Faculty & Research

Understanding Value Generation in Buyouts

by

A. Berg and O. Gottschalg

2003/26/SM

Working Paper Series Understanding Value Generation in Buyouts

By

Achim Berg Witten/Herdecke University, Germany and McKinsey & Company, Inc. Taunustor 2 60311 Frankfurt am Main, Germany Tel: +49 (0) 69 7162 5528 Fax: +49 (0) 69 7162 5529 [email protected]

and

Oliver Gottschalg INSEAD Department of Strategy & Management 77305 Fontainebleau, France Tel: +33 (0) 6 70 01 76 64 Fax: +33 (0) 1 60 74 55 43 [email protected]

Working Paper Comments welcome, pleased do not cite without permission.

Version 1.0 as of April 4, 2003

Achim Berg would like to thank McKinsey & Company, Inc. for its conscious support. Oliver Gottschalg would like to gratefully acknowledge financial support from the R&D Department at INSEAD and the INSEAD Gesellschaft Scholarship for the development of this research. We also wish to thank Maurizio Zollo, Nicolaus Loos, Max Scherr, and Uwe Steinbacher for their comments on earlier versions of this paper. All remaining errors or omissions are our own responsibility.

1 Understanding Value Generation in Buyouts

ABSTRACT

Buyouts have been described as a specific form of financial acquisition that leads to potentially substantial, but also highly volatile returns to investors. Previous research has illustrated a number of mechanisms through which buyouts cause increases or decreases in company value. While it is important to understand the performance impact of each of these levers individually, we are still missing a comprehensive framework that captures the full complexity of the buyout value generation process and recognizes interdependencies between various factors. In this paper, we develop a three-dimensional conceptual framework for value generation in buyouts that categorizes and links the different levers of buyouts value generation. This framework provides the basis to take a look beyond individual value levers and shed light on the underlying strategic logic of buyouts. We then review the literature on buyouts and categorize previously identified levers of value generation according to our framework. At the same time, we identify a number of levers that have received little attention in the academic literature so far or still lack convincing empirical support for their performance impact. Building upon this assessment of the status quo in research in buyouts value generation, we outline an agenda for future research.

2 INTRODUCTION

Buyouts can be defined as the purchase of a controlling stake in a company (or a division) from its owners, usually financed with a combination of equity and debt and with strong involvement of specialized financial investment companies1, the so-called buyout associations (Jensen 1989a: 372). Buyouts represent the later stage investment category of while represents the early stage (Jensen 1989a; Fenn et al. 1997;

EVCA 2000). They are archetypes of "unrelated" acquisitions as buyout associations typically manage their portfolio companies completely independent from one another (Baker &

Montgomery 1994). This form of is not motivated by potential advantages from the integration of the acquired into another entity ("synergies"), but by the intention to increase the value of the takeover target as a stand-alone business beyond the purchase price (Baker &

Smith 1998: 55).

In the last twenty years buyouts have emerged as an important field of interest for the financial community as well as for academics (Wright & Robbie 1998) and modes of value generation have always been at the forefront of interest. Researchers from fields as diverse as , strategic management, economics and entrepreneurship have looked at the issue of value generation in buyouts from their respective perspective and have identified a series of levers that contribute to acquirer returns from buyouts.3

In this paper, we provide a comprehensive overview over more than two decades of research on the factors that determine the value impact of buyouts. We identify three independent dimensions, along which levers of buyout value generation can be classified in

1 In the literature the transactions are variously labeled (e.g., leveraged buyouts, management buyouts, institutional buyout, management buyin, etc.). In this paper we prefer to call the transaction buyout, because this is the broadest term. Whenever necessary to be precise, we define the respective term while using. 2 Jensen introduces the term "LBO association" to the discussion. We prefer to use the broader term "buyout association" instead. 3 Throughout the paper we take a general and broad view on levers discussed, i.e., we do not take value generation levers into consideration that are based on very specific country characteristics. On the other hand it is also possible that some of the levers discussed are not applicable in selected countries due to special legal or tax regulations.

3 mutually exclusive and collectively exhaustive categories. Out of these three dimensions, we develop a three-dimensional framework that captures the complexity of the buyout value generation process and recognizes the differences between different levers regarding the timing of the effect, the mechanism of value creation and the relevance of specific characteristics of the equity investors. This framework enables us to understand interdependencies between individual levers and the overall process of buyout value generation. We then map levers of buyout value generation that have been previously discussed in the literature according to these three dimensions and highlight implications from our analysis for practitioners and academics.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows: the first section introduces three independent dimensions of buyout value generation and develops our three-dimensional framework accordingly. We then conduct an extensive review of the previous literature and discuss a variety of levers of value generation that have been proposed, presenting the academic discourse around individual levers whenever appropriate. Our paper concludes with an assessment of the status quo of the research on buyout value generation and outlines promising areas for future research in this domain.

A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK OF BUYOUT VALUE GENERATION4

Total value generation in buyouts is the result of a variety of value generation levers working together in a complex process. These different levers take effect during different phases of the buyout, differ in the way they cause value generation and can originate either within the target company or evolve out of the interaction between target company and equity investors. To capture this complexity, we develop a conceptual framework of buyout value

4 Several researchers who have analyzed value generation in buyouts also address the question whether returns from buyouts come from some form of "wealth transfer" from other stakeholders, such as employees, prior bondholders, prior shareholders, the tax-payers etc. (For an overview see: Palepu 1990: 252; Lehn & Poulsen 1990 202; Ippolito & James 1992: 141). We consider these questions as beyond the scope of our paper and will focus solely on how the various levers contribute to the total value generation

4 generation along three independent dimensions.

Dimension One: Phases of buyout value generation

On the most aggregate level, we can distinguish between three different phases of a buyout: acquisition phase, holding period and phase. This distinction can be made in two respects: regarding the question of when relevant value generation decisions are being taken and during which phase the value generation ultimately takes place.

The acquisition phase starts with the negotiation and due diligence process, during which the investors familiarizes themselves with the company and develop a business plan for the buyout. In the case of a , where current management participates in a buy-out along with financiers (Meulbroek 1996: 2), this is the time when the foundations are laid for the relationship between the management team that initiates the deal and the sponsoring equity investors. Probably the single most important value determinant in this phase is the of the target company and the corresponding acquisition price on which seller and acquirer agree at the end of their negotiations. This entry price sets the hurdle for all future valuations and determines the breakeven point for the equity investors. At the end of the acquisition phase, the acquirer makes important decisions regarding the structure of the buyout, such as the degree of financial leverage, the distribution of management equity stakes, the design of incentive systems, etc. It has been argued that much of the buyout value generation is

"front loaded", in that it is determined through decisions that are already taken during the acquisition phase (Baker & Montgomery 1994: 23).

It is during the subsequent holding period, that the strategic, organizational and operational changes prescribed in the initial business plan are being implemented and intended operational improvements are being realized. In practice, this is often more of an iterative than a linear process, in which the business plan is constantly updated.

5 The divestment phase constitutes the end of the buyout. It determines the divestment mode (trade sale, IPO, etc.) as well as the divestment valuation, as the final important determinant of buyout value generation. The divestment is a crucial part of the buyout, as it is during this phase that equity investors ultimately realize the returns5.

Dimension Two: Causes of buyout value generation

Value generation in buyouts has been typically analyzed from the perspective of the equity investors in buyout transactions, i.e. in terms of an appreciation of the equity value of a given business over a certain period of time6. Following simple accounting math, we can decompose the equity value of a business into four determinants: valuation multiple, revenues, margin and net debt7. This leads to the following equation:

Equity Value = Valuation Multiple * Revenues * Margin – Net Debt

Changes in equity value consequently have to be linked to a change in at least one of these four components. Based on this seemingly technical equation of determinants of value generation, we can introduce an important distinction between two basic classes of value generation.

The first type of increase in the equity value of a company is linked to changes in the valuation of the business, i.e. to the assumptions according to which the of a company is determined based on a given level of financial performance. Simply speaking, this is captured by the valuation multiple in our equation. The valuation may be partially influenced by changes in the financial performance8. On top of that, however, there are several additional

5 Here we assume that the majority of returns come from the divestment, rather than from intermediate cash flows to the equity investors during the holding period. 6 Practitioners typically evaluate value generation in buyouts based on the calculation of an "internal rate of return", which corresponds to the compounded annualized percentage increase in equity value. 7 Depending on the valuation methods used, it is possible to work with a net profit margin and a net profit multiple, an EBIT margin and EBIT multiple, EBITDA margin and EBITDA multiple, etc. 8 A company that is currently valued at nine times EBITDA and doubles EBITDA often more than doubles its value, as the improved performance often also induces an increase in the valuation multiple, say, from nine times EBITDA to eleven times EBITDA.

6 factors that can cause changes in the valuation of a company across time. Examples are changes in the market valuation multiples for comparable companies or updated expectations regarding the future financial performance (in terms of expected magnitude and variance of the returns) of a business or an entire industry. Essential for the realization of increases in the equity value of a buyout company are valuations at the time of acquisition and divestiture, which are typically the outcome of a negotiation process between the respective buyer and seller. To reflect the fact that these value increases can occur without any change in the underlying financial performance of the business, we shall hereafter refer to this type of value generation as "value capturing".

The second type of value generation is directly linked to a fundamental change in the financial performance of the target organization, i.e. either to improvements in revenues or margins or to reduced capital requirements. Such a change stems from factors such as improvements in operating performance (revenue growth, improved operating margin, etc.), reduced (optimization of , better financing terms etc.) or the freeing-up of resources through a reduction in the required fixed or current assets. Changes in financial performance have an impact on Revenues, Margin or Net Debt (or any combination of these) in our equation. We shall hereafter refer to this type of value generation as " value creation". Changes in net debt can also be related to a conscious decision to change the capital structure, i.e. changing the mix between debt and equity on the balance sheet by replacing one with the other. This does not constitute any change in company value per se and is therefore not relevant to our analysis.

Based on this technical decomposition of buyout value generation into value capturing and value creation, we can illustrate the causal dimension of buyout value generation, which consists of two levels.

We start with factors of value capturing, i.e. levers that have no direct impact on the

7 financial performance, and influence the valuation of the company with a given financial performance (i.e. the valuation multiple).

