Putting Neo-Liberalism in Its Place(S) Living With/In and Without Neo-Liberalism

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Putting Neo-Liberalism in Its Place(S) Living With/In and Without Neo-Liberalism FORUM Putting neo-liberalism in its place(s) Living with/in and without neo-liberalism John Clarke Abstract: This article explores some concerns about the concept of neo-liberalism, suggesting that it has been stretched too far to be productive as a critical analytical tool. Neo-liberalism suffers from promiscuity (hanging out with various theoret- ical perspectives), omnipresence (treated as a universal or global phenomenon), and omnipotence (identified as the cause of a wide variety of social, political and economic changes). Alternative ways of treating neo-liberalism as more contin- gent and contested are considered. These emphasize its mobile and flexible char- acter, stressing processes of contextual assemblage, articulation, and translation. The article concludes by wondering whether the concept of neo-liberalism is now so overused that it should be retired. Keywords: assemblage, articulation, authority, globalization, neo-liberalism Neoliberalism seems to be everywhere. —Jamie Peck and Adam Tickell Neoliberalism seems to mean many different things depending on one’s vantage point. — Aihwa Ong This article starts from the puzzles identified by think of the relationship between neo-liberalism these quotations. They point to what I think of and space. For Ong (2006), it creates the condi- as the core problems of neo-liberalism as a con- tion for critical reflection on how to think—or cept: it is omnipresent and it is promiscuous. rethink—neoliberalism as an analytic category. There may be a third: that neo-liberalism is om- In the course of the article, I will take up these nipotent, but we will come to questions of power as central issues for considering the “transla- later. I am intrigued by the two quotations in tion” of neo-liberalism. But first, let me offer a part because of what work the word “seems” to word of warning about the article. It is deliber- be doing in each of them. It opens up a moment ately conversational in approach. It forms part of critical distance. For Peck and Tickell (2002), of a long-running conversation centered on the the critical distance concerns precisely how to question of neo-liberalism. This is sometimes a Focaal—European Journal of Anthropology 51 (2008): 135–47 doi:10.3167/fcl.2008.510110 136 | John Clarke conversation with myself, sometimes with mulation directly or being more connected to friends, and sometimes with people with whom what Jessop might call their “societalization” in I feel less comfortable. It represents one more different regimes that attempt to organize and attempt to wrestle with puzzles that continue to reorganize time and space. It is this analytic fo- trouble me in analytical and political ways (e.g., cus that marks their difference from a set of Clarke 1991, 2004a, 2004b). approaches to neo-liberalism that views the con- cept through a Foucauldian analytic of govern- mentality. Here neo-liberalism marks the rise of Promiscuous neo-liberalism technologies of governing populations that con- struct “economic” logics of calculation and in- The question of what we might mean by neo- vite people to become “self-governing” (e.g., Ong liberalism is a difficult one. The answers to this 2006; Rose 1999). Such conceptions of neo- question are various, divergent, and overlapping. liberalism as governmentality link sites and tech- The simplest answer is, perhaps, David Harvey’s nologies as diverse as the management of security view of neo-liberalism as the political/ideologi- or the constitution/regulation of a global space, cal project of a class seeking to change the bal- the rise of NGOs (non-governmental organiza- ance of power in global capitalism and create new tions) as a mode of governance in and of civil means of capital accumulation (Harvey 2005). society, through the economization of the cal- The attraction of this answer is that it is simple, culating self (as entrepreneur, as consumer, as it is evident everywhere, and applies to a variety prudential risk taker, etc.), to the rise of thera- of economic and social phenomena, from ex- peutic technologies of the self.1 tensive land dispossession through to the new Although I have sketched these as three differ- flexibilities of capital or to the dismantling of ent answers (see also Barnett 2005; Larner 2000), the social state (in societies of the North/West). the boundaries between them blur and are tra- A related answer would perhaps stress the versed, as is usually the case with boundaries. political–ideological dimensions more emphat- From all three perspectives, some of the same ically, pointing to the dismantling of earlier po- trends or tendencies are visible, even if they are litical settlements and their forms of institu- made to mean slightly different things. For ex- tionalization (welfare states, forms of citizenship, ample, the much-cited renaming of an unem- corporatist settlements between capital and labor, ployed