Option Prices and Implied Volatility Dynamics Under Ayesian Learning

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Option Prices and Implied Volatility Dynamics Under Ayesian Learning T|L? hUit @?_ W4T*i_ VL*@|*|) #)?@4Ut ?_ih @)it@? wi@h??} @tt4L B_L*? **@? A44ih4@?? N?iht|) Lu @*uLh?@c 5@? #i}L a?i 2bc 2fff Devwudfw Wklv sdshu vkrzv wkdw pdq| ri wkh hpslulfdo eldvhv ri wkh Eodfn dqg Vfkrohv rswlrq sulflqj prgho fdq eh h{sodlqhg e| Ed|hvldq ohduqlqj hhfwv1 Lq wkh frqwh{w ri dq htxloleulxp prgho zkhuh glylghqg qhzv hyroyh rq d elqrpldo odwwlfh zlwk xqnqrzq exw uhfxuvlyho| xsgdwhg suredelolwlhv zh gh0 ulyh forvhg0irup sulflqj irupxodv iru Hxurshdq rswlrqv1 Ohduqlqj lv irxqg wr jhqhudwh dv|pphwulf vnhzv lq wkh lpsolhg yrodwlolw| vxuidfh dqg v|vwhpdwlf sdwwhuqv lq wkh whup vwuxfwxuh ri rswlrq sulfhv1 Gdwd rq V)S 833 lqgh{ rswlrq sulfhv lv xvhg wr edfn rxw wkh sdudphwhuv ri wkh xqghuo|lqj ohduqlqj surfhvv dqg wr suhglfw wkh hyroxwlrq lq wkh furvv0vhfwlrq ri rswlrq sulfhv1 Wkh sursrvhg prgho ohdgv wr orzhu rxw0ri0vdpsoh iruhfdvw huuruv dqg vpdoohu khgjlqj huuruv wkdq d ydulhw| ri dowhuqdwlyh rswlrq sulflqj prghov/ lqfoxglqj Eodfn0Vfkrohv1 Zh zlvk wr wkdqn Doh{dqghu Gdylg/ Mrvh Fdpsd/ Ehuqdug Gxpdv/ Fodxglr Plfkhodffl/ Hq0 ultxh Vhqwdqd dqg vhplqdu sduwlflsdqwv dw Erffrql Xqlyhuvlw|/ FHPIL/ Ihghudo Uhvhuyh Edqn ri Vw1 Orxlv/ LQVHDG/ PfJloo/ XFVG/ Xqlyhuvlw| ri Ylujlqld dqg Xqlyhuvlw| ri \run iru glvfxvvlrqv dqg khosixo frpphqwv1 W?|hL_U|L? *|L} *@U! @?_ 5UL*it< Eb. uLh4*@ hi4@?t |i 4Lt| UL44L?*) ti_ LT |L? ThU?} 4L_i* ? ?@?U@* 4@h!i|tc @ *@h}i *|ih@|hi @t _LU4i?|i_ |t t|hL?} i4ThU@* M@tit Lt| UL44L?*)c tU M@tit @hi @ttLU@|i_ | |i @TTi@h@?Ui Lu t)t|i4@|U T@||ih?t Et4*it Lh t!it ? |i 4T*i_ L*@|*|) thu@Ui ThL_Ui_ M) ?ih|?} 4@h!i| ThUit @?_ tL*?} uLh |i ?!?L? L*@|*|) T@h@4i|ih Ei} + M?t|i? EbHDc bbe @?_ #4@tc 6*i4?} @?_ `@*i) EbbH W4T*i_ L*@|*|) @*tL @TTi@ht |L Mi t)t|i4@|U@**) hi*@|i_ |L |i |ih4 t|hU|hi Lu LT|L? UL?|h@U|t E#@t @?_ 5?_@h@4 Ebbb 5iih@* ThU?} 4L_i*t @i Mii? ThLTLti_ |L LihUL4i |iti ThLM*i4t Aiti ?U*_i t|LU@t|U L*@|*|) EO** @?_ `|i EbH.c `}}?t EbH.c i*?L @?_ Ah?M** Ebbfc Oit|L? Ebb @?_ +O 4L_i*t E#@? EbbD( 4L_i*t | 4Tt ? |i ?_ih*)?} ThUi ThLUitt Eih|L? Eb.S( 4T_gtL? 4L_i*t E@** @?_ ALhLt EbHDc 4? Ebb ( @?_ 4L_i*t ?ULhTLh@|?} |h@?t@U|L? ULt|t Ewi *@?_ EbHD @!tc @L @?_ i? Ebb. t44@h3i |i i4ThU@* TihuLh4@?Ui Lu |iti 4L_i*t Lt| LT|L? ThU?} 4L_i*t u@* |L 4ThLi t}?U@?|*) L? |i i4ThU@* | Lu |i *@U!5UL*it E5 4L_i* @?