In contrast to this, the levers of value creation have a direct impact on the financial performance of the business. They can be subdivided according to a two-level generic taxonomy of value creation activities (Porter 1985: 39; Stabell & Fjaeldstad 1998: 417) into primary and secondary levers. The primary levers have a direct bottom line effect and lead to direct value generation through improvements in financial engineering, operational effectiveness and strategic distinctiveness In addition to that, we can identify two secondary levers of value creation. These levers do not have any direct impact on the financial performance or cash flow generation of a company, but enhance one or several of the primary levers of value generation. Secondary levers of value generation include factors such as reducing agency costs or support from the new equity investors. They enhance the effect of one or several primary levers. For example, an increased incentive alignment between target company management and new shareholders does not have any impact on profits or cash flow generation per se, but may help to remove operational inefficiencies or to achieve a better strategic positioning (see Figure 1).

.

8

Value Value Generation Value Creation Capturing in Buyouts Primary Levers

Value Creation Secondary Levers

FIGURE 1: Value generation in buyouts

Dimension Three: Sources of buyout value generation

Different types of buyout value generation can be distinguished according the degree to which they depend on specific characteristics of the equity investors involved in the buyout.

On the one extreme of this dimension, we find value generation that occurs entirely within the boundaries of the portfolio company and that would occur in any buyout context independent of specific characteristics of the equity investors. One example for such "intrinsic value generation" would be value generation through improvements in operational efficiency that were achieved without any form of knowledge transfer from the equity investors. On the other extreme, we have value generation that is inherently linked to specific characteristics of the equity investors (network, expertise, experience, capability, strategy, etc.) and that occurs through an interaction between the portfolio company and the equity investors. An example for

9 such "extrinsic value generation" would be a specific expertise of the equity investors leading to value creation through improvements in the financial performance of the portfolio company that would not have been possible with the skills previously available at the portfolio company itself. Levers of extrinsic value generation are comparable with the effects of a "parenting advantage” that business units may enjoy as part of a multibusiness company (Goold et al.

1994). Clearly, these two extreme cases mark a continuum and many types of value generation fall between the polar ends of this dimension.

CATEGORIZING LEVERS OF BUYOUT VALUE GENERATION

More than two decades of research on buyouts has lead to a number of propositions regarding possible levers of buyout value generation. Many of those are today widely accepted as crucial ingredients of successful buyout transaction. What we have been missing so far is a comprehensive view on these various levers that enables us to go beyond the analysis of each individual factor and helps us understand the underlying mechanics of buyout value generation.

In the following passage, we will revisit the levers of buyout value generation that have been proposed in the literature and categorize them along the three dimensions of our conceptual framework.

Levers of value capturing

Financial arbitrage The first important group of levers of buyout value generation that has received substantial attention in the literature can be classified as financial arbitrage, i.e., the ability to generate returns from differences in the valuation applied to a company between acquisition and divestment independent of changes in the underlying financial performance of the business

("buy low - sell high strategy"). The valuation rationale for a company depends on the market

10 valuation multiples for comparable companies, private information and differential expectations regarding the future financial performance of a business or an entire industry and the negotiation process through which buyer and seller agree on the valuation. Financial arbitrage based on any of those four factors may be a source of value generation in buyouts.

Financial arbitrage based on changes in market valuation

First of all, returns to equity investors in buyouts may be influenced by changes in the public market valuation multiples for comparable companies. To the extent that the valuation of the business at acquisition and divestment is correlated with the change in public market valuation multiples, equity investors may benefit or suffer from this exogenous effect. In some cases, buyout investors are able to successfully arbitrage within private markets or between private and public markets and vice versa or to more accurately predict the future evolution of public market valuation multiples than their counterparts in the valuation negotiation and benefit accordingly. This type of financial arbitrage has received surprisingly little attention in the academic literature so far, even though it is often mentioned by practitioners ("multiple riding"). It does not cause any changes in the financial performance of the portfolio company and consequently constitutes a case of value capturing. It is extrinsic to the portfolio company, in that it largely depends on characteristics of the buyout investors and is determined exclusively during the acquisition and divestment phases.

The valuation of a business is typically also based on expectations regarding magnitude and volatility of its future financial performance, so information about the future development of the business play a crucial role in the valuation process. Information asymmetries between the equity investors and their counterparts in the valuation negotiation can consequently be another source of financial arbitrage. In general, we can distinguish between two different

11 types of information asymmetry: an informational advantage because of insider information and because of a unique expertise in an industry. Both of these can be a source of value capturing.

Financial arbitrage based on private information about the portfolio company

Early on, it has been argued that insider information could be an important value lever in buyout transactions (DeAngelo et al. 1984: 367; Lowenstein 1985: 740; Wright & Coyne

1985; DeAngelo 1986: 400; Jensen 1989a: 40; Lehn & Poulsen 1989: 773; Opler 1992: 33), especially in management buyouts (MBOs) where the incumbent management is part of the equity investors and can take direct advantage of their information advantage vis-a-vis the previous owners through an equity participation in the transaction.

It has been argued that an opportunistic management team could take advantage of private information on the future development of the company (Ofek 1994: 638). In the extreme they could even depress or manipulate reported or forecasted earnings9 (Lowenstein

1985: 740; DeAngelo 1986: 402; Hite & Vetsuypens 1989: 959) to lower the acquisition price, i.e., to buy a company for less than a similarly informed bidder would be willing to pay, and informed owners would be willing to accept (Kaplan 1989b: 218). In this case vendor's shareholders may be considered to have experienced a loss if the transaction allows managers to exploit their private information (Palepu 1990: 253; Thompson et al. 1992: 64).

While it is imaginable that severe under-pricing may have been frequent in the early years of buyout growth (Wright & Coyne 1985), subsequent observations on buyout performance should have alerted later vendors to the need to anticipate gains and to price

9 See Lowenstein (1985: 740) for a detailed description of possible insiders' techniques intended to directly or indirectly depress the price of a company (e.g., cutting the dividend or increase it less than the market expects; officers decline to meet with security analysts, thus withholding the kind of detailed information and access to senior officers without which analysts and investment advisors do not feel comfortable; accelerate investment in long term projects for a period of time, thereby reducing reported earnings without affecting intrinsic or enterprise value)

12 accordingly (Thompson et al. 1992: 65). Furthermore it seems unlikely that managers of buyout targets have systematically hidden information about earnings and prospects and have been able to monopolize the bidding (Lowenstein 1985: 741; Palepu 1990: 251; Singh 1990:

112). Acquisitions usually underlie extensive disclosure requirements (Lee 1992: 1062) and need to be evaluated by independent committees of the board of directors and not only by the managers themselves (Magowan 1989: 17; Palepu 1990: 250; KKR 1989: 69). Additionally, the increase in buyout activity, the associated professionalization of vendors, and the increased activity of security analysts, as well as the establishment of open auctions as de-facto standard selling process (Jensen 1989b: 71; Wright & Robbie 1996: 700; Indahl & Zinterhofer 1998: 4;

Wright et al. 2001: 122) should have minimized the importance of insider information as source of value capturing. Therefore, we come to the same conclusion as Singh (1990: 115), that "the pure managerial opportunism argument implies a higher level of manipulation of superior information by management teams than is feasible in a competitive acquisition environment".

Additionally, it should be kept in mind that only one special type of buyouts, the management buyout, allows the exploitation of this kind of informational advantage (Long &

Ravenscraft 1993a: 19) and that other types of buyout transactions like management buyins or institutional buyouts have gained increasing importance in recent years (Wright & Robbie

1996: 700; Indahl & Zinterhofer 1998: 5).

However, while private information may not be the sole or dominant reason for buyout transactions, favourable inside information are likely to be a motivation for managers to propose an MBO (Lee 1992: 1063).

To our knowledge, another type of financial arbitrage through information asymmetries has not received any attention in the literature so far. Value capturing is also possible through

13 the exploitation of information advantages during the divestment phase, namely in cases where the post-buyout acquirer holds more advantageous believes regarding the expected financial performance of the portfolio company than the (better informed) selling buyout investors. Such information asymmetries may occur with or without some form of intentional "window dressing" by the selling party.

Financial arbitrage based on the exploitation of private information of the portfolio company management team does not fundamentally impact the financial performance of the business and thus also belongs to the class of value capturing. It is extrinsic to the portfolio company, as it is linked to the specific characteristics of the equity investors (which includes the initiating management team in case of an MBO). It can take place during either the acquisition or the divestment phase.

Financial arbitrage through superior market information

Financial arbitrage through information asymmetries does not necessarily depend on private information, but may also be a result of a unique expertise in assessing the value of a business based on market intelligence. Buyout associations are known for their extensive organisational and people networks. Their constant contact with a wide range of companies and top managers allows them to build up a significant industry expertise (Anders 1992: 80). This provides them with access to superior market information as well as the ability to interpret them in a way that gives them a competitive advantage over the average market participant.

(Fox & Marcus 1992). Like all other cases of financial arbitrage, such value generation is a case of value capturing. It is extrinsic to the portfolio company as it depends on a specific expertise of the buyout investors and can happen during the acquisition or the divestment phase.

14 Financial arbitrage through superior dealmaking capabilities

Financial arbitrage can also be linked to distinct capabilities in "deal making", i.e. the ability to identify suitable acquisition targets, limit the competition from other potential buyers and manage the negotiation and acquisition processes (Wright & Robbie 1996: 700; Baker &

Smith 1998: 26). Large and well-established buyout associations conduct regular and systematic reviews of the market for potential buyout candidates, and at the same time obtain useful information about various industries' developments (Anders 1992: 82). Often, these companies are part of a network that allows privileged access to transactions ("proprietary ") (Wright & Robbie 1996: 700).

The limitation of competition from other potential buyout or strategic investors for the target company has a strong impact on the resulting acquisition price. Whereas in exclusive negotiations, buyer and seller will agree on a acquisition price somewhere between their respective valuations of the company, competition tends to bid up the acquisition prices to the valuation of the second-highest bidder, reducing the value that can be captured by the winning party to their unique value generation potential (Barney 1988). Similarly, buyout associations can leverage their network to optimize their exit strategy for the portfolio company, either through the identification of a suitable buyer or through the preparation of a .