person claiming unemployment benefit Atlantic Fordism, etc.). These changes create as a “job seeker” by the UK’s Conservative gov- new ways of thinking, new political formations, ernment can be read as (a) evidence of the sub- and new institutional forms that can be charac- ordination of social policy to the power of terized as neo-liberal because they involve both capital and the liberation of the market; (b) evi- the direct expansion of the scope and reach of dence of trying to create a new “economized” or corporate capital, and the indirect “economiza- “market centric” rhetoric in displacing social tion” of areas of social and political life (public democratic, welfarist, or citizen-centered institu- functions to be either privatized or “run like a tions; or (c) an instance of a governmental tech- business,” for example). This view would focus nology for producing subjects who understand rather more attention on the political and ideo- themselves as “entrepreneurial” or “willing selves” logical levels of analysis, and would be especially (Maasen and Sutter 2007). concerned with processes of state reform or trans- It might be that these boundaries are both formation, and about the spatial and scalar re- blurred and traversed by the question of eco- structurings with which it is associated (e.g., nomics. Although the economic is clearly at the Hartmann 2005; Jessop 2002; Peck 2004). centre of political economic analyses of the ref- Despite their different emphases, these two ormation of capital, it mutates in the second ver- views are linked by a foundation in political econ- sion to include questions of neo-liberalism as omy, whether addressing forms of capital accu- “economic discourse” (Peck 2004: 394), whereas Living with/in and without neo-liberalism | 137 some Foucauldian work locates the discursive we might remember the difficult work that was and governmental “economization” of social and needed to “unlock” the oppressive and over- political life as a key feature of neo-liberalism whelming weight that the concept of globaliza- (Brown 2005; Rose 1999). There are two points tion carried—and the sense of inevitability that to be made here. On the one hand, these are was associated with it (Massey 2004a; see also not exactly the same “economic”: one refers to a Barnett 2005). But if it is not everywhere, is neo- material substructure of forces, relations, and liberalism merely the new colonialism, articulat- interests (which may be more or less directly ex- ing metropolises and peripheries in new forms pressed in political and ideological forms); the of ruling at a distance? How to understand the other refers to a view of the “economic” as those complicated spaces of neo-liberalism has been practices, relationships, and forms of organiza- the subject of much critical discussion in geog- tion that are discursively constituted as eco- raphy that has explored its uneven expansion, nomic through governmental work. This issue its variegated “local forms,” and its hybridity. is both a focus of coincidence and analytical For example, Peck argues that: frustration. On the other hand, we might take this coincidence not as the effect of bad theoret- “While neoliberalism may have begun life as a ical work, but as indicating something trou- North Atlantic intellectual movement, its muta- bling about both the central and problematic tion into a variegated and internationalized state character of “the economic” in contemporary project over the past thirty years has been asso- transformations. I realize this is a rather weak ciated with a profoundly transnational process formulation—but I am not sure I can reconcile of ‘social learning’ which has established new the epistemological, theoretical, and political circuits of neoliberal economic and legal exper- divergences between Marxism and Foucauldian tise, new material connections between finan- analysis here (if ever…). They will, however, con- cializing and globalizing economies and new tinue to haunt the concept of neo-liberalism. forms of connection around neoliberal norms” (2004: 402). Omnipresent neo-liberalism I have argued elsewhere that neo-liberalism is a political–cultural project that aims at transna- “There has everywhere been an emphatic turn tional hegemony, in which different places are towards neo-liberalism in political-economic invited, seduced, and compelled to join (Clarke practices and thinking since the 1970s. Deregu- 2004a). Peck points to the strange “doubling” of lation, privatization and withdrawal of the state general and particular in this process: “Each from many areas of social provision have been and every neoliberal transition, in this sense, is all too common. Almost all states, from those distinctive though each also remakes the relation- newly minted after the collapse of the Soviet ship between the part (an actually existing neo- Union to old-style social democracies and wel- liberal case) and the whole (the abstraction that fare states such as New Zealand and Sweden we might provisionally term neoliberalism-in- have embraced, sometimes voluntarily and in general)” (2004: 395).
