The Dictionary of Early American Philosophers

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Dictionary of Early American Philosophers THE DICTIONARY OF EARLY AMERICAN PHILOSOPHERS Volume 1 A – L GENERAL EDITOR John R. Shook Dictionary_Voume_I.indb iii 2/25/2012 7:49:12 AM The Continuum International Publishing Group 80 Maiden Lane, New York, NY 10038 The Tower Building, 11 York Road, London SE1 7NX www.continuumbooks.com © John R. Shook, 2012 All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise, without the permission of the publishers. Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data A catalog record for this book is available from the Library of Congress. ISBN: HB: 978-1-8437-1182-7 Typeset by Deanta Global Publishing Services, Chennai, India Printed and bound in the United States of America Dictionary_Voume_I.indb iv 2/25/2012 7:49:12 AM CAREY CAREY , Henry Charles (1793 – 1879) of the slave system, seeing it as just another form of economic slavery prevalent through- Henry Charles Carey was born in Philadelphia, out the world. He preferred to leave it to Pennsylvania on 15 December 1793. His “ nature . to remedy the existing evil ” parents were the infl uential Irish-born pro- (1836, 309). He did, however, encour- tectionist publisher Mathew CAREY and age the southern slave owner, “ if he regard Bridget Flahavan, daughter of a respectable his own interest, ” to take good care of his Philadelphia family. Henry, the “ miniature slaves (1836, 303). Most striking, though, bookseller, ” began working at his father ’ s was Carey ’ s early dedication to laissez faire bookshop at the age of eight, surrounded by economic principles: Restriction and monop- his father ’ s circle of Philadelphia protection- olies led to war and poverty, whereas “ free ists. At twelve years of age, he moved to Balti- trade, freedom of action – peace – moder- more, where he lived until 1809. For the next ate taxation – high wages, and abundance, nine years he was a traveling salesman for his are all associated ” (1835, 9). father ’ s company. In 1814 he was made part- Carey wrote The Harmony of Nature ner of the business. He married Martha Leslie in 1836. In this work, he yet remained a in 1819. He became head of the fi rm, later disciple of laissez-faire capitalism. Elabo- called Carey, Lea, and Carey, in 1825 upon rating upon his anti-Malthusian ideas, he his father ’ s retirement. After 1834, he ceased argued that there lay no confl ict between working with the publishing fi rm to focus upon populations and subsistence, or landlord the study of economics and social science. and laborer, within harmonious Nature. He In 1856, he became active in the Republican also challenged Ricardo ’ s theory of rent. Party. He was a prolifi c writer of articles, cor- Carey believed instead that the “ rise of rent respondence, and editorials on political and is always the effect of the increasing wealth economic issues. Carey died on 13 October and of the increased facility for providing 1879 in Philadelphia, Pennsylvania. food ” (112). Here, too, he defi ned capital as While running the family publishing com- “ everything that has exchangeable value, ” a pany, Carey avidly read the various submis- defi nition that would change little in his later sions of literature, geography, philosophy, and works (177). Carey was displeased with The political economy. Upon retirement from the Harmony ’ s disorganization and disjointed- book industry, Carey published his fi rst major ness, and withheld it from the public. work, an Essay on the Rate of Wages (1835). From 1837 to 1840, Carey published In it, he argued that “ high wages . are an his three volume The Principles of Political infallible evidence of prosperity, and of the Economy . In the fi rst volume, he outlined rapid increase of capital. ” Population increase his concept of labor and cost wherein man in turn brought “ new divisions of labour, will appropriates, alters, or transports “ the gifts insure a high degree of perfection, and a more of nature. ” The subsequently produced rapid increase of the supply of the means of goods “ have value [revenue] in his estima- support ” (247). As the United States ’ food sup- tion because of the labor that has been given ply had increased alongside its population, he in exchange for them ” (vol. 1, 337). Carey took on Malthus ’ s pessimistic theory of popu- defi ned capital as the portion of revenue that lation growth, asserting that “ where popula- the laborer saved for the future. Further- tion increases rapidly, food is abundant ” (244). more, as internal improvements increased Immigration, then, should be encouraged. the speed and quality of trade and labor, He seemed to have little disagreement “ both capitalist and laborer are, therefore, with southern slavery. He was in opposition enabled to obtain a constantly increasing to “ any attempt to change ” the “ condition ” measure of the conveniences, comforts, and 176 Dictionary_Voume_I.indb 176 2/25/2012 7:49:20 AM CAREY luxuries of life in exchange for their prod- The Past, the Present, and the Future , felt ucts ” ; this relationship of interests was thus he had to disprove Ricardo ’ s rent theory by “ in perfect harmony ” (vol. 1, 339). Capital questioning its supposed universality. Carey and population similarly shared such a rela- still tenuously held on to the tenants of free tionship so long as there were no high taxes, trade, believing that “ war is an evil, and so government interference, or war. are tariffs for protection. ” But he now also The infl ationary crisis that struck the admitted that “ both may be necessary, and United States in 1837 likely affected Carey ’ s both are sometimes necessary ” (302). Carey economic theory as he was writing the sec- thereafter increasingly saw the free-trading ond volume. Much of this volume focuses British Empire as evil, a threat to America ’ s upon credit. Yet while most Americans home industries. sought governmental restriction to stymie From around 1850 to 1857, Carey pro- further infl