Again, the ability to make an exit mode possible that leads to the highest valuation for the business, contributes to the value generation for the buyout investors.

In addition, buyout associations approach potential acquisition targets with sensitivity and are perceived as excellent and tough negotiators that are willing and able to adjust their negotiation postures and objectives as a deal evolves (Butler 2001: 143).

Financial arbitrage due to deal making and negotiation skills is a case of value capturing, which is exogenous to the portfolio company and can take place during both acquisition and divestment phase.

15

Financial arbitrage through an optimisation of corporate scope

Sophisticated buyout investors are able to identify and exploit the so-called effect, taking advantage of the fact that a multi-unit company may be less valuable as a whole than divided into pieces. Through the sale of peripheral undervalued businesses ("asset stripping"), buyout investors remove the conglomerate discount and benefit from the appreciation in the value of their assets (Magowan 1989: 12). This technique has been widely applied during the early days of buyout growth in the United States (Singh 1993: 158).

Financial arbitrage through an optimisation of corporate scope is a case of value capturing, which is exogenous to the portfolio company and can take place during all three phases of the buyout process.

Levers of value creation: Primary levers

While financial arbitrage leads to value capturing without improvements in financial performance of the portfolio company, other levers of value generation improve the financial performance and generate real gains in the value of the acquired company (Kitching 1989: 74).

They trigger a corporate restructuring process leading to significant and rapid changes in the firm's capital structure, assets and organizational structure and the corporate governance regime (Lichtenberg & Siegel 1990: 166; Singh 1993: 147; Lei & Hitt 1995). Company's objectives get revised and have in turn important consequences for the operating and strategic decisions of the firm. (Seth & Easterwood 1993: 251) In line with the second dimension

"causes of buyout value generation" from our framework, we will first concentrate on primary levers of value creation that are directly linked to such improvements in financial engineering, operational effectiveness or strategic distinctiveness.

16 Financial engineering Financial engineering, i.e. the optimisation of capital structure and minimization of after-tax cost of capital of the portfolio company is one of the most widely acknowledged levers applied by buyout associations to create value.

Optimizing the capital structure

Buyout associations possess intimate knowledge of capital market mechanisms and capitalize on their financial expertise in the buyout (Anders 1992: 85). They typically assist the management in negotiating bank loans, bond , initial public offerings, and subsequent sales. They leverage their excellent contacts in the financial community negotiating terms that the portfolio company would not have been able to get on a stand-alone basis (Magowan 1989: 15). The reduction of the marginal agency costs of debt financing is possible, because buyout associations have long-term relationships with institutional lenders - consequently, the new equity owners have reduced incentives to transfer wealth from lenders

(DeAngelo et al. 1984: 373). Buyout specialists are likely to be repeat players in the LBO debt market; with their reputations as "good" borrowers at stake, lenders are likely to deal with them at easier terms (Baker & Smith 1998: 56; Cotter & Peck 2001: 103).

The application of their financial engineering skills helps a company to improve its complex capital structure and to find an optimal mix between debt and equity (Anders

1992:80). This of leads to an increase in debt, hence the common term "".

Reducing corporate tax

Corporate tax savings as a consequence of increased leverage have also been identified as important sources of value creation in buyout transactions (Lowenstein 1985: 731; Bull

1989: 277; Kaplan 1989a: 611; Leland 1989: 20; Singh 1990: 115; Smith 1990b: 21; Long &

Ravenscraft 1993c: 215). The increase in debt makes high tax-deductible interest payments

17 necessary and provides a with a positive impact on cash flows10 (Kaplan 1989a: 611;

Singh 1990: 115). Similarly, the step-up in book value of purchased assets and the subsequent application of more accelerated depreciation procedures may have value increasing effects as well (Bull 1989: 265; Kaplan 1989a: 611; Smith 1990b: 21; Baker & Smith 1998: 70). In many countries, however, tax reforms have removed many of these benefits (KKR 1989: 66;

Newbould et al. 1992: 56; Baker & Smith 1998: 147) in recent years.

Other researchers argue that the cost of capital is more or less independent of leverage, since the tax advantage of a high level of debt is almost entirely offset by the higher cost of that debt (Long & Ravenscraft 1993a: 12; Opler & Titman 1998: 1998; Samdani et al. 2001: 99).

Or as Rappaport (1990: 102)11 puts it: "borrowing per se creates no value other than tax benefits. Value comes from the operational efficiencies debt inspires"12.

Financial engineering has direct impact on the bottom line of the portfolio company and thus represents a primary lever of value creation. To a large extent, it is extrinsic to the portfolio company, as expertise and reputation of the equity investors play a major role in the minimization of cost of capital. The financial structure is largely determined during the acquisition phase, but financial engineering may continue to play a role during the holding period.

While financial engineering was identified early on as a lever to create value in buyout transactions it took longer until buyout associations broadly acknowledged the need to focus on adding value by helping portfolio firms with their operations and strategy (Indahl &

Zinterhofer 1998). As the markets mature and become increasingly competitive buyout

10 The value creating impact of tax shields differs across countries and across time depending on tax regulations. 11 See Baker & Smith (1998: XII) for a comparable argumentation. 12 This effect will be discussed in more detail in the section on "Increasing opertional effectiveness".

18 associations realise that they need to find ways to add value to their portfolio companies beyond financial engineering (Baker & Smith 1998).

Increasing operational effectiveness While financial engineering focuses on capital structure and cost of capital, increasing operational effectiveness has an impact on the left side of the balance sheet, operating margins and cash flow. It is achieved through measures that enhance overall productivity and effectiveness of operations. While the strategic positioning of the company remains unchanged, the configuration of a company's resources, i.e. how the different available resources are put to work, are being readjusted. In this process, the quantities of individual resources may be changed and single resources may be exchanged. A substantial literature has developed that shows that buyout transactions have a positive effect on the operational performance of target companies13 (Bull 1989; Baker & Wruck 1989; Kaplan 1989b: 250; Lichtenberg & Siegel

1990: 191; Muscarella & Vetsuypens 1990: 1398; Singh 1990: 124; Smith 1990a: 162; Opler

1992: 33; Long & Ravenscraft 1993a: 23, 1993c: 214; Ofek 1994: 639; Phan & Hill 1995: 732;

Smart & Waldfogel 1995: 503; Holthausen & Larcker 1996; Weir & Laing 1998: 268; Harris et al. 2002: 15).14 We can distinguish between measures that increase operational effectiveness due to cost-cutting and margin improvements, reduce capital requirements or the removal of managerial inefficiencies.

Cost-cutting and margin improvements

Buyouts often substantially change in the way the operations are organized and managed in the target company, with the goal to reduce cost and improve margins (Muscarella

13 The motivations of the managers to implement operational changes will be ignored for a moment (they will be discussed as part of the secondary levers) we will focus on the activities and measures that lead to the improvements in operational effectiveness. 14 See Palepu (1990) for an overview on the early literature until 1990.

19 & Vetsuypens 1990: 1396; Wright et al. 2001: 116). After the acquisition the management immediately starts to tighten the control on corporate spending (Kaplan 1989: 250; Magowan

1989: 12; Anders 1992: 84; Holthausen & Larcker 1996: 296) and initiates a series of cost reduction programs (Muscarella & Vetsuypens 1990: 1398; Baker 1992: 1106). A variety of activities leads to a reduction in production cost and significantly increase plant productivity

(Lichtenberg & Siegel 1990: 191; Muscarella & Vetsuypens 1990: 1397; Harris et al. 2002:

15). In this context, the impact of buyouts on R&D expenses have received particular attention.

Findings tend to the contradictory, as a number of researchers (e.g., Hall 1990; Smith 1990b:

23; Long & Ravenscraft 1993b: 132, 1993c: 221; Hoskisson & Hitt 1994: 115) report a reduction of R&D expenses after the buyout. Other studies (e.g., KKR 1989: 67; Bull 1989;

Lichtenberg & Siegel 1990: 193) failed to support the corresponding hypothesis (see Zahra &

Fescina (1991: 10) for an overview).

Besides that, the reduction of overheads (e.g., corporate center) plays a key role in achieving higher overall efficiency. Buyout companies typically develop a less bureaucratic structure with decreased corporate overhead cost (Easterwood et al. 1989: 41; Butler 2001: 99;

Samdani et al. 2001: 99).

Reducing capital requirements

In addition to taking out unnecessary costs it is quite common to increase capital productivity and/or reduce capital requirements of the business. One common way to achieve this is to make more efficient use of existing corporate assets (Lowenstein 1985: 749; Bull

1989: 264; Baker & Smith 1998: 122), i.e., to rationalize corporate operations, for example through an improved management of working capital (Baker & Wruck 1989; Smith 1990a:

143; Kester & Luehrman 1995: 120; Samdani et al. 2001: 99). Inventory control and accounts receivable management are tightened and professionalized (Magowan 1989: 12; Singh 1990:

20 123; Long & Ravenscraft 1993c: 219) This leads to sharply reduced levels of inventory and receivables compared to pre-buyout levels (Easterwood et al. 1989: 42). Holthausen & Larcker

(1996: 296) found that post-buyout firms have, on average, significantly smaller amounts of working capital than their industry counterparts.

At the same time, the company adopts stricter regimes regarding capital expenditure that cut unsound investment programns and lead to the divestment of unnecessary or underutilized assets (Magowan 1989: 12; Phan & Hill 1995: 706). This leads to a consolidation and reorganization of production facilities and an increase in operational performance and total factor productivity on the one hand and additional cash flow to pay down debt on the other hand (Seth & Easterwood 1993: 251; KKR 1989: 68).

Is important to keep in mind, however, that all these organizational changes need to be such that they do not negatively affect the company's ability to compete in the market place

(Easterwood et al. 1989: 41). It should also be mentioned that the generally increased efficiency and tighter cost control, which has developed in many corporations over the last decade, might mean that the scope for obtaining significant short-term benefits from restructuring is more limited. (Wright & Robbie 1996: 701)

Removing managerial inefficiencies

Buyouts also often lead to improvements in operational effectiveness through the replacement of inefficient management teams (Anders 1992: 81). Following the logic of the market for corporate control (Manne 1965), poor performance may be the result of inefficient management teams. Buyouts has been proposed as a vehicle to takeover companies with inefficient management teams for a valuation based on their poor performance and change the management team and thus remove these cause for this type of underperformance (Jensen &

21 Ruback 1983)15. Buyout investors can then benefit from the appreciation in company value due to the performance increase.

