The Next Consumer Recession Preparing

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Next Consumer Recession Preparing The next consumer recession Preparing now UntappedThe next consumer potential recession| Finding of | Preparingthe 2016 Deloitte now Customs and Global Trade Management Benchmarking Survey Some say that we’re in a charmed, “Goldilocks” moment in the economic cycle: growth that’s neither too hot, nor too cold. But will this fairy tale end in the arms of a handsome prince—or in the jaws of a wolf in sheep’s clothing? 02 Untapped potential | Finding of the 2016 Deloitte Customs and GlobalThe next Trade consumer Management recession Benchmarking | Preparing Survey now Hard to believe, but it’s been 10 years since the collapse of Lehman Brothers, an event that helped trigger the 2008 economic meltdown. That recession, commonly referred to as the “Great Recession,” has become a defining moment for an entire generation. And the recovery that followed has proved equally unique, characterized by a measured pace of growth, stubbornly high unemployment figures, and slow wage growth. Many consumer companies struggled along with the economy, experiencing weak growth and strained profitability. This was compounded by industry- wide structural changes, allowing consumers greater access and choice. For some companies, this period of accelerating competition ushered in a boom, for others gloom, and for still others doom. Recently, however, the business environment has improved markedly: consumer confidence and spending are up, unemployment is at historic lows, and inflation appears to be relatively tame.1 After years of disappointing financials, some retailers are releasing increasingly upbeat results. Some economists are beginning to refer to the current stage of the recovery as a “Goldilocks economy”: not too hot, not too cold—just right. So what's the data saying: Is that really Grandma standing there before our eyes—or are we about to find ourselves face-to-face with the Big Bad Wolf of recession? 1 The next consumer recession | Preparing now Once upon a time... Since World War II, the US economy has faced 12 recessions, Individually, any one of these indicators is reason for caution; or one every 6.1 years on average, with the longest interval in concert, they could push a vulnerable economy over the between downturns clocking in at 10 years (1991–2001).2 We edge. History tells us that when the economy is strongest is currently find ourselves nearly 10 years since the end of the when we have to increase our sensitivity to a downturn. last downturn. Recessions don’t ring the doorbell and announce “I can predict with 100% themselves. But there are signs that the Evil Witch may be trying to poison the recovery: accuracy that the US • Flattening yield curve. An inverted yield curve (where yields on short-term T-bills exceed the yields on long-term economy will face another Treasuries) has historically been a leading indicator of recessions. The current yield curve has been flattening, recession, I just can’t and in turn the probability of a recession is on the rise.3 predict when.” • Tightening monetary policy. After a long period of accommodative policy, the Fed has been hiking the —Danny Bachman, Deloitte’s US fed funds rate, which usually leads to restrictive credit conditions. In fact, every recession since 1955 has been Economic Forecaster preceded by a period of tightening monetary policy and an increase in the fed funds rate.4 • Ultra-low unemployment. Low unemployment (the lowest since the months directly preceding the 2001 and 1970 recessions5) and rising wages are introducing inflationary pressures. That could spur the Fed to raise rates more aggressively, slowing economic growth. • Rising asset prices. Price-to-earnings (P/E) ratios of equities are 55 percent higher than their long-term average.6 If the stock market corrects, it will likely push down consumer confidence and consumer spending, which could trigger a recession. 2 The next consumer recession | Preparing now Watch out for the Big Bad Wolf The question facing consumer companies is simple: Are we “The four most expensive entering into an extended growth period or should we be preparing for a coming recession? The answer to this words in the English question can be paramount in setting strategy. language are, ‘This time it’s To explore the options that lie before the sector, we think it’s helpful to use a tale of two recessions as our looking different.’” glass: the dot-com bust (2001) and the Great Recession (2008–2009). —Sir John Templeton 3 The next consumer recession | Preparing now Mirror, mirror Each recession has its own triggers, characteristics, and paths to recovery. To grasp what the 2001 and 2008 recessions can teach us, we need to look into the mirror of time (see table 1). Table 1. Twenty-first-century recessions7 Dot-com bust Great Recession Housing market crash and interconnectedness of Cause Reaction to overvalued tech