_c M) 4L_u)?} |i t|LU@t|U ThLUitt uL**Li_ M) |i ?_ih*)?} @tti| ThUic _L ?L| ThL_i @ _hiU| iUL?L4U i T*@?@|L? uLh |i t)t|i4@|U tLh|UL4?}t Lu 5 iih|i*ittc |t *|ih@|hi @t UL?|hM|i_ t}?U@?|*) |L Lh ?_iht|@?_?} Lu |i hi^hi4i?|t Lu @? LT|L? ThU?} 4L_i* |@| U@? | LMtihi_ _@|@ W? |t T@Tih i hi*@ |i !i) @tt4T|L? ?_ih*)?} |i 5 4L_i* Lu u** ?uLh 4@|L? @ML| |i t|LU@t|U ThLUitt |@| _hit u?_@4i?|@*t Lhi tTiUU@**)c i @tt4i |@| u?_@4i?|@*t iL*i L? @ M?L4@* *@||Ui | <T< @?_ <_L?< ThLM@M*|it |@| @hi ?!?L? |L ?it|Lht L T_@|i |ih ThLM@M*|) it|4@|it t?} @)it< h*i Ai ?_ih*)?} @tti| ThUi ThLUitt t _i|ih4?i_ M) i4Mi__?} |i *i@h??} 4iU@?t4 ? @? i^*Mh4 4L_i* W? i^*Mh4c @tti| ThUit hiiU| @** TLttM*i u|hi ThLM@M*|) _t|hM|L?t Lu |i T@h@4i|ih it|4@|it @?_ |ihi @hi ?L i TiU|i_ }@?t uhL4 4T*i4i?|?} |h@_?} t|h@|i}it M@ti_ L? |i ?uL*_?} Lu it|4@|L? ?Uih|@?|) `*i |ihi @hi ?L 4@?) T@Tiht t|_)?} |i @tti| ThU?} igiU|t Lu *i@h??}c |i L?*) L|ih t|_) |@| i T*U|*) UL?t_iht |t _ih@|i ThU?} 4T*U@|L?t @T 4H1j1/ Ervvdhuw +4<<8/ 4<<<, dqg Wlpphupdqq +4<<6,1 Ti@ht |L Mi #@_ @?_ VihL?it Ebbb W?it|Lht ? |ih 4L_i* u@Ui @ *|ih?} ThLM*i4 U *i@_t |i4 |L T_@|i |i ThLM@M*|) Lu U Lu |L t|@|it u? _@4i?|@*t @hi Uhhi?|*) ? 5?Ui ?it|Lht _L ?L| !?L |i |hi t|@|ic tLU!t |L u?_@4i?|@*t @hi igiU|i*) _h@? uhL4 @ ?L?B@tt@? 4 |hi _t|hM|L? @?_ i?Ui |i 5 4L_i* t ?L| LM|@?i_ ? |i *4| W? UL?|h@t|c i @tt4i |@| u?_@ 4i?|@*t uL**L @ M?L4@* ThLUittc Lti *4| t B@tt@? At @**Lt t |L tL*@|i |i igiU| Lu ?it|Lht< hiUhti it|4@|L? Lu T@h@4i|ih @*it ? @ 4L_i* |@| UL? ih}it @t)4T|L|U@**) |L 5 ?L|ih _gihi?Ui t |@| i t|_) |i @M*|) Lu |i *i@h??} 4L_i* |L Thi_U| L|Lut@4T*i |i iL*|L? ? |i i?|hi UhLtttiU|L? Lu LT|L? ThUit @?_ |L }i?ih@|i *Lih i_}?} ihhLht |@? *@U!5UL*it Ai 4TLh |@?Ui Lu tU i ihUtit uLh i@*@|?} _gihi?| LT|L? ThU?} 4L_i*t @t hiUi?|*) Mii? i4T@t3i_ M) #4@t i| @* EbbH h @TThL@U t @*tL hi*@|i_ |L @ *@h}i *|ih@|hi |@| ?uiht |i 4@h!i|<t ThLM @M*|) Mi*iut uhL4 @tti| ThUit E+M?t|i? Ebbec a@U!ih| @?_ +M?t|i? EbbSc |5@@*@ @?_ wL EbbH @*|L} Lh hit*|t i T*U|*) ?ULhTLh@|i |i igiU| Lu ?it|Lht< Mi*iut L? i^*Mh4 ThUit Ai @tt4T|L? |@| |i 4@h!i| T_@|it |t Mi*iut |hL} @)it h*i @__t @ ?i @tTiU| |L |t i ihUti @?_ ThL _it @? ?_iht|@?_?} Lu |i |4itihit _)?@4Ut Lu 4T*i_ L*@|*|) thu@Uit 54T*) hiT*@U?} |i @tt4T|L? ? |i 5 4L_i* Lu !?L? <T< @?_ <_L?< ThLM@M*|it | @)it@? *i@h??} t uL?_ |L }i?ih@|i M@tit t4*@h |L |Lti LMtihi_ ? LT|L? ThUit L?tt|i?| | hiUi?| i4ThU@* i_i?Ui E|5@@*@ @?