Increased operational effectiveness has a direct impact on both profitability and cash flow of the portfolio company. It is typically the result of a combination of intrinsic and extrinsic factors. While some of the decisions to enhance operational effectiveness may have already been embedded in the business plan that was developed during the acquisition base, most of these measures will only take effect during the holding period.

Increasing strategic distinctiveness Buyouts can create value and improve performance beyond the increase of operational efficiency. Often, they lead to a redefinition of key strategic variables such as which markets to be in and with which products to compete and they conduct changes in pricing, product quality, customer service and customer mix as well as on the reorganization of distribution channels.

This often goes along with a substantial change in the resource base of the company. Two common approaches to increase strategic distinctiveness that have been observed in buyouts are a refocusing on core activities and the execution of a buy-and-build strategy.

Corporate refocusing

Often buyouts lead to a corporate refocusing (Seth & Easterwood 1993: 251), along with a overall reduction of complexity (Phan & Hill 1995: 732). Through a reduction of the number and degree of diversity of different activities and the removal of inefficient cross- subsidies between different product lines (Liebeskind et al. 1992: 75; Wiersema & Liebeskind

1995: 449), the portfolio company refocuses on its core business. Activities which are

15 The case where buyout investors partner with an outside management team to gain control over a company and then replace the previous management team, have been termed "Management Buy-In (MBI)“.

22 peripheral (from a strategic point of view) or not a competitive advantage for the company are often sold to another party that can make better use of it (Muscarella & Vetsuypens 1990:

1397; Hoskisson & Turk 1990: 472; Singh 1990: 114, 1993: 158; Anders 1992: 83; Baker

1992; Seth & Easterwood 1993: 251; Baker & Smith 1998: 98)16. In general, resources allocation prioritizes projects, which are essential to maintaining or enhancing competitive advantage (Easterwood et al. 1989: 39).

It has been argued, however that the times when buyouts could be viewed as solely emphasizing downside efficiencies are over (Wright et al. 2001: 123). A successful exit of a buyout via trade sale or often requires a history of strong growth (Butler

2001: 143). The these companies to either pursue internal growth strategies and to actively strive for promising innovations (Markides 1997, 1998: 32; Wright et al. 2001: 114), or to CE external growth through acquisitions of new lines of business an expansion of business scope in areas where distinctive competences and resources are significant compared to the competition (Easterwood et al. 1989: 39; Liebeskind et al. 1992: 76; Seth & Easterwood 1993:

251; Wiersema & Liebeskind 1995: 449).

Buy and build strategies

Some buyout transactions are intended from the beginning to accomplish a so-called

"buy and build" strategy. In these cases buyout associations undertake an initial buyout investment in a fragmented and/or sub-scale market to build a nucleus (Samdani et al. 2001:

105). This nucleus than gets provided with cash, leverage and know how to undertake a couple of subsequent acquisitions that lead to a consolidation in that market segment (Seth &

16 We need to distinguish between "asset stripping" strategies, which have been treated as a case of financial arbitrage through and optimization of corporate scope, and the reduction of scope of activities to increase strategic distinctiveness. Asset stripping occurs on the corporate level and concerns the sale of entire business units, whereas the reduction of scope of activities happens on the business in level when, for example, the reduction of a certain component is been outsourced and the corresponding facility shut down or divested.

23 Easterwood 1993: 260; Baker & Montgomery 1994: 26; Allen 1999: 770; Wright et al. 2001:

117). Such a strategy aims at establishing a dominant market position and to capture economies of scale.

Improved strategic distinctiveness also a clear impact on the financial performance of the portfolio company and qualifies therefore as value creation. It is often achieved through an interaction between buyout investors and portfolio company and is thus partly intrinsic and partly extrinsic. While the overall strategic plan may be set during the acquisition phase already, its implementation happens during the holding period.

The previous passage has made clear, that buyouts create value through a variety of different levers. The important question remains, however, why companies are able to pull these levers value creation in a buyout context and have not been able to do so before the buyout. The following description of secondary levers of buyouts value creation addresses this point and highlights a number of reasons why in many cases the buyout events itself or the active equity investors facilitate or enhance the application of our primary value creation levers.

Levers of value creation: Secondary levers

We have to remember that secondary levers of value creation do not have a direct impact on financial performance, but influence value creation through primary levers. We can distinguish the secondary levers into one category related to the reduction of agency costs and a second category that is linked to a so-called parenting advantage.

24 Reducing agency costs The most prominent and exhaustively described value creation lever in buyouts is the reduction of agency costs (Wright et al. 2001: 112). It should be kept in mind that a reduction of agency cost, as a secondary lever of value creation, has no direct effect to the bottom line, as even the mere absence of agency costs does not guarantee business success (Bull 1989: 277).

But the mechanisms leading to reduction of the agency conflict can support the three previously described primary levers.

The magnitude of the agency problem in an organization depends on the degree of discretion in managerial decisions, the degree of disalignment in incentives between managers and owners and the degree to which a deviation from shareholder-wealth-maximizing decisions can be observed and sanctioned (Berle & Means 1932; Manne 1962, 1966; Ross 1973; Fama

1980; Jensen & Meckling 1976, Fama & Jensen 1983; Jensen 1986, 1989b). Research has shown that agency conflicts are highly relevant in the buyout context (Opler & Titman 1993:

1996). The changes in organizational structure and ownership that become possible in a buyout transaction allow to take advantage of agency costs reduction mechanisms and subsequently lead to an improved firm's operating performance (Kaplan 1989b: 220; Lehn & Poulsen 1989:

773; Smith 1990: 144). Buyouts potentially influence all three factors and can thus reduce the agency problem significantly.

Reducing agency costs of

First of all, the increased level of debt we find in many buyouts (so-called "leveraged buyouts") plays a crucial role in the limitation of managerial discretion in buyouts. Jensen

(1986: 323, 1989a, 1989b) emphasized that debt used to finance the buyout helps to limit the waste of free cash flow by compelling managers to service debt payments rather than spend it

25 inefficiently within the firm. It reduces managers' discretion over corporate expenditures17

(Grossman & Hart 1982; Smith 1990a: 140) and limits possible non-value maximizing behaviour (Newbould et al. 1992: 50). The debt burden forces managers to efficiently run the company to avoid default (Lowenstein 1985: 757; Jensen 1986; Allen 1999: 710; Cotter &

Peck 2001: 102).

Bancruptcy is costly for managers, as they lose benefits of control or reputation

(Grossman and Hart 1982). Consequently, high leverage and increased default risk can create an incentive for managers to work harder, consume fewer perquisites and make better investment decisions, as such behaviour reduces the probability of bankruptcy.

Another positive effect of debt is the additional outsourced governance. Financial lenders have strong incentives to monitor the managements' actions and to make sure that the company is able to fulfil its duties.18 The debt covenants and repayment requirements serve as a sort of operating budget for the buyout company (Baker & Montgomery 1994: 20) and provide clear constraints for the management (Baker & Wruck 1989; Lichtenberg & Siegel

1990: 166).

But it should be mentioned that high leverage in finance can have downsides for a company as well. Unforeseen shocks (e.g., increase in interest rates, shortfall in demand) can result in a dramatic corporate failure (Singh 1990: 126; Rappaport 1990: 97; Singh 1993: 157).

Therefore the ability of the buyout investors to quickly intervene and provide support in such situations can be of superior importance19. Furthermore, the increased financial leverage can make a firm short-term oriented because of its vulnerability to financial distress, leading to a decline in competitiveness (Palepu 1990: 248; Gifford 2001: 18). Rappaport (1990: 97) argued that modern competition "requires the financial flexibility of a public company not burdened

17 A number of empirical studies have shown that expenditures decline following a leveraged buyout (Bull 1989; Kaplan 1989b; Kitching 1989; Muscarella & Vetsuypens 1990; Smith 1990a). 18 Thompson et al. (1992) argued that institutions supplying debt and loan finance have a comparative advantage in monitoring a company because of their long experience in that matter.

26 with exraordinary debt". In addition, leverage could affect project selection by managers due to managerial risk aversion: high leverage could cause risk-averse managers to alter their investment decisions in such way as to decrease the risk of the assets of the firm in order to reduce the likelihood of default (Holthausen & Larcker 1996: 295)20.

Improving incentive alignment

Buyouts also increase the incentive alignment between shareholders and managers through a combination of a "carrot" and a "stick" mechanism (Jensen 1986: 326, 1989b: 64;

Coller & Peck 2001: 102). Buyout associations provide incentives (the "carrot") in order to align the interests of all parties involved and to reduce the agency conflict after the buyout

(Jensen 1989b; Bull 1989: 264; Lichtenberg & Siegel 1990: 166). Managers are encouraged (if not forced) to increase their share in equity ownership in the company to a significant level

(Muscarella & Vetsuypens 1990: 1393; Baker & Montgomery 1994: 16).21 It is expected that this increase in the equity stake of the management directly increases the personal costs of inefficiency (Smith 1990b: 21) and reduces their incentive to shirk (Jensen & Meckling 1976;

DeAngelo et al. 1984: 372; Hite & Vetsuypens 1989: 955; Smith 1990a: 144; Weir & Laing

1998: 262).

Furthermore, the change in status, from manager to co-owner could increase financial performance because it gives managers a positive incentive to look for efficiency gains and smart strategic moves (Phan & Hill 1995: 706; Weir & Laing 1998: 261). Their equity participation gives them a greater stake in any value-increasing actions that are taken (e.g.,

19 This support is a secondary lever of value creation that will be discussed in a following section. 20 It has been argued that an emphasis on financial controls induces managerial risk aversion (see Lei & Hitt (1995: 847) for an overview) as well. 21 Managers get usually offered a substantial stake in the equity of the company to favourable conditions ("sweet equity"). But due to the high amount of the total investment compared to their personal net worth, managers usually have to take big financial risks to participate in the buyout ("pain equity") (Kitching 1989: 75; Thompson et al. 1992: 63; Baker & Smith 1998: 57; Beaver 2001: 308; Samdani et al. 2001: 100).