stocks. underlying investments. Relatively shallow, with impact concentrated in Global in reach and strongly affected all sectors of Reach business investment. the economy. Corporate profits Down 0.2% peak to trough. Down 13.5% peak to trough. Wages and salaries Down 0.9% peak to trough. Down 4.5% peak to trough. Spending on nonresidential investment fell 6.4% Spending on nonresidential investment fell 15.6% Business investment peak to trough. peak to trough. Spending on consumer goods grew slowly through Spending on consumer goods contracted 8.6% Consumer spending the downturn (up 0.6% peak to trough). peak to trough. Labor market Unemployment reached 6.3%. Unemployment reached 10.0%. The 2001 (dot-com) recession began in March 2001 in The 2008 recession (Great Recession) was different. The reaction to excessive investing in technology by businesses soaring housing market triggered the Great Recession in 2008. and an overvaluation of dot-com stocks. As a result, the 2001 But unlike the crash in dot-com stocks in 2001, the complex recession reverberated more deeply on Wall Street and in financial instruments used to fuel the real estate boom, and the business world than on Main Street and in the consumer the interconnectedness of the US and global financial systems, sector. That’s not to say households were unaffected: did the most damage. The complex interplay between physical unemployment rose from a low of 3.8 percent in spring assets, synthetic derivatives, and global financial markets 2000 to 6.3 percent in June 2003. But while consumer followed by a severe credit crunch made the Great Recession income growth took a hit, it soon bounced back, though ubiquitous. Consumers were rocked to their very core: not equally for everyone. Unemployment shot up to 10 percent, labor force participation fell off a cliff, and consumer confidence plummeted.8 4 The next consumer recession | Preparing now Who’s the fairest of them all? Figure 1. Change in discretionary income The two recessions of the twenty-first century were quite different in cause, effect, and magnitude of impact. We tend Dot-com cycle Great Recession cycle to gloss over the granular details of the recovery and discuss (1999–2006) (2007–2017) the rebound in terms of averages—but those numbers may $31K not tell the full story of a recovery. To look at the process of consumer recovery in a more $18K granular way, we broke down the averages. We used the US Census department’s definition of low-, middle-, and $9K high-income households (less than $50,000; $50,000 $4K $2K to $100,000; more than $100,000) to see how different groups benefited from the business cycle upswing. While the change in income across the three groups was telling, ($3K) we dug deeper and looked at discretionary income to Low income (<$50K) understand what consumers really have available to spend on retail and other consumer categories (see figure 1). Middle income ($50K–$100K) High income ($100K+) What emerged was an alarming pattern for consumers: The vast majority of the US population has not materially Source: US Census Bureau and US Bureau of Labor Statistics. participated in either of the two most recent recovery periods. After both twenty-first-century recessions, the The result was a very different consumer in the wake of upper-income bracket showed significant discretionary the downturns. income growth. The same pattern held true after the Great Recession. However, a substantial portion of the US consumer base—consisting of the low- and middle-income A majority of the US consumer base groups—is not materially better off today than they were nearly two decades ago. This income bifurcation—more failed to participate fully in the recoveries than region, gender, or generation—has impacted that followed, leaving a very different 9 spending patterns. consumer in the wake of the two most recent downturns. 5 The next consumer recession | Preparing now Into the woods As we studied the two most recent downturns and tried Growth in e-commerce and digital business to determine the true impact on the consumer sector, we The hype around dot-com companies and e-commerce was were surprised by what the data told us. Of course we found a major theme in the early 2000s. E-commerce continued the normal downturn in revenues, pressure on margins, its steady ascent despite the dot-com bubble bursting, and increase in bankruptcies and store closings. But what which some took as a sign of the death of the e-commerce was more surprising was the degree to which the structural promise. Many industry experts struggled to forecast change of the industry not only continued unabated e-commerce growth at this time, with the commonly held during the periods of downturn, but actually appeared belief that e-commerce growth would flatten, sales would to accelerate, leaving many of those that failed to reposition eventually hit a ceiling, and a new normal would then during the downturn even more exposed when the be established.