_ wL EbbHc *i@h??} @*|iht |i t@Ti Lu |i t|@|i ThUi _i?t|) TihUii_ M) ?it|Lht M) @__?} |L |@* ThLM@M*|it 6h|ih4Lhic *i@h??} igiU|t U@? }i?ih@|i 4T*i_ L*@|*|) t4*it @t i** @t @ @hi|) Lu ?L?UL?t|@?| |ih4 t|hU|hit Lu 4T*i_ L*@|*|)2 ) ?ih|?} |i hit*|?} 4L_i*c i U@? ?uih |i _)?@4Ut Lu |i T@h@4i|iht Lu |i @)it@? *i@h??} tUi4i uhL4 _@|@ L? 5: Dff ?_i LT|L? ThUit W?_iTi?_i?|*) Lu |i |4i TihL_ Lih U |iLhi|U@* LT|L? ThUit @hi 4@|Ui_ | LMtihi_ ThUitc i ?_ |@| it|4@|i_ T@h@4i|iht @hi hi4@h!@M*) t|@M*i Lih |4i @?_ |@| Lh 4L_i* ThL_it @? i Ui**i?| ?t@4T*i @?_ L|Lu t@4T*i | ? @__|L? |L }i?ih@|?} t4@**ih i_}?} ihhLht |@? |i 5 4L_i* @?_ @hLt @*|ih?@|it ThLTLti_ ? |i *|ih@|hi 5Gdv dqg Vxqgdudp +4<<<, vkrz wkdw wkh prvw srsxodu dowhuqdwlyhv wr EV mxps0glxvlrq dqg vwrfkdvwlf yrodwlolw| prghov idlo wr vlpxowdqhrxvo| jhqhudwh lpsolhg yrodwlolw| vplohv dqg whup vwuxfwxuhv wkdw pdwfk wkh frpsoh{ ihdwxuhv ri wkh gdwd1 2 Ai L|*?i Lu |i T@Tih t @t uL**Lt 5iU|L? 2 ?|hL_Uit |i _@|@ ti| @?_ Mhi) _itUhMit t)t|i4@|U M@tit ? |i 5 LT|L? ThU?} 4L_i* 5iU|L? Thiti?|t |i M?L4@* *@||Ui 4L_i* ?_ih u** ?uLh4@|L? @?_ @)it@? *i@h??} t ?|hL_Ui_ ? 5iU|L? e U @*tL _ihit i T*U| uLh4*@i uLh ,hLTi@? LT|L? ThUit 5iU|L? D U@h@U|ih3it |i i^*Mh4 igiU| Lu *i@h??} L? LT|L? ThUit @?_ U@*Mh@|it |i LT|L? ThU?} 4L_i* ?_ih *i@h??} tL | U@? Mi UL4T@hi_ |L |i _@|@ uhL4 5iU|L? 2 Ai T@h@4i|iht U@h@U|ih3?} |i 4@?|@?i_ hiUhti *i@h??} ThLUitt @hi ?uihhi_ uhL4 LT|L? ThUit ? 5iU|L? S @?_ ti_ |L Thi_U| LT|L? ThUit L|Lut@4T*i 5iU|L? . UL?U*_it 2 @tit ? |i *@U!5UL*it L_i* At tiU|L? Mhi) L|*?it |i t)t|i4@|U ThU?} M@tit ? |i 5 LT|L? ThU?} 4L_i* @?_ |t tihit @t @ Mi?U4@h! uLh |i i4ThU@* @?@*)tt h _@|@ ti| Lu LT|L? ThUit uhL4 |i , UL?tt|t Lu 5: Dff ?_i LT|L? ThUit ULih?} |i TihL_ a@? ec bb |L #iU c bb @?_ t _i?|U@* |L |@| ti_ ? |5@@*@ @?_ wL EbbH @?_ @t Mii? *|ihi_ ? |i t@4i @)e `*i |i U@*i?_@h TihL_ t hi*@|i*) tLh| UL4T@hi_ |L |@| ti_ M) #4@t i| @* EbbHc |i ?4Mih Lu LMtih@|L?t E cfbf t UL4T@h@M*i _i |L |i u@U| |@| i ti _@*) h@|ih |@? 6Dv vwuhvvhg e| Uxelqvwhlq +4<<7, wkh pdunhw iru V)S 833 lqgh{ rswlrqv rq wkh FERH surylghv d fdvh vwxg| zkhuh wkh frqglwlrqv uhtxluhg e| EV vhhp wr eh zhoo dssur{lpdwhg lq whupv ri yroxphv/ frqwlqxlw| ri wkh wudglqj surfhvv dqg khgjlqj rssruwxqlwlhv1 7Zh wkdqn \dflqh Dlw0Vdkdold iru pdnlqj klv gdwd vhw dydlodeoh wr wkh sxeolf1 Lq0wkh0prqh| rswlrqv duh wklqo| wudghg/ wkhlu sulfhv duh qrwrulrxvo| xquholdeoh dqg duh wkxv glvfdughg iurp wkh gdwd vhw1 