27 Jensen & Meckling 1976) and leads therefore to better operating and investment decisions

(Easterwood et al. 1989: 40; Palepu 1990: 248)22. Another motivational side effect of the construction is that management finds themselves with a substantial undiversifiable equity investment and their specific human capital locked into the company. This double lock-in (“the stick”) should give them a strong motivation to safeguard their position (Thompson et al. 1992:

63).

On the other hand increased managerial ownership in equity can result in a decrease in financial performance due to managerial risk aversion and the potential under-diversification of the managers' wealth (Fama & Jensen 1985; Morck et al. 1988; Holthausen & Larcker

1996:295). Demsetz (1983) and Fama and Jensen (1983) argue that if managerial equity ownership is concentrated, the manager may have effective control over the organization and disciplining mechanisms such as the market for corporate control and managerial labour markets may be rendered ineffective, that could result in a decline in performance as well.

(Holthausen & Larcker 1996: 295).

In addition to an increased equity ownership of the top management, buyout associations increase the sensitivity of pay-to-performance for a large number of employees in the company (Jensen 1989a: 39, 1989b; Anders 1992: 80; Fox & Marcus 1992: 76).

Motivational systems get installed and employee contracts get changed in a way that motivates to achieve key tasks and includes changes in the way employees get evaluated and compensated (Easterwood et al. 1989: 41; Baker & Wruck 1989: 176; Muscarella &

Vetsuypens 1990: 1396). These additional incentives are not necessarily restricted to those at the peak tier of authority. Buyouts may introduce employee share ownership plans or other

22 The equity owned by management in the LBO companies is generally illiquid. However, because of the requirement that the LBO association liquidate the within a fairly short time period (10 years or less) there is a guarantee that the company will be valued, in a third-party transaction, at some point in the relatively near future. This guarantee of future liquidity, and of an object and unbiased valuation event, is crucial to the incentives provided by management equity ownership (Baker & Montgomery 1994: 21).

28 shareholdings schemes and sometimes involve participation programmes. (Thompson et al.

1992: 63)

Support for the view that incentives help to reduce managerial opportunism comes from Wright et al. (1994: 38) who empirically showed that incentives were negatively related to MBO failure.

Improving monitoring and controlling

Finally, buyouts change the governance structure in a way that increases the possibilities to reduces the agency conflict through monitoring and controlling of the company management (Hite & Vetsuypens 1989: 956; Singh 1990: 112). The greater concentration of equity in the hands of active investors encourages closer monitoring and leads to a more active representation in the board of directors (DeAngelo et al. 1984: 373; Jensen 1989a, 1989b;

Smith 1990a: 144). The involvement in the monitoring of management as members of the board offers the chance to get direct access to confidential company information. This eases the oversight over ongoing operations as well as the evaluation of longer-term strategies. Portfolio companies' management gets continously evaluated through an ongoing process of control

(Palepu 1990: 247; Anders 1992: 84; Cotter & Peck 2001: 101).

Buyout specialists are professional active investors that are likely to have a comparative advantage over third party equity investors in monitoring managers of post-buyout organization (DeAngelo et al. 1984: 373; KKR 1989: 68; Jensen 1989a: 36; Cotter & Peck

2001: 103). Their involvement in a large number of buyout investments improves their skills in monitoring.

The reduction of the agency conflict through these mechanisms is a critical determinant of several of the factors previously discussed as primary levers value creation. Agency

29 problems create inefficiencies, especially regarding improved operational effectiveness and strategic distinctiveness. The improved agency relationship after the buyout removes these inefficiencies and motivates management to pull the necessary levers value creation to maximize the value of the company. This includes taking even unpopular and difficult decisions like cutting jobs and disposing businesses as well (Butler 2001: 143). The different factors that contribute to a reduction of agency costs are all secondary levers of value generation. They are largely predetermined during the acquisition phase, even though the actual value creation effect only happens during the holding period. While the effect of increased leverage is independent of specific characteristics of the equity investors and thus intrinsic to the portfolio company, monitoring and controlling as well as the interest alignment depends on specific capabilities of the equity investors.

The parenting effect The last lever we describe is the so-called parenting advantage. Similar to the effect of being part of a certain corporation for a specific business unit that has been identified in research on conglomerates (Goold et al. 1994), buyout associations can have an important impact on the value creation in the various buyout businesses of their "family". Even though buyout associations differ in the degree to which they are involved and management of the portfolio company, they support the value creation in their portfolio companies in various ways.

Restoring the entrepreneurial spirit

In many cases, companies that are acquired in buyouts suffer from a lack of entrepreneurial spirit. The reasons for this are manifold and include cases where non-core units of large corporations did not receive the necessary attention or resources from corporate headquarters to pursue innovative strategies or where risk-version led to an unfavourable

30 climate for entrepreneurial activities. Buyout associations can contribute to the restoration of an entrepreneurial climate, by giving the management of portfolio companies sufficient freedom to develop and realize innovative ideas. The new institutional structure and changed governance and interaction modes makes managers of post-buyout companies feel released from corporate bureaucracy and of central importance23 (Lowenstein 1985: 756; Jensen 1989a:

39; Hoskisson & Turk 1990: 472; Butler 2001: 144; Wright et al. 2001: 118), as many buyout associations reduce their interference with day-to-day operational issues to a minimum, as long as financial targets are met. Portfolio company managers feel and act as entrepreneurs in their organizations, freed from the constraints of a corporate centre and encouraged to make independent decisions (Bull 1989: 277; Jensen 1989a: 39; Singh 1990: 112; Houlden 1990: 74;

Kester & Luehrman 1995: 120; Weir 1996: 25; Bruining & Wright 2002: 147). Researchers describe this effect as "LBO fever" or "adrenalin": energized and highly motivated management teams are willing to take nearly any action to make their buyout a success

(Houlden 1990: 74; Beaver 2001: 308; Samdani et al. 2001: 101)24.

Advising and enabling

Another positive effect of belonging to a particular buyout associations as the "parent company" can come from the constructive interaction between portfolio company managers and their counterparts in the buyout associations, which is often facilitated through direct and unbureaucratic communication channels (Kester & Luehrman 1995: 123). While the investment managers in the buyout associations typically stay free of the day-to-day operations,they are still much closer to operations and management than conglomerate

23 Wright et al (2001: 118) highlighted that managers of pre-buyout organizations are discouraged if their divisions provided profitable and innovative investment opportunities but where limited in their discretion because of the fact that the division was not regarded central to the parent organization (see also Weir 1996: 25; Beaver 2001: 307). 24 The motivational effect of incentive systems that has been discussed in the section on agency cost certainly also contributes to this phenomenon.

31 headquarters or the board of directors in traditional organizations (Bull 1989: 271; Hite &

Vetsuypens 1989: 955; Anders 1992: 82).

At the same time, buyout associations are known for their ability to produce "stretch budgets" (Anders 1992: 84; Baker & Montgomery 1994: 22; Butler 2001: 143) and to, in general, raise the standards for management performance. By increasing the minimum level of acceptable performance managers are forced to work harder after the buyout or they risk losing their jobs (Baker & Wruck 1989: 176, Magowan 1989: 14). They also spend a serious amount of time on selecting the top management team after the buyout25 and they usually do not hesitate to replace it if corporate performance should falter (Anders 1992: 81). Overall, target setting is much more aspirational in buyouts. It is not surprising that they expect, for example, the business to double EBITDA in five years time (Butler 2001: 146).

Furthermore, buyout sponsors understand their role vis-a-vis the portfolio company management as active advisors and enablers. Usually, the lead representative of the buyout association serves as the top management's sounding board on both day-to-day operations and long-term decisions and provides additional perspectives on, and knowledge of, strategy, markets and external conditions (Sapienza & Timmons 1989: 77; Houlden 1990: 74; Kester &

Luehrman 1995: 123; Baker & Wruck 1989: 183; Bruining & Wright 2002: 165). The buyout specialists bring to the new unit additional management expertise and industry experience acquired in previous transactions in which they participated, which constitutes a case of knowledge transfer from the new owners to the target company (Baker & Smith 1998: 171).

This "cross-utilization" of managerial talent can represent a valuable and not otherwise readily available resource to the buyout company. (Hite & Vetsuypens 1989: 956). Another source of value added through the buyout association comes from their network of contacts in various industries and especially in the financial and consulting markets that can be exploited to the

25 This team can be composed of previous managers of the buyout company or of outside managers.

32 benefit of the buyout (Baker & Smith 1998: 174; Bruining & Wright 2002: 165). Be it to find a business partner, to recruit a new manager for the portfolio company or to identify potential targets for the buy-and-build strategy, contacts of the buyout association may be an important success factor for the portfolio company.

The parenting effect represents a secondary lever of value creation. Advising and enabling are inherently linked to characteristics of the equity investors and thus extrinsic in nature. To some extent, an entrepreneurial orientation may exist in the portfolio company per se, that just has to be “freed” by the equity investors, so that this lever can be partially intrinsic and partially extrinsic. The parenting effect can be active throughout all three phases of the buyout.

33

SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS

This study provides a detailed and comprehensive synopsis of the literature on buyout value generation of the last twenty years, pulling together arguments from a variety of different academic areas. The application of our new conceptual framework makes it possible to classify various levers of buyout value generation according to three dimensions. We identify seventeen distinctly different levers of value generation, discuss the way they influence returns to the buyout investors and outline key arguments of the academic discourse of these levers whenever beneficial for our understanding. For the sake of completeness, new or less prominent levers of value generation have been added and put into context (see Table 1).