Recommended publications
  • COVID-19 and Economic Policy Toward the New Normal: a Monetary-Fiscal Nexus After the Crisis?
    IN-DEPTH ANALYSIS Requested by the ECON committee Monetar y Dialogue Papers, November 2020 COVID-19 and Economic Policy Toward the New Normal: A Monetary-Fiscal Nexus after the Crisis? Policy Department for Economic, Scientific and Quality of Life Policies Directorate-General for Internal Policies Author: Thomas MARMEFELT EN PE 658.193 - November 2020 COVID-19 and Economic Policy Toward the New Normal: A Monetary-Fiscal Nexus after the Crisis? Monetary Dialogue Papers, November 2020 Abstract Current developments during the COVID-19 pandemic involve strongly complementary monetary and fiscal policy, but both as responses to COVID-19 and not the outcome of an emergent monetary-fiscal nexus. Therefore, the ECB maintains its independence by using unconventional monetary policy measures to reach price stability, according to its mandate. This document was provided by the Policy Department for Economic, Scientific and Quality of Life Policies at the request of the Committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs (ECON) ahead of the Monetary Dialogue with the ECB President on 19 November 2020. This document was requested by the European Parliament's committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs (ECON). AUTHOR Thomas MARMEFELT, CASE – Center for Social and Economic Research (Warsaw, Poland) and University of Södertörn (Huddinge, Sweden) ADMINISTRATOR RESPONSIBLE Drazen RAKIC EDITORIAL ASSISTANT Janetta CUJKOVA LINGUISTIC VERSIONS Original: EN ABOUT THE EDITOR Policy departments provide in-house and external expertise to support European Parliament committees
    [Show full text]
  • A Structural Model of the Unemployment Insurance Take-Up
    A Structural Model of the Unemployment Insurance Take-up Sylvie Blasco∗ Fran¸coisFontainey GAINS, University of Aarhus, BETA-CNRS, CREST and IZA LMDG and IZA. January 2012 - IN PROGRESSz Abstract A large fraction of the eligible workers do not claim the unemployment insurance when they are unemployed. This paper provides a structural framework to identify clearly, through the esti- mates, the economic mechanisms behind take-up. It incorporates take-up in a job search model and accounts for the determinants of claiming, especially the level of the unemployment benefits and the practical difficulties to make a claim. It provides a simple way to model selection into participation and sheds new light on the link between the job search and the claiming efforts. We estimate our model using a unique administrative dataset that matches a linked employer - employee data and the records of the national employment agency. Keywords: Unemployment Insurance Take-up, Job Search JEL Classification numbers: J64, J65, C41 ∗Address : Universit´e du Maine, Av. Olivier Messiaen, 72085 Le Mans Cedex 9, France ; Email: [email protected] yUniversity of Nancy 2, Email: [email protected]. zWe thank Jesper Bagger, Sebastian Buhai, Sam Kortum, David Margolis, Dale Mortensen, Fabien Postel-Vinay, Jean-Marc Robin, Chris Taber and participants at the Tinbergen Institute internal seminar, CREST-INSEE, Nancy and Royal Holloway seminars, the ESEM conference, the AFSE, IZA-Labor Market Policy Evalation, LMDG, T2M workshops for comments and discussions. This is a preliminary version of the paper, the readers are invited to check on the authors' websites for newer versions.