Rxw0ri0wkh0prqh| dqg qhdu0dw0wkh0prqh| sxw sulfhv/ S / duh wudqvodwhg lqwr fdoo sulfhv/ F/ xvlqj sxw0fdoo sdulw|1 Doo lqirupdwlrq frqwdlqhg lq oltxlg sxw sulfhv kdv wkxv ehhq h{wudfwhg dqg frqyhuwhg lqwr fdoo sulfhv1 Wkh uhpdlqlqj sxw rswlrqv duh glvfdughg iurp wkh gdwd vhw zlwkrxw orvv ri lqirupdwlrq1 Zh h{solflwo| wdnh lqwr dffrxqw wkdw wkh lqgh{ sd|v rxw gdlo| glylghqgv dqg iroorz Dlw0Vdkdold dqg Or +4<<;, lq xvlqj wkh frqwlqxrxv glylghqg |lhog/ / lpsolhg e| gdlo| ydoxhv ri wkh lqgh{/ V/ dqg sulfhv ri ixwxuhv frqwudfwv/ I / ri jlyhq pdwxulw|/ 1 E| wkh vsrw0ixwxuhv sdulw| 4 V +uw> w> , w Iw> @ Vwh @, w> @ oq .
Recommended publications
  • Implied Volatility Modeling
    Implied Volatility Modeling Sarves Verma, Gunhan Mehmet Ertosun, Wei Wang, Benjamin Ambruster, Kay Giesecke I Introduction Although Black-Scholes formula is very popular among market practitioners, when applied to call and put options, it often reduces to a means of quoting options in terms of another parameter, the implied volatility. Further, the function σ BS TK ),(: ⎯⎯→ σ BS TK ),( t t ………………………………(1) is called the implied volatility surface. Two significant features of the surface is worth mentioning”: a) the non-flat profile of the surface which is often called the ‘smile’or the ‘skew’ suggests that the Black-Scholes formula is inefficient to price options b) the level of implied volatilities changes with time thus deforming it continuously. Since, the black- scholes model fails to model volatility, modeling implied volatility has become an active area of research. At present, volatility is modeled in primarily four different ways which are : a) The stochastic volatility model which assumes a stochastic nature of volatility [1]. The problem with this approach often lies in finding the market price of volatility risk which can’t be observed in the market. b) The deterministic volatility function (DVF) which assumes that volatility is a function of time alone and is completely deterministic [2,3]. This fails because as mentioned before the implied volatility surface changes with time continuously and is unpredictable at a given point of time. Ergo, the lattice model [2] & the Dupire approach [3] often fail[4] c) a factor based approach which assumes that implied volatility can be constructed by forming basis vectors. Further, one can use implied volatility as a mean reverting Ornstein-Ulhenbeck process for estimating implied volatility[5].