Dimensions of value generation 1 Phases 2 Causes 3 Sources

Divest- Value Value creation Lever Acqui- ment capturing sition Holding Primary Secondary Intrinsic Extrinsic A. Financial arbitrage A-1. …based on changes in x x x x market valuation

A-2. … based on private information x x x x about the portfolio company

A-3. … through superior market x x x x information

A-4. … through superior dealmaking x x x capabilities

A-5 ...through an optimization of x x x x x corporate scope

B. Financial B-1. Optimizing the capital structure x x x x B-2. Reducing corporate tax x xxx C. Increasing operational C-1. Cost cutting & margin improvements (x) x x x (x) C-2. Reducing capital requirements (x) x x x (x) D-3. Removing managerial inefficiencies (x) x x x x

D. Increasing strategic D-1. Corporate refocusing (x) x x (x) x D-2. Buy and build strategies (x) x x x x E. Reduction of agency E-1. Reducing agency cost of FCF x (x) x x E-2. Improving incentive alignment x x x x E-3. Improving monitoring and controlling x x x

F. The parenting

D-1. Restoring entrepreneurial spirit x x x (x) x D-2. Advising and enabling x x x x x

Table 1: Value Generation in Buyouts

34 Our three-dimensional framework offers a structure to the disperse field and views the topic from various different angles. This framework helps us to structure the complexity of the buyout value generation process and increases our understanding of the interconnectedness of the different levers, their importance during the different phases of the buyout and the degree to which they are inherently linked to the specific characteristics of the sponsoring buyout investor.

This structured view at the buyout value generation process illustrates that all three phases of the buyout contribute significantly to value generation and shows that buyouts value generation is not entirely "front loaded", as suggested by Baker & Montgomery (1994). At the same time, the importance of specific characteristics of the equity investors for buyout value generation is striking. The large number of value generation levers that qualify as (at least partially) extrinsic in that they depend on characteristics of the equity investors, suggests that it really makes a difference who undertakes the buyout. For investment managers in buyout associations, who compete with increasing intensity for suitable buyout targets, this has important implications.

Buyout associations need to carefully analyze through which levers they can add value in the process, and specifically through which levers they may have an edge over competing bidders for a given company. This suggests that a strategic positioning of buyout associations, through which they consciously explore and exploit their competitive advantage in buyout value generation is becoming increasingly relevant.

The appendix provides a comprehensive overview of the studies on levers of buyout value generation in the previous literature and specifies in which area the different studies contribute to the theoretical discussion, provide anecdotal evidence and conduct empirical tests of the different phenomena.

35 Our review of the literature on buyout value generation reveals that much research has been conducted in the late 80s and the early 90s. If we consider the fact that this period was characterized by highly leveraged going-private transactions (mainly in the US), it is not surprising that most of the empirical testing is based on this type of case. While these studies have been helpful to understand the basic logic of buyout transactions, it is important to recognize that the development in recent years and the international spread of buyout activity has led to a great variety of different facets of buyouts. These may differ substantially from early transactions in their strategic logic and value generation mechanisms, so that earlier studies may be less suitable to explain them.

Furthermore the synopsis (see Appendix) shows that some topics have received much attention while others have been somewhat neglected. One possible reason for this may lie in the difficulties to operationalize and manage some of the "softer" levers of value generation, such as the parenting effect.

Overall, a lack of empirical evidence for the different value generation levers becomes obvious from our overview. Much of the existing empirical evidence is rather anecdotal in nature and cannot be taken as conclusive support for the actual relevance of these levers. In addition, many levers are still entirely statistically untested and much of the quantitative empirical work we have seen is limited in its power by small sample sizes and an operationalization of key constructs that has been subject to criticism (Fox & Marcus 1992). In the light of the complex process through which various levers interact to generate value in buyouts, the importance to expand the scope of empirical studies to models that consider multiple levers simultaneously in a multivariate analysis becomes obvious. Only through such work, it will be possible to draw any kind of inference regarding the significance and relative magnitude of the different levers.

36 This lack of empirical work may be partially due to difficulties to get access to data in an industry that calls itself “private equity”. Nevertheless, we consider it highly worthwhile to take the long way and compose a data set of sufficient breadth and depth that makes it possible to tests more comprehensive models of buyout value generation. We are convinced that our synopsis and framework provide a good starting point and frame for this kind of work. Such work will not only increase our understanding of buyouts, as a phenomenon of great economic relevance. Research on buyouts can also be used to focus on effects of great relevance in a broader strategic management context that can be observed in the buyout setting.

37 REFERENCES

Allen, Jay, 1999, LBOs - The Evolution of Financial Structures and Strategies, in: Chew, Donald (Ed.), The New : Where Theory Meets Practice, Boston, MA, McGraw-Hill, p. 708-719

Anders, George, 1992, The Barbarians in the Boardroom, in: Harvard Business Review, July - August, p. 79-87

Baker, George P., 1992, Beatrice: A Study in the Creation and Destruction of Value, in: Journal of Finance, vol. 47, no. 3 (July), p. 1081-1119

Baker, George P. / Montgomery Cynthia A., 1994, Conglomerates and LBO Associations: A Comparison of Organizational Forms, in: Harvard Business School, Working Paper, November 4, p. 1-34

Baker, George P. / Smith, George D., 1998, The New Financial Capitalists: and the Creation of Corporate Value, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press

Baker, George P./ Wruck, Karen H., 1989, Organizational Changes and Value Creation in Leveraged Buy-Outs: The Case of O.M. Scott & Sons Company, in: Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 25, no. 2, p. 163-190

Barney, Jay B., 1988, Returns to Bidding Firms in Mergers and Acquisitions: Reconsidering the Relatedness Hypothesis, in: Strategic Management Journal, vol. 9 (Special Issue Summer), p. 71-78

Beaver, Graham, 2001, Management Buy-Outs: Who Dares Wins ?, in: Strategic Change, vol. 10, no. 6 (September - October), p. 307-310

Berle, Adolph / Means, Gardiner, 1932, The Modern Corporation and Private Property, New York, McMillan

Bruining, Hans / Wright, Mike, 2002, Entrepreneurial Orientation in Management Buy-outs and the Contribution of Venture Capital, in: Venture Capital: An International Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance, vol. 4, no. 2, p. 147- 168

Bull, Ivan, 1989, Financial Performance of Leveraged Buyouts: An Empirical Analysis, in: Journal of Business Venturing, vol. 4, p. 263-289

Butler, Paul A., 2001, The Alchemy of LBOs, in: The McKinsey Quarterly, Nr. 2, p. 140-151

Cotter, James F. / Peck, Sarah W., 2001, The Structure of Debt and Active Equity Investors: The Case of the Buyout Specialist, in: Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 59, no. 1 (January), p. 101-147

DeAngelo, Harry / DeAngelo, Linda / Rice, Edward M., 1984, Going Private: Minority Freezeouts and Shareholder Wealth, in: Journal of Law and Economics, vol. 27 (October), p. 367-401

DeAngelo, Linda E., 1986, Accounting Numbers as Market Valuation Substitutes: A Study of Management Buyouts of Public Shareholders, in: Accounting Review, vol. 61, no. 3 (July), p. 400-420

Demsetz, Harold, 1983, The Structure of Ownership and the Theory of the Firm, in: Journal of Law and Economics, vol. 26, p. 378-389

Easterwood, John C. / Seth, Anju / Singer, Ronald F., 1989, The Impact of Leveraged Buyouts on Strategic Direction, in: California Management Review, vol. 31, no. 1 (Fall), p. 30-43

European Private Equity and Venture Capital Association (EVCA), 2000, EVCA Guidelines, Zaventem/Belgium, April, p. 1-96

Fama, Eugene F., 1980, Agency Problems and the Theory of the Firm, in: Journal of Political Economy, vol. 88, no. 2, p. 288-307

Fama, Eugene F. / Jensen, Michael C., 1985, Organization Forms and Investment Decisions, in: Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 14, no. 2, p. 101-119

_____, 1983, Separation of Ownership and Control, in: Journal of Law and Economics, vol. 26, p. 301-325

38 Fenn, George W. / Liang, Nellie / Prowse, Stephen, 1997, The Economics of the Private Equity Market, in: Financial Markets, Institutions and Instruments , vol. 6, No. 4 (July), p. 1-105

Fox, Isaac / Marcus, Alfred, 1992, The Causes and Consequences of Leveraged Management Buyouts, in: Academy of Management Review, vol. 17, no. 1 (January), p. 62-85

Gifford, Dun, 2001, Why Debt Can Hurt Corporate Growth, in: MIT Sloan Management Review, Spring, p. 18

Goold, Michael / Campbell, Andrew / Alexander, Marcus, 1994, Corporate-Level Strategy: Creating Value in the Multibusiness Company, New York, NY, John Wiley & Sons

Grossman, Sanford J. / Hart, Oliver, 1982 (1986), Corporate Financial Structure and Managerial Incentives, in: McCall, J. (Ed.), The Economics of Information and Uncertainty, Chicago, University of Chicago Press, p. 107- 140

Hall, Bronwyn H., 1990, The Impact of Corporate Restructuring on Industrial Research and Development, in: Brooking Papers on Economic Activity, Special Issue Microeconomics, p. 85-135

Harris, Milton / Raviv, Artur, 1991, The Theory of Capital Structure, in: Journal of Finance, vol. 46, no. 1 (March), p. 297-355

Harris, Richard / Siegel, Donald S. / Wright, Mike, 2002, Assessing the Impact of Management Buyouts on Economic Efficiency: Plant-Level Evidence from the United Kingdom, Working Paper, October, p. 0-27

Hite, Gailen L. / Vetsuypens, Michael R., 1989, Management Buy-outs of Divisions and Shareholder Wealth, in: Journal of Finance, vol. 44, no. 4 (September), p. 953-970

Holthausen, Robert W. / Larcker, David F., 1996, The Financial Performance of Reverse Leveraged Buyouts, in: Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 42, no. 3 (November), p. 293-332

Hoskisson, Robert E. / Hitt, Michael A., 1994, Downscoping: How to Tame the Diversified Firm, New York, Oxford, Oxford University Press

Hoskisson, Robert E. / Turk, Thomas A., 1990, Corporate Restructuring: Governance and Control Limits of the Internal Capital Market, in: Academy of Management Journal , vol. 15, no. 3 (March), p. 459-477

Houlden, Brian, 1990, Buyouts and Beyond: Motivations, Strategies and Ownership Changes, in: Long Range Planning, vol. 23 (August), p. 73-77

Indahl, Reynir / Zinterhofer, Eric, 1998, A Note on European Private Equity, in: Harvard Business School Case, No. 9-299-017, p. 1-11

Ippolito, Richard A. / James, William M., 1992, LBOs, Reversions and Implicit Contracts, in: Journal of Finance, vol. 47, no. 1 (March), p. 139-168

Jensen, Michael C., 1989b, Eclipse of the Public Corporation, in: Harvard Business Review, vol. 67, no. 5 (September - October), p. 61-74