ation, Carey continued to call for moted his protectionist creed as an editorial unrestrained laissez faire policies. Freedom writer for the New York Tribune . In 1853, of capital guaranteed “ the safest and least he published The Slave Trade, Domestic expensive currency ” (1838, vol. 2, 258). and Foreign , wherein Carey saw southern Regulation of currency would merely lead to African slavery as merely one manifesta- hoarding by bankers. He thus advocated free tion of slavery; the southern cotton growers banking, and he gained the respect of such themselves, with no home market to speak free traders as French economist Frederic of, were slaves to the British cotton market, Bastiat for his stance. Bastiat himself after- as well. Southerners needed industries and ward admitted his indebtedness to Carey for a protective tariff. Thus, Carey argued that his original theory of value and labor. slavery and free trade were intertwined. He American tariffs were decreased between joined the Republican Party in 1856 and 1836 and 1840. The resulting recession, helped shape its later protectionist platform. and Carey ’ s own fi nancial losses during this Between 1858 and 1860, Carey crafted his period, probably caused him to question the greatest work, his three volume The Principles principles of laissez faire . More and more, of Social Science . He supplemented his eco- Carey saw the British industrial dominance nomic theories with the addition of natural and moves toward freer trade with skepti- history and natural science. Man was but the cism and suspicion. So, too, was the likely “ molecule of society . the subject of social infl uence of Friedrich List ’ s System of science, ” and “ the great law of molecular National Economics (1841). When tariffs gravitation ” was “ the indispensible condition were raised in 1842 and Carey ’ s business of the being called man ” (vol. 1, 41, 42). The grew accordingly, he later remarked that protective tariff was therefore a force that “ in the closing months of 1842, seeing the “ tends to the establishment of decentraliza- wonderful change effected by the protec- tion, and to the production of local employ- tive tariff then in operation, ” John C. CAL- ment for time and talent, tends to give value HOUN had “ suggested that there must be to land, to promote its division, and to enable some great law that would explain the fact parents and children to remain in closer con- that we always grew rich under protection, nection with each other ” (vol. 1, 45). whereas we always ended in bankruptcy Money advanced fi nancial progress. after free trade ” (1883, vol. 1, 26). By 1845, According to Carey, increases to the money Carey began to further question Ricardo ’ s metals, gold and silver, increased soci- theory of rent which was so closely tied to etal ties: “ The more abundant the supply free trade. In order to support a protective of those metals, the more instant become tariff, therefore, Carey, in his 1848 work the exchanges of society, the greater is the 177 Dictionary_Voume_I.indb 177 2/25/2012 7:49:20 AM CAREY economy of mental and physical force, and Further Reading the greater the power to produce commodi- Amer Nat Bio, Appleton ’ s Cycl Amer Bio, ties to be given in exchange for further sup- Cambridge Dict Amer Bio, Dict Amer plies of these great instruments of association Bio, WWWHV and combination ” (vol. 2, 306). His position Conkin, Paul K. Prophets of Prosperity: on free banking and infl ationary currency America ’ s First Political Economists remained quite similar to his views twenty (Bloomington, Indiana, 1980). years before. He did add that international Dawson, Andrew. “ Reassessing Henry free trade forced raw materials and precious Carey (1793 – 1879): The Problems of metals into foreign markets, whereas protec- Writing Political Economy in Nineteenth- tionism increased the price of raw materials, Century America, ” Journal of American domestic consumption of those materials, Studies 34 (2000): 465 – 85.
Recommended publications
  • Free Trade by Gordon Bannerman
    Free Trade by Gordon Bannerman Exchanging commodities by commercial transaction is one of the most direct forms of transferring cultural and intellectual capital. Historically, however, international trading relationships have been complicated by national rivalries, opposing economic interests, and the desire of nation‐states to protect domestic industries as a guarantee of economic power and military strength. Against these restrictive influences, the acceptance of free trade has varied according to time, place, and circumstance. This article examines the international and ideological trajectory of the idea and considers the structural and economic influences which shaped policy development and outcomes, as well as the historical context within which it occurred. TABLE OF CONTENTS 1. Introduction 2. Early Modern Conceptions of Trade 3. Mercantilism and Liberal Political Economy 4. The Emergence of Free Trade in Europe 5. Repeal of the British Corn Laws 6. The Rise of Free Trade in Europe 7. The Revival of Protection in Europe 8. Free Trade in Decline 9. Conclusion 10. Appendix 1. Sources 2. Bibliography 3. Notes Indices Citation Introduction The notion of free trade in international commerce has a long history, but only in the 18th century did an increasingly liberal view of the practical benefits and economic efficiency of free international commerce emerge in scholarly work. Most notably, The Wealth of Nations (1776) by Adam Smith (1723–1790) (➔ Media Link #ab) saw free international commerce as a prerequisite for the wealth creation of expanding capitalist economies through the division of labour and the removal of artificial barriers to trading relationships. Smith's work was the catalyst for free trade theory, and despite the obstinate survival of protectionism, notably in emerging nation‐ states anxious to protect domestic industries as a guaranty of national strength, free trade theory was increasingly accepted as underpinning progressive, modern policy‐making.