    [Show full text]
  • An Efficient Lattice Algorithm for the LIBOR Market Model
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Xiao, Tim Article — Accepted Manuscript (Postprint) An Efficient Lattice Algorithm for the LIBOR Market Model Journal of Derivatives Suggested Citation: Xiao, Tim (2011) : An Efficient Lattice Algorithm for the LIBOR Market Model, Journal of Derivatives, ISSN 2168-8524, Pageant Media, London, Vol. 19, Iss. 1, pp. 25-40, http://dx.doi.org/10.3905/jod.2011.19.1.025 , https://jod.iijournals.com/content/19/1/25 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/200091 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu AN EFFICIENT LATTICE ALGORITHM FOR THE LIBOR MARKET MODEL 1 Tim Xiao Journal of Derivatives, 19 (1) 25-40, Fall 2011 ABSTRACT The LIBOR Market Model has become one of the most popular models for pricing interest rate products.
    [Show full text]
  • Option Prices Under Bayesian Learning: Implied Volatility Dynamics and Predictive Densities∗
    Option Prices under Bayesian Learning: Implied Volatility Dynamics and Predictive Densities∗ Massimo Guidolin† Allan Timmermann University of Virginia University of California, San Diego JEL codes: G12, D83. Abstract This paper shows that many of the empirical biases of the Black and Scholes option pricing model can be explained by Bayesian learning effects. In the context of an equilibrium model where dividend news evolve on a binomial lattice with unknown but recursively updated probabilities we derive closed-form pricing formulas for European options. Learning is found to generate asymmetric skews in the implied volatility surface and systematic patterns in the term structure of option prices. Data on S&P 500 index option prices is used to back out the parameters of the underlying learning process and to predict the evolution in the cross-section of option prices. The proposed model leads to lower out-of- sample forecast errors and smaller hedging errors than a variety of alternative option pricing models, including Black-Scholes and a GARCH model. ∗We wish to thank four anonymous referees for their extensive and thoughtful comments that greatly improved the paper. We also thank Alexander David, Jos´e Campa, Bernard Dumas, Wake Epps, Stewart Hodges, Claudio Michelacci, Enrique Sentana and seminar participants at Bocconi University, CEMFI, University of Copenhagen, Econometric Society World Congress in Seattle, August 2000, the North American Summer meetings of the Econometric Society in College Park, June 2001, the European Finance Association meetings in Barcelona, August 2001, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, INSEAD, McGill, UCSD, Universit´edeMontreal,andUniversity of Virginia for discussions and helpful comments.
    [Show full text]
  • Term Structure Lattice Models
    Term Structure Models: IEOR E4710 Spring 2005 °c 2005 by Martin Haugh Term Structure Lattice Models 1 The Term-Structure of Interest Rates If a bank lends you money for one year and lends money to someone else for ten years, it is very likely that the rate of interest charged for the one-year loan will di®er from that charged for the ten-year loan. Term-structure theory has as its basis the idea that loans of di®erent maturities should incur di®erent rates of interest. This basis is grounded in reality and allows for a much richer and more realistic theory than that provided by the yield-to-maturity (YTM) framework1. We ¯rst describe some of the basic concepts and notation that we need for studying term-structure models. In these notes we will often assume that there are m compounding periods per year, but it should be clear what changes need to be made for continuous-time models and di®erent compounding conventions. Time can be measured in periods or years, but it should be clear from the context what convention we are using. Spot Rates: Spot rates are the basic interest rates that de¯ne the term structure. De¯ned on an annual basis, the spot rate, st, is the rate of interest charged for lending money from today (t = 0) until time t. In particular, 2 mt this implies that if you lend A dollars for t years today, you will receive A(1 + st=m) dollars when the t years have elapsed.