Recommended publications
  • The Lost and the New 'Liberal World' of Welfare Capitalism
    Social Policy & Society (2017) 16:3, 405–422 C Cambridge University Press 2016. This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. doi:10.1017/S1474746415000676 The Lost and the New ‘Liberal World’ of Welfare Capitalism: A Critical Assessment of Gøsta Esping-Andersen’s The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism a Quarter Century Later Christopher Deeming School of Geographical Sciences, University of Bristol E-mail: [email protected] Celebrating the 25th birthday of Gøsta Esping-Andersen’s seminal book The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism (1990), this article looks back at the old ‘liberal world’ and examines the new. In so doing, it contributes to debates and the literature on liberal welfare state development in three main ways. First, it considers the concept of ‘liberalism’ and liberal ideas about welfare provision contained within Three Worlds. Here we are also interested in how liberal thought has conceptualised the (welfare) state, and the class-mobilisation theory of welfare-state development. Second, the article elaborates on ‘neo-’liberal social reforms and current welfare arrangements in the English-speaking democracies and their welfare states. Finally, it considers the extent to which the English-speaking world of welfare capitalism is still meaningfully ‘liberal’ and coherent today. Key words: Welfare regimes, welfare state capitalism, liberalism, neoliberalism, comparative social policy. Introduction Esping-Andersen’s The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism (Three Worlds hereafter) has transformed and inspired social research for a quarter of a century.
    [Show full text]
  • Welfare Capitalism and the Social Security Act of 1935 Author(S): Jill S
    Welfare Capitalism and the Social Security Act of 1935 Author(s): Jill S. Quadagno Source: American Sociological Review, Vol. 49, No. 5 (Oct., 1984), pp. 632-647 Published by: American Sociological Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2095421 Accessed: 16/09/2009 14:54 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=asa. Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. JSTOR is a not-for-profit organization founded in 1995 to build trusted digital archives for scholarship. We work with the scholarly community to preserve their work and the materials they rely upon, and to build a common research platform that promotes the discovery and use of these resources. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. American Sociological Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to American Sociological Review. http://www.jstor.org WELFARE CAPITALISM AND THE SOCIAL SECURITY ACT OF 1935* JILL S.
    [Show full text]
  • Representations of Social Europe
    Representations of Social Europe Arnaud Lechevalier (Université Paris 1 ; LISE, UMR CNAM-CNRS 3320 ; Centre Marc Bloch, UMIFRE N°14 CNRS-MAE, Humboldt University of Berlin), Fransesco Laruffa (Graduate School of Social Science, Humboldt University of Berlin), Maryse Salles (University of Toulouse), Gabriel Colletis (University of Toulouse). Communication au Colloque « Les usages de la sociologie des politiques sociales », organisé les jeudi 2 et vendredi 3 octobre 2014 par le Centre Georges Chevrier (Université de Bourgogne – CNRS) et le réseau RT6 de l’AFS à la Maison des Sciences de l’Homme de Dijon. Abstract: Two main political and economic paradigms have framed the Social Europe so far. The first one has consisted in the (German) “ordoliberalism”, which has played a key role in structuring the foundations of the European Community as well as those of the Monetary Union. The other and more recent one is the so called “Social Investment Strategy” ” recently endorsed by the European Commission. Both normative frameworks have been also at the heart of the responses formulated at the European level to the euro crisis. Therefore, they have had decisive consequences on the current social situation in the Economic and Monetary Union. This paper uses a theoretical and methodological framework, that combine Weltanschauungen (or doxai), principles and norms, for analyzing models of representations of social facts. This grid of analysis is used to understand what has happened to the Social Europe in the wake of the current Eurozone crisis and to formulate some alternatives. 1 The collapse of the financial markets, which happened 2007-2008 in the United States, has meanwhile turned into the worst social crisis ever experienced by several Member States of the Economic and Monetary Union.
