formally show that these differences can make direct payments less effective in stimulating aggregate consumption. Scott R. Baker Michaela Pagel Kellogg School of Management Columbia Business School Northwestern University 3022 Broadway 2211 Campus Drive Uris Hall Evanston, IL 60208 New York, NY 10027 and NBER and NBER [email protected] [email protected] R.
    [Show full text]
  • Monetary Policy in the Great Depression: What the Fed Did, and Why
    David C. Wheelock David C. Wheelock, assistant professor of economics at the University of Texas-Austin, is a visiting scholar at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. David H. Kelly provided research assistance. Monetary Policy in the Great Depression: What the Fed Did, and Why SIXTY YEARS AGO the United States— role of monetary policy in causing the Depression indeed; most of the world—was in the midst of and the possibility that different policies might the Great Depression. Today, interest in the have made it less severe. Depression's causes and the failure of govern- ment policies to prevent it continues, peaking Much of the debate centers on whether mone- whenever the stock market crashes or the econ- tary conditions were "easy" or "tight" during the omy enters a recession. In the 1930s, dissatisfac- Depression—that is, whether money and credit tion with the failure of monetary policy to pre- were plentiful and inexpensive, or scarce and vent the Depression, or to revive the economy, expensive. During the 1930s, many Fed officials led to sweeping changes in the structure of the argued that money was abundant and "cheap," Federal Reserve System. One of the most impor- even "sloppy," because market interest rates tant changes was the creation of the Federal were low and few banks borrowed from the dis- Open Market Committee (FOMC) to direct open count window. Modern researchers who agree market policy. Recently Congress has again con- generally believe neither that monetary forces sidered possible changes in the Federal Reserve were responsible for the Depression nor that System.1 different policies could have alleviated it.
    [Show full text]
  • Nils Bernstein: the European Debt Crisis – from a Danish Perspective
    Nils Bernstein: The European debt crisis – from a Danish perspective Speech by Mr Nils Bernstein, Governor of the National Bank of Denmark, at the seminar “Europe in the times of crisis – are we looking for solutions or parachutes?”, at Danske Bank, Copenhagen, 14 December 2011. The slides can be found on the website of the National Bank of Denmark. * * * Thank you for inviting me to speak here today. I will touch upon the European debt crisis from a Danish perspective. The world economy has lost momentum since last spring and short-term outlook has worsened. The European economies, especially in the euro area, have seen the strongest slowdown. But there are considerable differences from country to country. Germany and France continued to enjoy solid growth in the 3rd quarter, whereas growth in the most indebted countries, the five GIIPS countries i.e. Greece, Italy, Ireland, Portugal and Spain, has been close to zero or even negative (slide 2 – real GDP). There is a clear division among the EU Member States: countries, with relatively sound public finances and external balances before the crisis, are performing better than countries with internal and external imbalances (slide 3 – General government balance). But over the past couple of months even euro area Member States with sound economies have been affected by rising interest rates. There is considerable volatility, and three groups in the euro area seem to have been formed. The first group with the narrowest spreads to Germany includes Finland, the Netherlands, Austria and France. The second group consists, among others, of Belgium, Spain and Italy and the third group is Ireland, Portugal and Greece.