    [Show full text]
  • Research & Policy Brief No.47
    Research & Policy Briefs From the World Bank Malaysia Hub No. 47 May 24, 2021 Demand and Supply Dynamics in East Asia during the COVID-19 Recession Ergys Islamaj, Franz Ulrich Ruch, and Eka Vashakmadze The COVID-19 pandemic has devastated lives and damaged economies, requiring strong and decisive policy responses from governments. Developing Public Disclosure Authorized the optimal short-term and long-term policy response to the pandemic requires understanding the demand and supply factors that drive economic growth. The appropriate policy response will depend on the size and duration of demand and supply shocks. This Research & Policy Brief provides a decomposition of demand and supply dynamics at the macroeconomic level for the large developing economies of East Asia. The findings suggest that both demand and supply shocks were important drivers of output fluctuations during the first year of the pandemic. The demand shocks created an environment of deficient demand—reflected in large negative output gaps even after the unprecedented policy response—which is expected to last through 2021. The extant deficient demand is suggestive of continued need to support the economic recovery. Its size should guide policy makers in calibrating responses to ensure that recovery is entrenched, and that short-term supply disruptions do not lead to long-term declines in potential growth. The Pandemic-Induced Shock Low external demand will continue to affect economies reliant on tourism, while sluggish domestic demand will disproportionally affect The pandemic, national lockdowns, and reverberations from the rest economies with large services sectors. Understanding the demand of the world inflicted a massive shock to the East Asia and Pacific and supply factors that drive economic growth is critical for region in 2020 (World Bank 2020a).
    [Show full text]
  • Epidemics in the Neoclassical and New Keynesian Models∗†
    Epidemics in the Neoclassical and New Keynesian Models∗† Martin S. Eichenbaum‡ Sergio Rebelo§ Mathias Trabandt¶ June 19, 2020 Abstract We analyze the e§ects of an epidemic in three standard macroeconomic models. We find that the neoclassical model does not rationalize the positive comovement of consumption and investment observed in recessions associated with an epidemic. Intro- ducing monopolistic competition into the neoclassical model remedies this shortcoming even when prices are completely flexible. Finally, sticky prices lead to a larger recession but do not fundamentally alter the predictions of the monopolistic competition model. JEL Classification: E1, I1, H0 Keywords: Epidemic, comovement, investment, recession. ∗We thank R. Anton Braun, Joao Guerreiro, Martín Harding, Laura Murphy, and Hannah Seidl for helpful comments. †Matlab/Dynare replication codes will be made available by the end of June 2020 at the following URL: https://sites.google.com/site/mathiastrabandt/home/research ‡Northwestern University and NBER. Address: Northwestern University, Department of Economics, 2211 Campus Dr, Evanston, IL 60208. USA. E-mail: [email protected]. §Northwestern University, NBER, and CEPR. Address: Northwestern University, Kellogg School of Man- agement, 2211 Campus Dr, Evanston, IL 60208. USA. E-mail: [email protected]. ¶Freie Universität Berlin, School of Business and Economics, Chair of Macroeconomics. Address: Boltz- mannstrasse 20, 14195 Berlin, Germany, German Institute for Economic Research (DIW) and Halle Institute for Economic Research (IWH), E-mail: [email protected]. 1Introduction Acentralfeatureofrecessionsisthepositivecomovementbetweenoutput,hoursworked, consumption, and investment. In this respect, the COVID-19 recession is not unique. At least since Barro and King (1984), it has been recognized that, absent aggregate productivity shocks, it is di¢cult for many models to generate comovement in macroeconomic aggregates.
    [Show full text]
  • Reducing Income Inequality While Boosting Economic Growth: Can It Be Done?
    Economic Policy Reforms 2012 Going for Growth © OECD 2012 PART II Chapter 5 Reducing income inequality while boosting economic growth: Can it be done? This chapter identifies inequality patterns across OECD countries and provides new analysis of their policy and non-policy drivers. One key finding is that education and anti-discrimination policies, well-designed labour market institutions and large and/or progressive tax and transfer systems can all reduce income inequality. On this basis, the chapter identifies several policy reforms that could yield a double dividend in terms of boosting GDP per capita and reducing income inequality, and also flags other policy areas where reforms would entail a trade-off between both objectives. 181 II.5. REDUCING INCOME INEQUALITY WHILE BOOSTING ECONOMIC GROWTH: CAN IT BE DONE? Summary and conclusions In many OECD countries, income inequality has increased in past decades. In some countries, top earners have captured a large share of the overall income gains, while for others income has risen only a little. There is growing consensus that assessments of economic performance should not focus solely on overall income growth, but also take into account income distribution. Some see poverty as the relevant concern while others are concerned with income inequality more generally. A key question is whether the type of growth-enhancing policy reforms advocated for each OECD country and the BRIICS in Going for Growth might have positive or negative side effects on income inequality. More broadly, in pursuing growth and redistribution strategies simultaneously, policy makers need to be aware of possible complementarities or trade-offs between the two objectives.