    [Show full text]
  • The Mediterranean Model in European Economic Thought
    Athens Journal of Mediterranean Studies- Volume 6, Issue 3, July 2020 – Pages 179-198 The Mediterranean Model in European Economic Thought By Catia Eliana Gentilucci* The Mediterranean Economic Model (MEM) is understood as being a system of thought involving Greece, Italy and Spain which places man at the centre of economic relations, unlike other economic models which are based on the individualistic approach and see man as a rational, passive product determined by economic processes. MEM is part of the more general European Social Model, in which three distinct approaches to capitalism based on different religious and historical backgrounds can be observed: the social market economy, inspired by Lutheranism; the Mediterranean Economic Model, inspired by Catholicism, has its roots in Aristotelian thought and, through the contribution of Thomas Aquinas, reaches Spain; and a more traditional approach, the Anglo-Saxon (neoclassical mainstream), is inspired by Calvinism and Lutheranism. This paper maintains that, due to their different cultural approaches to welfare, MEM countries are struggling with economic growth. In reality, the evident difference between Mediterranean and continental Europe regarding the management of public spending ought to make us reflect on the fact that historical processes should never be underestimated. Keywords: European Social Model, Lutheran and Catholic Capitalism, Welfare Society. Introduction The Mediterranean Economic Model is understood as being a system of thought involving Greece, Italy and Spain which
    [Show full text]
  • Welfare Capitalism and Americanization on the D&IR
    Welfare Capitalism and Americanization on the D&IR: Creating Unity in the Work Place and in the community Jimmy Engren (Ph.D.), Örebro University 1 During the latter part of the 1800s the “labor problem”, as it was labeled in its day, became an acute threat to the development of industrial capitalism and bourgeois society in America. The period from before the civil war and into the gilded age created increasing levels of social unrest. David Brody has explained the increasing strife between labor and capital during this period by increased mechanization, the increasingly large companies, the gradual systematization of administration, and finally the launching of scientific management. All these factors changed the conditions of the American work force and, to use David Brody’s words, “each in its way diminished the worker and cut him down to fit the productive system”.1 One response to the increasingly visible conflict between labor and capital is constituted by welfare programs of many American companies. The purpose of this article is to analyze the specific character of the welfare programs that were deployed on the Duluth & Iron Range Railroad between the late 1890s and the mid 1920s and what role the programs played in the political economy of Minnesota under Anglo-American leadership. The Context The establishment of a railroad connecting the ore fields in Northern Minnesota and Lake Superior was started in 1882 when Eastern Capital interests in mining sought to transport Minnesotan Ore to steel mills in Pittsburg and Cleveland. Two Harbors was initially a small town of a few hundred railroad employees but grew steadily to more than 8 000 persons in the 1910s.
    [Show full text]
  • Related Issue #Ii: an Overview
    RELATED ISSUE #II: AN OVERVIEW Watch the video Individualism and Collectivism Reviewed In this section you have been charged with assessing impacts of, and reactions to, principles of liberalism. Liberalism, although having a number of specific and diverse applications, is generally held to be a belief in individual freedom and dignity that is to be achieved through as little government intervention as is possible. As a result of this very general definition, there are many, many examples that may be used to describe liberalism in practice. You are encouraged to review this section in the textbook to more fully understand specific contributions to this concept’s development by many Aboriginal/Indigenous People throughout the globe. Sometimes these actions and belief systems arise in response to different interpretations of what is in the best interest because at the heart of liberalism is the belief that individuals will make choices so as to benefit themselves and society. This duality has often been Reproduction | Not for Protected Copyright problematic as the interests of individuals and societies have clashed. An example of this was the abject poverty experienced by those working in the early stages of classical liberal thinking. Factory conditions certainly meant that employers were able to enjoy larger profits because of the monies saved by not having proper ventilation or safety devices in place but … without many of the labor laws and other developments to protect the workers society would not have been able to progress to its current state. Classical liberal thinkers you are charged with more fully understanding are John Locke, Montesquieu, Adam Smith and John Stuart Mill.