    [Show full text]
  • Reflation Trade” and Through an Eventual Tightening Policy Environment
    Relative value beyond the “reflation trade” and through an eventual tightening policy environment FEBRUARY 2021 Monetary Policy Drives Asset Inflation But the Fed seems almost defensive about The November announcements by its role in asset price inflation. In his Pfizer/BioNTech and Moderna regarding January 27 press conference, Fed Chair highly encouraging vaccine efficacy data Powell flatly rejected this very suggestion: represented the first true bright spot for “If you look at what’s really been driving the near-term economic outlook since the asset prices in the last couple of months, beginning of the pandemic almost a year it isn’t monetary policy… It’s been ago. Credit and equity markets had already expectations about vaccines, and it’s also been on a virtually uninterrupted charge fiscal policy.” higher since March, buoyed by fiscal and This is true, to be sure. However, with monetary policy and more recently by an the Fed’s new policy of average inflation election result that seemed likely to deliver targeting (allowing inflation to overshoot its more calm, less uncertainty and more long-term 2% goal due to years of lagging) stimulus. The vaccine rollout seemed a and a palpable fear of triggering a repeat justification, if not an outright catalyst, for of the “taper tantrum” in 2013 by another leg higher, as a return to normalcy committing to telegraph an end to asset seemed closer than ever. purchases far in advance, it’s hard not to However, the vaccine rollout has been view the monetary policy environment fraught, new variants continue to emerge as a catalyst for increasingly aggressive and business restrictions come and go.
    [Show full text]
  • Micro and Macroeconomics: an Introduction
    Micro and Macroeconomics: An Introduction MICROECONOMICS AND MACROECONOMICS Dr. Vijay Kumar Gupta, Assistant Professor of Economics, Women’s College, Samastipur, L.N.Mithila University, Darbhanga(Bihar) Microeconomics and macroeconomics are two approaches to economic problems and economic analysis. These terms were first coined and used by Ragnar Frisch in 1933 and have now been adopted by economists the entire world over. “Microeconomics studies the economic action of a particular individual and well defined group of individuals, i.e., household, firms industries, etc. and macroeconomics studies the broad aggregate, such as total employment, total consumption, and all industries, particular commodities.” Meaning of Microeconomics According to Boulding, “Microeconomics is the study of particular firms, particular households, individual prices, wages, incomes, individual industries, particular commodities. According to Prof. Gardener Ackley, “Microeconomics deals with the division of total output among industries, products and firms and the allocation of resources among competing groups. It considers problems of income distribution. Its interest is in relative prices of particulars goods and services,” Content Writer: Vijay Kumar Gupta Micro and Macroeconomics: An Introduction According to Prof. Lerner, “Microeconomics consists of looking at the economy through a microscope, as it were, to see how the millions of cells in the body economic- the individuals or households as consumers, and the individuals or firms as producers-play their part in the working of the whole economic organism.’ From the above definitions, it is clear that under the microeconomics we study particular economic organism; for instance, individual prices, wages or incomes; economic behaviour of individual consumers and producers, etc. Under the microeconomics, following theories are studied: 1.
    [Show full text]
  • The Return of Reflation: Time to Move?
    The Return of Reflation: Time to Move? JANUARY 2021 By Portfolio Strategies Group Snapshot Recent chatter about “reflation” may have some investors wondering just › SEI does not generally believe investors what reflation means. In economic terms, reflation refers to inflation rising should try to broadly tailor a strategic from a below-average level back toward its long-term trend. At SEI, we (long-term) portfolio to any specific typically view reflationary periods as economic regimes where both growth growth/inflation environment. and inflation are accelerating. Exhibit 1 provides a model framework that › Yet, there are times it might be prudent to highlights expected asset performance during various environments, with tilt portfolio allocations toward assets that a reflationary environment shown in the top right quadrant. In such na are expected to do well given a compelling environment, we would expect real assets like commodities and real estate view of the economic outlook. to perform well. There are some important nuances to consider, however. › SEI believes we are now at a point where Exhibit 1: Economic Regimes Tend to Favor Certain Assets such a tilt makes sense, given our view that the U.S. is likely to see stronger growth and higher inflation once the world Rising Growth / Falling Inflation Rising Growth / Rising Inflation economy is able to move beyond the Risk Premiums Real Assets Equity Commodities COVID-19 pandemic. Riskier credit Real estate Growth Falling Growth / Falling Inflation Falling Growth / Rising Inflation Duration Hedges Government Bonds Inflation-linked bonds High-quality credit High-quality short duration Inflation For illustrative purposes only.
    [Show full text]