    [Show full text]
  • The Socialization of Investment, from Keynes to Minsky and Beyond
    Working Paper No. 822 The Socialization of Investment, from Keynes to Minsky and Beyond by Riccardo Bellofiore* University of Bergamo December 2014 * [email protected] This paper was prepared for the project “Financing Innovation: An Application of a Keynes-Schumpeter- Minsky Synthesis,” funded in part by the Institute for New Economic Thinking, INET grant no. IN012-00036, administered through the Levy Economics Institute of Bard College. Co-principal investigators: Mariana Mazzucato (Science Policy Research Unit, University of Sussex) and L. Randall Wray (Levy Institute). The author thanks INET and the Levy Institute for support of this research. The Levy Economics Institute Working Paper Collection presents research in progress by Levy Institute scholars and conference participants. The purpose of the series is to disseminate ideas to and elicit comments from academics and professionals. Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, founded in 1986, is a nonprofit, nonpartisan, independently funded research organization devoted to public service. Through scholarship and economic research it generates viable, effective public policy responses to important economic problems that profoundly affect the quality of life in the United States and abroad. Levy Economics Institute P.O. Box 5000 Annandale-on-Hudson, NY 12504-5000 http://www.levyinstitute.org Copyright © Levy Economics Institute 2014 All rights reserved ISSN 1547-366X Abstract An understanding of, and an intervention into, the present capitalist reality requires that we put together the insights of Karl Marx on labor, as well as those of Hyman Minsky on finance. The best way to do this is within a longer-term perspective, looking at the different stages through which capitalism evolves.
    [Show full text]
  • Demand Composition and the Strength of Recoveries†
    Demand Composition and the Strength of Recoveriesy Martin Beraja Christian K. Wolf MIT & NBER MIT & NBER September 17, 2021 Abstract: We argue that recoveries from demand-driven recessions with ex- penditure cuts concentrated in services or non-durables will tend to be weaker than recoveries from recessions more biased towards durables. Intuitively, the smaller the bias towards more durable goods, the less the recovery is buffeted by pent-up demand. We show that, in a standard multi-sector business-cycle model, this prediction holds if and only if, following an aggregate demand shock to all categories of spending (e.g., a monetary shock), expenditure on more durable goods reverts back faster. This testable condition receives ample support in U.S. data. We then use (i) a semi-structural shift-share and (ii) a structural model to quantify this effect of varying demand composition on recovery dynamics, and find it to be large. We also discuss implications for optimal stabilization policy. Keywords: durables, services, demand recessions, pent-up demand, shift-share design, recov- ery dynamics, COVID-19. JEL codes: E32, E52 yEmail: [email protected] and [email protected]. We received helpful comments from George-Marios Angeletos, Gadi Barlevy, Florin Bilbiie, Ricardo Caballero, Lawrence Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum, Fran¸coisGourio, Basile Grassi, Erik Hurst, Greg Kaplan, Andrea Lanteri, Jennifer La'O, Alisdair McKay, Simon Mongey, Ernesto Pasten, Matt Rognlie, Alp Simsek, Ludwig Straub, Silvana Tenreyro, Nicholas Tra- chter, Gianluca Violante, Iv´anWerning, Johannes Wieland (our discussant), Tom Winberry, Nathan Zorzi and seminar participants at various venues, and we thank Isabel Di Tella for outstanding research assistance.