    [Show full text]
  • The Real Worlds of Welfare Capitalism
    The Real Worlds of Welfare Capitalism The Real Worlds of Welfare Capitalism traces how individuals fare over time in each of the three types of welfare state. Through a unique analysis of panel data from Germany, the Netherlands and the US, tracking individuals’ socio-economic fate over fully ten years, Goodin, Headey, MuVels and Dirven explore issues of economic growth and eYciency, of poverty and inequality, of social integration, stability and autonomy. It is common to talkof the inevitability of trade-o Vs between these goals, but in this bookthe authors contend that the social demo- cratic welfare regime, represented here by the Netherlands, equals or exceeds the performance of the corporatist German regime and the liberal US regime across all these social and economic objectives. They thus argue that, whatever one’s priorities, the social democratic welfare regime is the best choice for realizing them. Robert E. Goodin is Professor of Philosophy at the Research School of Social Sciences, Australian National University. He is the editor of The Journal of Political Philosophy, and of the Cambridge University Press series Theories of Institutional Design. His books include Political Theory and Public Policy (1982), Not Only the Poor (with Julian Le Grand, et al., 1987), Reasons for Welfare (1988) and Social Welfare and Individual Responsibility (with David Schmitz, 1998). Bruce Headey is Associate Professor of Political Science and Public Policy at the University of Melbourne. He is the author of various articles and books on housing, well-being and income dynamics. His publications include Housing Policy in the Developed Economy (1978) and Understanding Happiness: A Theory of Subjective Well-Being (with Alex Wearing, 1992).
    [Show full text]
  • Avant-Garde Welfare Capitalism Corporate Welfare Work and Enlightened Capitalism in Great Britain, the US, Germany and France (1880-1930)1
    Avant-garde Welfare Capitalism Corporate Welfare Work and Enlightened Capitalism in Great Britain, the 1 US, Germany and France (1880-1930) Erik de Gier Nijmegen School of Management Radboud University, Nijmegen, Netherlands [email protected] Abstract This research paper deals with welfare work in four industrializing countries, Great Britain, the USA, Germany and France, in the half century of flowering enlightened paternalistic capitalism between 1880 and 1930. Welfare work in this context is defined as, sometimes overly, paternalistic labour policy of enlightened entrepreneurs often encompassing workman’s housing programs, pensions, saving programs, educational programs, sports facilities, medical services, worker participation, generous remuneration forms, and shorter working times. The question is raised if nowadays flex-capitalism in the context of shrinking collective welfare states can learn lessons from past experience with welfare work. By redefining paternalistic welfare work in modernistic terms as well as by reweighting company, personal and state responsibilities a new future-proof trade-off as regards welfare work might be realised. Keywords: company towns, corporate welfare work, paternalism, welfare capitalism. 1 This paper was presented at the international conference ‘Social boundaries of work. Changes in the sphere of work in the 21st century capitalism’,Wrocław University, Poland, 14-15 November 2014. It will be part of the introductory chapter of: Gier, Erik de, Capitalist Workingman’s Paradises Revisited. Corporate welfare work in Great Britain, the USA, Germany and France in the golden age of capitalism, 1880-1930. To be published in fall 2015 by Amsterdam University Press (AUP): Amsterdam. (1) Setting the stage: Émile Zola’s workers utopia In one of his last works before he died, renowned French author Émile Zola, sketched a utopian cité idéale, or ideal steel manufacturing company town by 1900.
    [Show full text]
  • Re-Theorizing the Welfare State and the Political Economy of Neoliberalism's War Against It
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Palley, Thomas I. Working Paper Re-theorizing the welfare state and the political economy of neoliberalism's war against it FMM Working Paper, No. 16 Provided in Cooperation with: Macroeconomic Policy Institute (IMK) at the Hans Boeckler Foundation Suggested Citation: Palley, Thomas I. (2018) : Re-theorizing the welfare state and the political economy of neoliberalism's war against it, FMM Working Paper, No. 16, Hans-Böckler-Stiftung, Macroeconomic Policy Institute (IMK), Forum for Macroeconomics and Macroeconomic Policies (FFM), Düsseldorf This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/181474 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu FMM WORKING PAPER No.