_____, 1989a, Active Investors, LBOs and the Privatization of Bancruptcy, in: Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Vol. 2, No. 1 (Spring), p. 35-44

Jensen, Michael C., 1986, Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance, and , in: American Economic Review, vol. 76, no. 2, p. 323-329

Jensen, Michael C. / Ruback, Richard S., 1983, The Market for Corporate Control, in: Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 11, p. 5-50

Jensen, Michael C. / Meckling, William, 1976, Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs, and Ownership Structure, in: Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 3, no. 4 (October), p. 305-360

Kaplan, Steven N., 1989b, The Effects of Management Buy-outs on Operating Performance and Value, in: Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 24, no. 2 (November), p. 217-254

_____, 1989a, Management Buyouts: Evidence on Taxes as a Source of Value, in: Journal of Finance, vol. 44, no. 3 (July), p. 611-632

39 Kitching, John, 1989, Early Retuns on LBOs: A Transatlantic Study Sheds New Light on How and Why They work, in: Harvard Business Review, vol. 67, no. 6 (November - December), p. 74-81

(KKR) Kohlberg, Kravis Roberts & Co. (with Deloitte Haskins & Sells), 1989, Leveraged Buy-Outs, in: Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Spring, p. 64-70

Lee, D. Scott, 1992, Management Buyout Proposals and Inside Information, in: Journal of Finance, vol. 47, no. 3 (July), p. 1061-1079

Lehn, Kenneth / Poulsen, Annette, 1990, The Economics of Event Risk: The Case of Bondholders in Leveraged Buyouts, in: Journal of Corporation Law, vol. 15, no. 2 (Winter), p. 199-217

Lei, David / Hitt, Michael A., 1995, Strategic Restructuring and Outsourcing: The Effect of Mergers and Acquisitions and LBOs on Building Firm Skills and Capabilities, in: Journal of Management, vol. 21, no. 5, p. 835-859

Lichtenberg, Frank / Siegel, Donald, 1990, The Effects of Leveraged Buyouts on Productivity and Related Aspects of Firm Behavior, in: Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 27 (September), p. 165-194

Liebeskind, Julia P. / Wiersema, Margarethe / Hansen, Gary, 1992, LBOs, Corporate Restructuring, and the Incentive-Intensity Hypothesis, in: Financial Management, Spring, p. 73-88

Leland, Hayne E., 1989, LBOs and Taxes: No One to Blame But Ourselves ?, in: California Management Review, vol. 32, no. 1 (Fall), p. 19-29

Long, William F. / Ravenscraft, David J., 1993a, The Financial Performance of Whole Company LBOs, Discussion Paper, November, p. 0-36

Long, William F. / Ravenscraft, David J., 1993b, LBOs, Debate and R&D Intensity, in: Strategic Management Journal , 14 (summer special issue), p. 119-135

Long, William F. / Ravenscraft, David J., 1993c, Decade of Debt: Lessons from the LBOs in the 1980s, in: Blair, Margaret M. (Ed.), The Deal Decade: What Takeovers and Leveraged Buyouts mean for Corporate Governance, Washington, D.C., Brookings Institution, p. 205-237

Lowenstein, Louis, 1985, Management Buyouts, in: Columbia Law Review, vol. 85 (May), p. 730-784

Manne, H. , 1965, Mergers and the Market for Corporate Control, in: Journal of Political Economy, vol. 73, p. 110-120

_____, 1962, The 'Higher Criticism' of the Modern Corporation, in: Columbia Law Review, vol. 62, p. 399-432

Magowan, Peter A., 1989, The Case for LBOs: The Safeway Experience, in: California Management Review, vol. 23, no. 1 (Fall), p. 9-19

Markides, Constantinos C., 1998, Strategic Innovation in Established Companies, in: MIT Sloan Management Review, vol. 39, (Spring), p. 31-42

Markides, Constantinos C., 1997, Strategic Innovation, in: MIT Sloan Management Review, vol. 38, no. 3 (Spring), p. 9-23

Meulbroek, Lisa, 1996, Note on European Buy-outs, in: Harvard Business School Case, No. 9-296-051, p. 1-34

Morck, Randall / Shleifer, Andrei / Vishny, Robert, 1988, Management Ownership and Market Valuation: An Empirical Analysis, in: Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 20, p. 293-315

Muscarella, Chris J. / Vetsuypens, Michael R., 1990, Efficiency and Organizational Structure: A Study of Reverse LBOs, in: Journal of Finance, vol. 45, no. 5 (December), p. 1389-1413

Newbould, Gerald D. / Chatfield, Robert E. / Anderson, Ronald F., 1992, Leveraged Buyouts and Tax Incentives, in: Financial Management, Spring, p. 50-57

Ofek, Eli, 1994, Efficiency Gains in Unsuccessful Management Buyouts, in: Journal of Finance, vol. 49, no. 2 (June), p. 637

40 Opler, Tim C., 1992, Operating Performance in Leveraged Buyouts: Evidence From 1985-1989, in: Financial Management, (Spring), p. 27-34

Opler, Tim C. / Titman, Sheridan, 1993, The Determinants of Leveraged Buyout Activity: Free Cash Flow vs. Financial Distress Costs, in: Journal of Finance, vol. 48, no. 5 (December), p. 1985-1999

Palepu, Krishna G., 1990, Consequences of Leveraged Buyouts, in: Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 27, no. 1 (September), p. 247-262

Phan, Phillip H. / Hill, Charles W. L., 1995, Organizational Restructuring and Economic Performance in Leveraged Buyouts: An Ex Post Study, in: Academy of Management Journal, vol. 38, no. 3 (June), p. 704-739

Porter, Michael E., 1985, Competitive Advantage, New York, Free Press

Rappaport, Alfred, 1990, The Staying Power of the Public Corporation, in: Harvard Business Review, vol. 68, no. 1 (January - February), p. 96-104

Ross, Stephen A., 1973, The Economic Theory of Agency: The Principal's Problem, in: American Economic Review, vol. 63, p. 134-139

Samdani, G. Sam / Butler, Paul / McNish, Rob, 2001, The Alchemy of Leveraged Buyouts, in: Budde, Florian / Farha, Gary A. / Frankemölle, Heiner / Hoffmeister, David F. / Krämer, Konstantin (Eds.), Value Creation: Strategies for the Chemical Industry, Weinheim, Wiley-VCH Verlag, p. 93-107

Sapienza, Harry J. / Timmons, Jeffry A., 1989, The Roles of Venture Capitalists in New Ventures: What determines Their Importance?, in: Academy of Management Best Paper Procceedings, p. 74-78

Seth, Anju / Easterwood, John, 1993, Strategic Redirection in Large Management Buyouts: The Evidence from Post-Buyout Restructuring Activity, in: Strategic Management Journal, vol. 14, no. 4, p. 251-273

Singh, Harbir, 1993, Challenges in Researching Corporate Restructuring, in: Journal of Management Studies, vol. 30, no. 1 (January), p. 147-172

_____, 1990, Management Buyouts: Distinguishing Characteristics and Operating Changes Prior To Public Offering, in: Strategic Management Journal, vol. 11, Special Issue, p. 111

Smart, Scott B. / Waldfogel, Joel, 1994, Measuring the Effect of Restructuring on Corporate Performance: The Case of Management Buyouts, in: Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 76, no. 3 (August), p. 503-511

Smith, Abbie J., 1990b, The Effects of Leveraged Buyouts , in: Business Economics, vol. 25, no. 2, p. 19-25

_____, 1990a, Corporate Ownership Structure and Performance: The Case of Management Buyouts, in: Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 27 (September), p. 143-164

Stabell, Charles B. / Fjeldstad, Oystein D., 1998, Configuring for Competitive Advantage: On Chains, Shops, and Networks, in: Strategic Management Journal, vol. 19, no. 5 (May), p. 413-437

Thompson, Steve / Wright, Mike / Robbie, Ken, 1992, Buy-Outs, Divestment, and Leverage: Restructuring Transactions and Corporate Governance, in: Oxford Review of Economic Policy, vol. 8, no. 3, p. 58-69

Weir, Charlie, 1996, Management Buyouts and Entrepreneurial Opportunities, in: Management Decisions, vol. 34, no. 3, p. 23-28

Weir, Charlie / Laing, David, 1998, Management Buy-outs: The Impact of Ownership Changes on Performance, in: Journal of Small Business and Enterprise Development, vol. 5, no. 3 (March), p. 261-269

Wiersema, Margarethe F. / Liebeskind, Julia P. , 1995, The Effects of Leveraged Buyouts on Corporate Growth and Diversification in Large Firms, in: Strategic Management Journal, vol. 16, no. 6 (September), p. 447-460

Wright, Mike / Coyne, John, 1985, Management Buy-outs, Beckenham/London, Croom-Helm

Wright, Mike / Hoskisson, Robert E. / Busenitz, Lowell W., 2001, Firm Rebirth: Buyouts as Facilitators of Strategic Growth and Entrepreneurship, in: Academy of Management Executive, vol. 15, no. 1 (February), p. 111- 125

41 Wright, Mike / Robbie, Ken, 1998, Venture Capital and Private Equity: A Review and Synthesis, in: Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, vol. 25, no. 5-6 (June/July), p. 521-570

_____, 1996, The Investor-led Buy-out: A New Strategic Option, in: Long Range Planning, vol. 29, no. 5 (October), p. 691-702

Wright, Mike / Wilson, Nick / Robbie, Ken / Ennew, Chris, 1994, Restructuring and Failure in Buy-outs and Buy- ins, in: Business Strategy Review, vol. 5, no. 2 (Summer), p. 21

Zahra, Shaker A. / Fescina, Michael, 1991, Will Leveraged Buyouts Kill U.S. Corporate Research and Development?, in: Academy of Management Executive, vol. 5, no. 4, p. 7-21