    [Show full text]
  • Predicting Recessions: Financial Cycle Versus Term Spread
    BIS Working Papers No 818 Predicting recessions: financial cycle versus term spread by Claudio Borio, Mathias Drehmann and Dora Xia Monetary and Economic Department October 2019 JEL classification: C33, E37, E44 Keywords: financial cycle, term spread, recession risk, panel probit model BIS Working Papers are written by members of the Monetary and Economic Department of the Bank for International Settlements, and from time to time by other economists, and are published by the Bank. The papers are on subjects of topical interest and are technical in character. The views expressed in them are those of their authors and not necessarily the views of the BIS. This publication is available on the BIS website (www.bis.org). © Bank for International Settlements 2019. All rights reserved. Brief excerpts may be reproduced or translated provided the source is stated. ISSN 1020-0959 (print) ISSN 1682-7678 (online) Predicting recessions: financial cycle versus term spread1 Claudio Borio, Mathias Drehmann and Dora Xia2 Abstract Financial cycles can be important drivers of real activity, but there is scant evidence about how well they signal recession risks. We run a horse race between the term spread – the most widely used indicator in the literature – and a range of financial cycle measures. Unlike most papers, ours assesses forecasting performance not just for the United States but also for a panel of advanced and emerging market economies. We find that financial cycle measures have significant forecasting power both in and out of sample, even for a three-year horizon. Moreover, they outperform the term spread in nearly all specifications.
    [Show full text]
  • How Would Modern Macroeconomic Schools of Thought Respond to the Recent Economic Crisis?
    ® Economic Information Newsletter Liber8 Brought to You by the Research Library of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis November 2009 How Would Modern Macroeconomic Schools of Thought Respond to the Recent Economic Crisis? “Would financial markets and the economy have been better off if the Fed pursued a policy of quantitative easing sooner?” —Daniel L. Thornton, Vice President and Economic Adviser, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Economic Synopses The government and the Federal Reserve’s response to the current recession continues to be hotly de bated. Several questions arise: Was a $780 billion economic stimulus bill appropriate? Was the Troubled Asset Re lief Program (TARP) beneficial? Should the Fed have increased the money supply sooner? Should Lehman Brothers have been allowed to fail? Some answers to these questions lie in economic theory, and whether prudent decisions were made depends on whom you ask. This article examines three modern schools of economic thought and how each school would advise was the best way to respond to the most recent crisis. The New Keynesian Approach New Keynesian economics, the “new” version of the school based on the works of the early twentieth- century economist John Maynard Keynes, is founded on two major assumptions. First, people are forward looking; that is, they use available information today (interest rates, stock prices, gas prices, and so on) to form expectations about the future. Second, prices and wages are “sticky,” meaning they adjust gradually. One example of “stickiness” is a union-negotiated contract, which is fixed for a definite period of time. Menus are also an example of price stickiness: The cost associated with reprinting menus causes a restaurant owner to be reluctant about replacing them.
    [Show full text]
  • A Glossary of Fiscal Terms & Acronyms
    AUGUST7,1998VOLUME13,NO .VII A Publication of the House Fiscal Analysis Department on Government Finance Issues A GLOSSARY OF FISCAL TERMS & ACRONYMS 1998 Revised Edition Abstract. This issue of Money Matters is a resource document containing terms and acronyms commonly used by and in legislative fiscal committees and in the discussion of state budget and tax issues. The first section contains terms and abbreviations used in all fiscal committees and divisions. The remaining sections contain terms for particular budget categories and accounts, organized according to fiscal subject areas. This edition has new sections containing economic development, family and early childhood, and housing terms and acronyms. The other sections are revised and updated to reflect changes in terminology, particularly the human services section. For further information, contact the Chief Fiscal Analyst or the fiscal analyst assigned to the respective House fiscal committee or division. A directory of House Fiscal Analysis Department personnel and their committee/division assignments for the 1998 legislative session appears on the next page. Originally issued January 1997 Revised August 1998 House Fiscal Analysis Department Staff Assignments — 1998 Session Committee/Division Fiscal Analyst Telephone Room Chief Fiscal Analyst Bill Marx 296-7176 373 Capital Investment John Walz 296-8236 376 EDIT— Economic Development Finance CJ Eisenbarth Hager 296-5813 428 EDIT— Housing Finance Cynthia Coronado 296-5384 361 Environment & Natural Resources Finance Jim Reinholdz 296-4119 370 Education — Higher Education Finance Doug Berg 296-5346 372 K-12 Education Finance Greg Crowe 296-7165 378 Family & Early Childhood Finance Cynthia Coronado 296-5384 361 Health & Human Services Finance Joe Flores 296-5483 385 Judiciary Finance Gary Karger 296-4181 383 State Government Finance Helen Roberts 296-4117 374 Transportation Finance John Walz 296-8236 376 Taxes — Income, sales, misc.