    [Show full text]
  • The Real Worlds of Welfare Capitalism
    The Real Worlds of Welfare Capitalism Robert E. Goodin, Bruce Headey, Ruud MuVels and Henk-Jan Dirven published by the press syndicate of the university of cambridge The Pitt Building, Trumpington Street, Cambridge CB2 1RP, United Kingdom cambridge university press The Edinburgh Building, Cambridge, CB2 2RU, UK http://www.cup.cam.ac.uk 40 West 20th Street, NY 10011-4211, USA http://www.cup.org 10 Stamford Road, Oakleigh, Melbourne 3166, Australia © Robert E. Goodin, Bruce Headey, Ruud MuVels and Henk-Jan Dirven 1999 This book is in copyright. Subject to statutory exception and to the provisions of relevant collective licensing agreements, no reproduction of any part may take place without the written permission of Cambridge University Press. First published 1999 Printed in the United Kingdom at the University Press, Cambridge Typeset in Plantin 10/12pt [vn] A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library Library of Congress Cataloguing in Publication data The Real Worlds of Welfare Capitalism/Robert E. Goodin . [et al.]. p. cm. Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN 0 521 59386 7 (hardbound) 1. Welfare state. 2. Welfare state – Case studies. 3. United States – Social policy. 4. Netherlands – Social policy. 5. Germany – Social policy. I. Goodin, Robert E. JC479.R4 1999 361.6'5 – dc21 98-49778 CIP ISBN 0 521 59386 7 hardback ISBN 0 521 59639 4 paperback Contents Preface page vii Acknowledgments viii 1 Introduction 1 Part I: Setting the scene 2 Reasons for welfare 21 3 Alternative institutional designs
    [Show full text]
  • Economic Inequality's Correlation with Political Inequality and Inequality of Opportunity and the Implications for Social Justice Theory
    Portland State University PDXScholar Dissertations and Theses Dissertations and Theses Spring 7-25-2013 Economic Inequality's Correlation with Political Inequality and Inequality of Opportunity and the Implications for Social Justice Theory Staci Leigh Schoff Portland State University Follow this and additional works at: https://pdxscholar.library.pdx.edu/open_access_etds Part of the Inequality and Stratification Commons, Political Theory Commons, and the Politics and Social Change Commons Let us know how access to this document benefits ou.y Recommended Citation Schoff, Staci Leigh, "Economic Inequality's Correlation with Political Inequality and Inequality of Opportunity and the Implications for Social Justice Theory" (2013). Dissertations and Theses. Paper 980. https://doi.org/10.15760/etd.980 This Thesis is brought to you for free and open access. It has been accepted for inclusion in Dissertations and Theses by an authorized administrator of PDXScholar. Please contact us if we can make this document more accessible: [email protected]. Economic Inequality’s Correlation with Political Inequality and Inequality of Opportunity and the Implications for Social Justice Theory By Staci Leigh Schoff A thesis suBmitted in partial fulfillment of the Requirements for the degree of Master of Arts In Political Science Thesis Committee: Craig Carr Christopher Shortell Bruce Gilley Portland State University 2013 © 2013 Staci Schoff Abstract In 2004 the American Political Science Association (“APSA”) published research exploring whether the rising income inequality in the United States had an effect on political equality. Although the APSA found tremendous evidence of a correlation between income and political power, the APSA nonetheless concluded that the issue could not be conclusively determined without further analysis.
    [Show full text]
  • The Three Political Economies of the Welfare State*
    [1] The Three Political Economies of the Welfare State* The Legacy of Classical Political Economy Most debates on the welfare state have been guided by two questions. First, will the salience of class diminish with the extension of social citizenship? In other words, can the welfare state fundamentally trans- form capitalist society? Second, what are the causal forces behind welfare-state development? These questions are not recent. Indeed, they were formulated by the nineteenth-century political economists 100 years before any welfare state can rightly be said to have come into existence. The classical political economists - whether of liberal, conservative, or Marxist persuasion - were preoccupied with the relationship between capital- ism and welfare. They certainly gave different (and usually normative) answers, but their analyses converged around the relationship between market (and property), and the state (democracy). Contemporary neo-liberalism is very much an echo of classical liberal political economy. For Adam Smith, the market was the superior means for the abolition of class, inequality, and privilege. Aside from a necessary minimum, state intervention would only stifle the equalizing process of competitive exchange and create monopolies, protectionism, and inefficiency: the state upholds class; the market can potentially undo class society (Smith, 1961, II, esp. pp. 232-6).1 Liberal political economists were hardly of one mind when it came * This chapter is adapted from an article which previously appeared in the Canadian Review of Sociology and Anthropology, Vol. 26:2 (1989) under the title "The three political economies of the welfare state'. 4 Welfare States: Construction, Deconstruction, Reconstruction II 4 10 THE THREE WELFARE-STATE REGIMES to policy advocacy.
    [Show full text]