    [Show full text]
  • Decision Analysis and Real Options: a Discrete Time Approach to Real Option Valuation
    Annals of Operations Research 135, 21–39, 2005 c 2005 Springer Science + Business Media, Inc. Manufactured in The Netherlands. Decision Analysis and Real Options: A Discrete Time Approach to Real Option Valuation LUIZ E. BRANDAO˜ [email protected] JAMES S. DYER [email protected] The University of Texas at Austin, McCombs School of Business, Department of Management Science and Information Systems, 1 University Station B6500, CBA 5.202, Austin, TX 78712-1175 Abstract. In this paper we seek to enhance the real options methodology developed by Copeland and Antikarov (2001) with traditional decision analysis tools to propose a discrete time method that allows the problem to be specified and solved with off the shelf decision analysis software. This method uses dynamic programming with an innovative algorithm to model the project’s stochastic process and real options with decision trees. The method is computationally intense, but simpler and more intuitive than traditional methods, thus allowing for greater flexibility in the modeling of the problem. Keywords: real options, lattice methods, decision trees Introduction Due to its importance for the creation of value for the shareholder, the investment decision in the firm has always been a focus of academic and managerial interest. The use of the discounted cash flow method (DCF), introduced in firms in the 1950’s, was initially considered a sophisticated approach for the valuation of projects due to the need to use present value tables. In spite of its obvious advantages over the obsolete payback method, its widespread use occurred only after the development of portable calculators and computers that automated the necessary financial calculations, and most practitioners currently consider it the model of choice.
    [Show full text]
  • A Brief History of Active Credit Portfolio Management
    MARCH 25, 2008 A BRIEF HISTORY OF ACTIVE CREDIT PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT MODELINGMETHODOLOGY AUTHOR ABSTRACT Brian Dvorak The first commercial EDF™ (Expected Default Frequency) credit measure model was released by KMV in 1990, although its foundations in extending the Merton model date from the early 1980s. In those early days, KMV found that it was not easy to convince credit officers that there was a better way to assess the credit risk of publicly-listed firms compared to their traditional credit analyses. The EDF model is now in use at hundreds of institutions worldwide, and Moody’s KMV EDF credit measures are produced daily on more than 30,500 listed firms in 58 countries. This paper addresses the following questions: What are the origins of active credit portfolio management? How did the practice start, how has it evolved, and what can we see on the horizon? Copyright© 2008, Moody’s KMV Company. All rights reserved. Credit Monitor, CreditEdge, CreditEdge Plus, CreditMark, DealAnalyzer, EDFCalc, Private Firm Model, Portfolio Preprocessor, GCorr, the Moody’s KMV logo, Moody’s KMV Financial Analyst, Moody’s KMV LossCalc, Moody’s KMV Portfolio Manager, Moody’s KMV Risk Advisor, Moody’s KMV RiskCalc, RiskAnalyst, RiskFrontier, Expected Default Frequency, and EDF are trademarks owned by of MIS Quality Management Corp. and used under license by Moody’s KMV Company. Published by: Moody’s KMV Company To contact Moody’s KMV, visit us online at www.moodyskmv.com. You can also contact Moody’s KMV through e-mail at [email protected], or call us by using the following phone numbers: NORTH AND SOUTH AMERICA, NEW ZEALAND, AND AUSTRALIA: 1 866 321 MKMV (6568) or 415 874 6000 EUROPE, THE MIDDLE EAST, AFRICA, AND INDIA: 44 20 7280 8300 ASIA-PACIFIC: 852 3551 3000 JAPAN: 81 3 5408 4250 TABLE OF CONTENTS 1 THE ROLE OF KMV IN THE ORIGINS OF CREDIT PORTFOLIO MODELING ...........
    [Show full text]
  • A Simple Model for Pricing Securities with Equity, Interest-Rate, and Default Risk∗
    A Simple Model for Pricing Securities with Equity, Interest-Rate, and Default Risk∗ Sanjiv R. Das Rangarajan K. Sundaram Santa Clara University New York University Santa Clara, CA 95053 New York, NY 10012. June 2002, November 2003; Current version: October 2004. ∗The authors’ respective e-mail addresses are [email protected], and [email protected]. We owe a huge debt of grati- tude for extensive discussions and correspondence with Suresh Sundaresan and Mehrdad Noorani. We are very grateful for the use of data from CreditMetrics. Our thanks also to Jan Ericsson, Kian Esteghamat, Rong Fan, Gary Geng, and Maxime Popineau for several helpful comments. The paper benefitted from the comments of seminar participants at York University, New York University, University of Oklahoma, Stanford University, Santa Clara University, Universita La Sapienza, Cred- itMetrics, MKMV Corp., the 2003 European Finance Association Meetings in Glasgow, Morgan Stanley, Archeus Capital Management, Lehman Brothers, and University of Massachusetts, Amherst. 1 Equity, Interest-rate, Default Risk . .2 A Simple Model for Pricing Securities with Equity, Interest-Rate, and Default Risk Abstract We develop a model for pricing derivative and hybrid securities whose value may depend on dif- ferent sources of risk, namely, equity, interest-rate, and default risks. In addition to valuing such secu- rities the framework is also useful for extracting probabilities of default (PD) functions from market data. Our model is not based on the stochastic process for the value of the firm, which is unobservable, but on the stochastic processes for interest rates and the equity price, which are observable. The model comprises a risk-neutral setting in which the joint process of interest rates and equity are modeled to- gether with the default conditions for security payoffs.