    [Show full text]
  • The Theory of Distribution Francis Y
    The Theory of Distribution Francis Y. Edgeworth Quarterly Journal of Economics, February, 1904. Distribution is the species of Exchange by which produce is divided between the parties who have contributed to its production.1 Exchange being divided according as both, or one only, or neither of the parties have competitors, Distribution is similarly divided. The case in which both parties have competitors will here be first and principally considered. The simplest type of this distributive exchange would be of a kind which is effected once for all, without reference to a series of future productions and exchanges. For example, to adapt an illustration used by Mr. Henry George,2 let it be supposed that on a particular occasion each out of a number of white men hires one or more black men to assist in catching seals, on the agreement that each white man shall give his black assistants a certain proportion of the take, the terms having been settled in an open market in which any one white is free to bid against any other white and any one black against any other black. A conception more appropriate to existing industry is that each white agrees to pay in exchange for a certain amount of service a definite quantity of produce, not in general limited to the result of a particular operation. On a particular day less seal may be taken than the employer has agreed to give the employee for the day. In this case, even if payment is not made till the end of the day, the employer must pay for help on a particular day in part with seal caught on a previous day.
    [Show full text]
  • Key Areas of Economic Analysis of Projects: an Overview
    KEY AREAS OF EcoNOMIC ANALYSIS OF PROJECTS An Overview ECONOMIC ANALYSIS AND OPERATIONS SUPPORT DIVISION (EREA) ECONOMICS AND RESEARCH DEPARTMENT (ERD) June 2004 CONTENTS INTRODUCTION PART I: SCOPE OF PROJECT ECONOMIC ANALYSIS 2 PART II: THE 10 AREAS OF ANALYSIS 10 1. Assess Macroeconomic Context 10 2. Assess Sector Context 11 3. Assess Demand 12 4. Identify Economic Rationale 13 5. Identify Project Alternatives 13 6. Identify and Compare Benefits and Costs 14 7. Assess Financial and Institutional Sustainability 15 8. Undertake Distribution Analysis 16 9. Undertake Sensitivity and Risk Analyses 16 10. Establish a Project Performance Monitoring System (PPMS) 17 PART Ill: AREAS OF ANALYSIS IN ADB's PROJECT PROCESSING CYCLE 18 6. Identification of Costs and Benefits 7. Fiscal/Financial Sustainability 8. Distribution Analysis 9. Sensitivity and Risk Analyses 10. Project Performance Monitoring System INTRODUCTION conomic analysis of projects helps identify and Eselect public investments that will sustainably improve the welfare of beneficiaries and a country as a whole. This 2"d edition pamphlet1 outlines key areas of economic analysis of projects. It stresses that analysis begins during country strategy studies and programming, when projects are identified, and continues iteratively throughout the project cycle. Economic analysis is coordinated with institutional, financial, environmental, social, and poverty analyses, forming an integral part of investment appraisal. Part I of the pamphlet summarizes the principles and key areas of analysis needed to appraise the economic feasibility of every project. The detailed assessment methods are outlined in ADB's Guidelines for the Economic Analysis of Projects (1997). Part II summarizes the main issues to be addressed in each of the 10 key areas of analysis (AAs).
    [Show full text]