42 APPENDIX: Studies on value generation* in buyouts along levers and type of contribution

Lever Theroretical Discussion** Anecdotal Evidence**/*** Empirical Testing**/***

A. Financial Arbitrage …

A-1. … based on changes in market valuation A-2. … based on private DeAngelo et al. 1984: 367; Lehn & Poulsen 1989: 773 (s); DeAngelo 1986 (n); Hite & information about the Lowenstein 1985: 740-743; Wright & Magowan 1989 (n); Baker & Smith Vetsuypens 1989 (n); Kaplan 1989b protfolio company Coyne 1985; DeAngelo 1986: 400; 1998 (s) (n); Lehn & Poulsen 1989 (n); Lee Hite & Vetsuypens 1989: 959; Jensen 1992 (n); Opler 1992 (n); Ofek 1989a: 40; Kaplan 1989b: 218; KKR 1994 (n); 1989: 69; Lehn & Poulsen 1989: 773; Magowan 1989: 17 ; Palepu 1990: 253; Singh 1990: 114; Lee 1992: 1063; Opler 1992: 33; Thompson et al. 1992: 64; Long & Ravenscraft 1993a: 19; Ofek 1994: 638 A-2. … based on superior Anders 1992: 82; Fox & Marcus market information 1992: 68 A-3. … through superior Anders 1992: 82; Wright & Robbie dealmaking capabilities 1996: 700; Baker & Smith 1998: 26+56+107; Butler 2001:145+147 A-4. … through an Magowan 1989: 12; Singh 1993: 158 Magowan 1989 (s) optimization of corporate scope

B. Financial Engineering

B-1. Optimizing the capital DeAngelo et al. 1984: 373; Magowan Magowan 1989 (s); Anders 1992: structure 1989: 15; Anders 1992: 85; Baker & 86 (s) Smith 1998: 56; Cotter & Peck 2001: 103

43 B-2. Reducing corporate tax Lowenstein 1985: 731; Bull 1989: Lowenstein 1985: 747 (s); Leland Lowenstein, 1985 (s); Kaplan 277; Kaplan 1989a: 611; KKR 1989: 1989 (s); Baker & Smith 1998: 70 1989a (s); KKR 1989 (n); Opler & 66; Leland 1989: 20; Rappaport 1990: (s) Titman 1993: 1998 (n); Long & 102; Singh 1990:115; Smith 1990b: Ravenscraft 1993c (s) 21; Newbould et al. 1992: 56; Long & Ravenscraft 1993a: 12, 1993c: 215; Opler & Titman 1993: 1998; Baker & Smith 1998: XII+70+147; Samdani et al. 2001: 99

C. Increasing operational effectiveness

C-1. Increased efficiency after Bull 1989: 277; Baker & Wruck 1989: Baker & Wruck 1989 (s); Bull 1989 (s); Kaplan 1989b (s); buyouts 166; Kaplan 1989b: 250; Lichtenberg Magowan 1989 (s) Lichtenberg & Siegel 1990 (s); & Siegel 1990: 191; Muscarella & Muscarella & Vetsuypens 1990 (s); Vetsuypens 1990: 1398; Palepu 1990: Singh 1990 (s); Smith 1990a (s); 249-250; Singh 1990: 124; Smith Opler 1992 (s); Long & 1990a: 162; Opler 1992: 33; Long & Ravenscraft 1993a (s), 1993c (s); Ravenscraft 1993a: 23, 1993c: 214; Ofek 1994 (s); Phan & Hill 1995 Ofek 1994: 639; Phan & Hill 1995: (s); Smart & Waldfogel 1995: 503; 732; Smart & Waldfogel 1995: 503; Holthausen & Larcker 1996 (s); Holthausen & Larcker 1996: 328; Weir & Laing 1998 (s); Harris et al. Weir & Laing 1998: 268; Harris et al. 2002 (s) 2002: 15 C-2. Cost-cutting and margin Lowenstein 1985: 749; Bull 1989: Magowan 1989 (s); Baker 1992 (s); Kaplan 1989b (s) ; Hall 1990: improvements 264****; Easterwood et al. 1989: 41; Hoskisson & Hitt 1994: 115**** 87**** (s); Lichtenberg & Siegel Kaplan 1989b: 250; KKR 1989: 68, (s); Baker & Smith 1998 (s) 1990: 193**** (n); Long & 67****; Hall 1990: 87****; Ravenscraft 1993b**** (s), Lichtenberg & Siegel 1990: 193****; 1993c**** (s); Holthausen & Muscarella & Vetsuypens 1990: 1396; Larcker 1996 (s) Smith 1990b: 23****; Zahra & Fescina 1991: 10****; Anders 1992: 84; Baker 1992: 1106; Long & Ravenscraft 1993b: 132****, 1993c:

44 221****; Hoskisson & Hitt 1994: 115****; Holthausen & Larcker 1996: 296; Baker & Smith 1998: 122; Butler 2001: 143; Wright et al. 2001: 116; Samdani et al. 2001: 99; Harris et al. 2002: 15 C-3. Reducing capital Baker & Wruck 1989: 184; Baker & Wruck 1989: 184-187 (s); Easterwood et al. 1989 (s); Singh requirements Easterwood et al. 1989: 42; KKR Magowan 1989 (s); Anders 1992: 1990 (s); Smith 1990a (s); Long & 1989: 68; Singh 1990: 123; Smith 81-83 (s); Ravenscraft 1993c (s); Holthausen 1990a: 144; Long & Ravenscraft & Larcker 1996 (s) 1993c: 219; Seth & Easterwood 1993: 251; Kester & Luehrman 1995: 120; Phan & Hill 1995: 706; Holthausen & Larcker 1996: 296; Wright & Robbie 1996: 701; Samdani et al. 2001: 99 C-4. Removing managerial Anders 1992: 81 inefficiencies

D. Increasing strategic distinctiveness D-1. Corporate refocusing Easterwood et al. 1989: 39; Hoskisson Anders 1992: 83-84 (s); Baker Liebeskind et al. 1992 (s); Seth & & Turk 1990: 472; Muscarella & 1992 (s) Easterwood 1993 (s); Wiersema & Vetsuypens 1990: 1397; Singh 1990: Liebeskind 1995 (s) 114; Anders 1992: 83; Baker 1992: 1106; Liebeskind et al. 1992: 75; Seth & Easterwood 1993: 251; Singh 1993: 158; Phan & Hill 1995: 732; Wiersema & Liebeskind 1995: 449; Baker & Smith 1998: 98; Butler 2001: 143; Wright et al. 2001: 114 D-2. Buy and Build Strategies Baker & Montgomery 1994: 26; Allen 1999: 710+717; Samdani et al. 2001: 105; Wright et al. 2001: 117

E. Reducing agency costs Bull 1989: 277; Kaplan 1989b: 220;

45 Lehn & Poulsen 1989: 773; Smith 1990a: 144; Opler & Titman 1993: 1996; Wright et al. 2001: 112 E-1. Reducing agency costs Grossman & Hart 1982; Lowenstein Baker & Wruck 1989 (s) Lehn & Poulsen 1989 (s) of free cash flow 1985: 757; Jensen 1986: 323; Baker & Wruck 1989: 166; Jensen 1989a: 37+43, 1989b: 66; Lehn & Poulsen 1989: 771; Lichtenberg & Siegel 1990: 166; Palepu 1990: 248; Rappaport 1990: 97; Singh 1990: 126; Smith 1990a: 144; Fox & Marcus 1992: 66; Newbould et al. 1992: 50; Singh 1993: 157; Baker & Montgomery 1994: 20; Lei & Hitt 1995: 847; Holthausen & Larcker 1996: 295; Allen 1999: 710;Cotter & Peck 2001: 102; Gifford 2001: 18 E-2. Improving incentive DeAngelo et al. 1984: 372; Jensen Baker & Wruck 1989 (s); Anders Kitching 1989 (s); Wright et al. alignment 1986: 326; Baker & Wruck 1989: 176; 1992: 80-81 (s) 1994 (s); Phan & Hill 1995 (s) Bull 1989: 264; Easterwood et al. 1989: 40; Hite & Vetsuypens 1989: 955; Jensen 1989a: 39, 1989b: 64+68; Kitching 1989: 75; Lichtenberg & Siegel 1990: 166; Muscarella & Vetsuypens 1990: 1393+1396; Palepu 1990: 248; Smith 1990a: 144, 1990b: 21; Anders 1992: 80; Fox & Marcus 1992: 76; Thompson et al. 1992: 63; Baker & Montgomery 1994: 16; Wright et al. 1994: 38; Phan & Hill 1995: 706; Holthausen & Larcker 1996: 295; Baker & Smith 1998: 57+96; Weir & Laing 1998: 262; Beaver 2001: 308; Cotter & Peck 2001: 102; Samdani et al. 2001: 100

46 E-3. Improving monitoring DeAngelo et al. 1984: 373; Hite & Cotter & Peck 2001 (s) and controlling Vetsuypens 1989: 956; Jensen 1989a: 36, 1989b: 64; KKR 1989: 68; Palepu 1990: 247; Singh 1990: 112; Smith 1990a: 144; Anders 1992: 84; Cotter & Peck 2001: 101+135

F. The parenting effect

D-1. Restoring entrepreneurial Lowenstein 1985: 756; Bull 1989: Baker & Smith 1998: 56 (s) spirit 277; Jensen 1989a: 39; Hite & Vetsuypens 1989: 955; Hoskisson & Turk 1990: 472; Houlden 1990: 74; Singh 1990: 112; Kester & Luehrman 1995: 120+123; Weir 1996: 25; Baker & Smith 1998: 56; Beaver 2001: 308; Butler 2001: 144; Samdani et al. 2001: 101; Wright et al. 2001: 118; Bruining & Wright 2002: 165 D-2. Advising and enabling Baker & Wruck 1989:176+183; Hite Baker & Wruck 1989:176+183 (s); & Vetsuypens 1989: 956; Magowan Anders 1992: 84 (s) 1989: 14; Sapienza & Timmons 1989: 77; Houlden 1990: 74; Baker & Wruck 1989: 176; Baker & Montgomery 1994: 22; Kester & Luehrman 1995: 123; Baker & Smith 1998: 100+171+174; Butler 2001: 146; Bruining & Wright 2002: 165 * This Appendix lists only publications with a clear buyout focus. ** Studies in order of publication date and in alphabetical order within a year. Page follow year of publication. *** s = supported; n = not supported (This reflects only the oucome of the empirical testing of the studies has not been reviewed qualitatively by the authors.) **** Studies that focus explicitely on the development of R&D expenses after a buyout.

47