    [Show full text]
  • An Actuarial Layman's Guide to Building Stochastic Interest Rate Generators
    VII An Actuarial Layman's Guide to Building Stochastic Interest Rate Generators James A. Tilley Abstract 1. Introduction A stochastic interest rate generator is a valuable In recent years, the literature of financial economics actuarial tool. The parameters that specify a stochastic has featured papers on how to value interest-rate-con- model of interest rates can be adjusted to make the tingent claims by means of option-pricing models (for model arbitrage-free, or they can be adjusted to accom- example, [2], [8], [11], [14], and [18]). The most impor- modate an individual investor's subjective views. The tant applications include the pricing of fixed-income arbitrage-free settings of the parameters must be used instruments with embedded options: callable corporate when pricing streams of interest-rate-contingent cash bonds, mortgage-backed securities subject to prepay- flows, for example, when establishing the risk-neutral ment risk, collateralized mortgage obligations (CMOs) position for asset-liability management. The real-world created by allocating the cash flows arising from pools settings of the parameters should be used when evaluat- of mortgages to different classes of bonds, floating-rate ing the risk-reward tradeoffs inherent in deviating from and other indexed bonds, and various hedging instru- the risk-neutral position. ments, such as futures, options, and interest rate swaps, Without relying on formulas, this paper presents the caps, and floors. Life insurers have begun to use option- important concepts underlying the theory
    [Show full text]
  • Financial Lexicon a Compendium of Financial Definitions, Acronyms, and Colloquialisms
    Financial Lexicon A compendium of financial definitions, acronyms, and colloquialisms Erik Banks Financial Lexicon A compendium of financial definitions, acronyms, and colloquialisms ERIK BANKS © Erik Banks 2005 All rights reserved. No reproduction, copy or transmission of this publication may be made without written permission. No paragraph of this publication may be reproduced, copied or transmitted save with written permission or in accordance with the provisions of the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988, or under the terms of any licence permitting limited copying issued by the Copyright Licensing Agency, 90 Tottenham Court Road, London W1T 4LP. Any person who does any unauthorised act in relation to this publication may be liable to criminal prosecution and civil claims for damages. The author has asserted his right to be identified as the author of this work in accordance with the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988. First published 2005 by PALGRAVE MACMILLAN Houndmills, Basingstoke, Hampshire RG21 6XS and 175 Fifth Avenue, New York, N.Y.10010 Companies and representatives throughout the world PALGRAVE MACMILLAN is the global academic imprint of the Palgrave Macmillan division of St. Martin’s Press, LLC and of Palgrave Macmillan Ltd. Macmillan® is a registered trademark in the United States, United Kingdom and other countries. Palgrave is a registered trademark in the European Union and other countries. ISBN 1–4039–3609–9 This book is printed on paper suitable for recycling and made from fully managed and sustained forest sources. A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library. A catalog record for this book is available from the Library of Congress.
    [Show full text]
  • MANAGEMENT SCIENCE Informs ® Vol
    MANAGEMENT SCIENCE informs ® Vol. 53, No. 9, September 2007, pp. 1439–1451 doi 10.1287/mnsc.1070.0702 issn 0025-1909 eissn 1526-5501 07 5309 1439 © 2007 INFORMS An Integrated Model for Hybrid Securities Sanjiv R. Das Leavey School of Business, Santa Clara University, Santa Clara, California 95053, [email protected] Rangarajan K. Sundaram Department of Finance, Stern School of Business, New York University, New York, New York 10012, [email protected] e develop a model for pricing securities whose value may depend simultaneously on equity, interest- Wrate, and default risks. The framework may also be used to extract probabilities of default (PD) functions from market data. Our approach is entirely based on observables such as equity prices and interest rates, rather than on unobservable processes such as firm value. The model stitches together in an arbitrage-free setting a constant elasticity of variance (CEV) equity model (to represent the behavior of equity prices prior to default), a default intensity process, and a Heath-Jarrow-Morton (HJM) model for the evolution of riskless interest rates. The model captures several stylized features such as a negative relation between equity prices and equity volatility, a negative relation between default intensity and equity prices, and a positive relationship between default intensity and equity volatility. We embed the model on a discrete-time, recombining lattice, making implementation feasible with polynomial complexity. We demonstrate the simplicity of calibrating the model to market data and of using it to extract default information. The framework is extensible to handling correlated default risk and may be used to value distressed convertible bonds, debt-equity swaps, and credit portfolio products such as collateralized debt obligations (CDOs).
    [Show full text]
  • A Review of the Binomial and Trinomial Models for Option Pricing and Their Convergence to the Black-Scholes Model Determined Option Prices
    A REVIEW OF THE BINOMIAL AND TRINOMIAL MODELS FOR OPTION PRICING AND THEIR CONVERGENCE TO THE BLACK-SCHOLES MODEL DETERMINED OPTION PRICES Dushko Josheski Business Administration, University Goce Delchev, Stip, Macedonia e-mail: [email protected] ORCID: 0000-0002-7771-7910 Mico Apostolov Business Administration, University Goce Delchev, Stip, Macedonia e-mail: [email protected] ORCID: 0000-0003-3697-1346 © 2020 Dushko Josheski, Mico Apostolov This is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial- -NoDerivs license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/3.0/) DOI: 10.15611/eada.2020.2.05 JEL Classification: C5, C57 Abstract: This paper reviews the binomial and trinomial option pricing models and their convergence to the Black-Scholes model result. These models are generalized for the European and American options. The trinomial models are said to be more accurate than the binomial when fewer steps are modelled. These models are widely used for the usual vanilla option types, European or American options, that respectively can be exercised only at the expiration date and at any time before the expiration date. The results are supportive of the conventional wisdom that trinomial option pricing models such as the Kamrad-Ritchken model and the Boyle model are converging faster than the binomial models. When binomial models are compared in terms of convergence, the most efficient model is the Jarrow-Rudd model. This paper concludes that improved binomial models such as the Haahtela model are converging faster to the BS model result. After some trials, binomial distribution follows log-normal distribution assumed by the Black-Scholes model.
    [Show full text]
  • Copyrighted Material
    Index Accounting standards, 68n Arbitrage cash CDOs, 244–247 Accounting volatility, absence. See Synthetic CDOs assets, 245–246 Accretion-directed bonds, 50–55 fl owchart, 245f classes legal structure, 245 creation, 51 reinvestment period, 246 specialization, 54 returns, 246–247 Accretion process, 50 Arbitrage CDOs, 215–216, 243–249 Accrual bonds (Z bonds), 50–55 assets, purchase, 216 class examples, 243 structure, comparison, 52 issuance, capability, 243–244 structuring, 54 pooling process, profi t source, 243 lockout period, months (number), 51 purpose, 243–244 par value, lockout period (addition), 50 relevance, 219–220 Actual/365 day count, usage. See Sterling-denomi- returns, 246–247 nated swaps example, 247t Administrative agent. See Asset-backed commercial Arbitrage conduits, 173 paper S&P defi nition, 172 duties, 179. See also Commercial paper Arbitrage-free model, 331 role, 180 Arbitrage synthetic CDOs, 247–249 Administrative receivership, usage, 199–200 collateral manager, appointment, 248 Agency CMOs creation, 248–249 creation, 65 fl owchart, 249t qualifi cation, 31n. See also Nonagency CMOs income, 248–249 usage, 75 ramp-up period, 248 Agency costs, reduction, 284 Arbitraging, purpose, 314–315 Agency deals, 22n Asset-aging analysis, usage. See Servicers arbitrage transactions, 65 Asset-backed bonds, 10 structuring, 34, 38 Asset-backed commercial paper Agency MBS deals, structuring, 31 placement agent, involvement, 180 summary, 61–64 Asset-backed commercial paper (ABCP), 10 Agency passthrough securities, valuation alterna- administrative agent, involvement, 179–180 tive, 329n bank usage, 170 Agreed-upon periodic interest rate, 101–102 collateral, 174 American Skandia Life Assurance Company (ASLAC), deleverage triggers, usage, 176–177 securitization transactions issuance, 205 initiation, 170 Amortization issuance programs, 170 calculation, 35 issuing agent, involvement, 180 triggers.
    [Show full text]