    [Show full text]
  • 1. the Damnation of Economics
    Notes 1. The Damnation of Economics 1. One example of vice-regal patronage of anti-economics is Canada’s ‘Governor General’s Award for Non-Fiction’. In 1995 this honour was bestowed upon John Raulston Saul’s anti-economic polemic The Unconscious Civilization (published in 1996). A taste of Saul’s wisdom: ‘Over the last quarter-century economics has raised itself to the level of a scientific profession and more or less foisted a Nobel Prize in its own honour onto the Nobel committee thanks to annual financing from a bank. Yet over the same 25 years, economics has been spectacularly unsuc- cessful in its attempts to apply its models and theories to the reality of our civili- sation’ (Saul 1996, p. 4). See Pusey (1991) and Cox (1995) for examples of patronage of anti-economics by Research Councils and Broadcasting Corporations. 2. Another example of economists’ ‘stillness’: the economists of 1860 did not join the numerous editorial rebukes of Ruskin’s anti-economics tracts (Anthony, 1983). 3. The anti-economist is not to be contrasted with the economist. An economist (that is, a person with a specialist knowledge of economics) may be an anti- economist. The true obverse of anti-economist is ‘philo-economist’: someone who holds that economics is a boon. 4. One may think of economics as a disease (as the anti-economist does), or one may think of economics as diseased. Mark Blaug: ‘Modern economics is “sick” . To para- phrase the title of a popular British musical: “No Reality, Please. We’re Economists”’ (Blaug 1998, p.
    [Show full text]
  • INFORMATION to USERS the Most Advanced Technology Has Been Used to Photo­ Graph and Reproduce This Manuscript from the Microfilm Master
    INFORMATION TO USERS The most advanced technology has been used to photo­ graph and reproduce this manuscript from the microfilm master. UMI films the text directly from the original or copy submitted. Thus, some thesis and dissertation copies are in typewriter face, while others may be from any type of computer printer. The quality of this reproduction is dependent upon the quality of the copy submitted. Broken or indistinct print, colored or poor quality illustrations and photographs, print bleedthrough, substandard margins, and improper alignment can adversely affect reproduction. In the unlikely event that the author did not send UMI a complete manuscript and there are missing pages, these will be noted. Also, if unauthorized copyright material had to be removed, a note will indicate the deletion. Oversize materials (e.g., maps, drawings, charts) are re­ produced by sectioning the original, beginning at the upper left-hand comer and continuing from left to right in equal sections with small overlaps. Each original is also photographed in one exposure and is included in reduced form at the back of the book. These are also available as one exposure on a standard 35mm slide or as a 17" x 23" black and white photographic print for an additional charge. Photographs included in the original manuscript have been reproduced xerographically in this copy. Higher quality 6" x 9" black and white photographic prints are available for any photographs or illustrations appearing in this copy for an additional charge. Contact UMI directly to order. UMI University Microfilms International A Bell & Howell Information Company 3 00 Nortfi Z eeb Road, Ann Arbor, Ml 48106-1346 USA 313/761-4700 800/521-0600 Order Number 9011133 Sudden leaps: The young Alfred Marshall Butler, Robert William, Ph.D.
    [Show full text]
  • Economics - Czech Republic Turnovec, Frantisek
    www.ssoar.info Economics - Czech Republic Turnovec, Frantisek Veröffentlichungsversion / Published Version Sammelwerksbeitrag / collection article Zur Verfügung gestellt in Kooperation mit / provided in cooperation with: GESIS - Leibniz-Institut für Sozialwissenschaften Empfohlene Zitierung / Suggested Citation: Turnovec, F. (2002). Economics - Czech Republic. In M. Kaase, V. Sparschuh, & A. Wenninger (Eds.), Three social science disciplines in Central and Eastern Europe: handbook on economics, political science and sociology (1989-2001) (pp. 50-64). Berlin: Informationszentrum Sozialwissenschaften. https://nbn-resolving.org/urn:nbn:de:0168- ssoar-278768 Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Dieser Text wird unter einer CC BY Lizenz (Namensnennung) zur This document is made available under a CC BY Licence Verfügung gestellt. Nähere Auskünfte zu den CC-Lizenzen finden (Attribution). For more Information see: Sie hier: https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0 https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/deed.de 50 František Turnovec Economics - Czech Republic1 Discussant: Jiří Havel Introduction Until the 1989 “Velvet Revolution”, Czechoslovakia was one of the most conservative socialist countries. Even compared to other former socialist countries in Central Europe, the Czechoslovak economy was exceptional in etatization, with only 4% of GDP produced by the private sector (and 10% produced by the cooperative sector) in 1989. After a promising discussion in the 1960s and then the defeat of the Prague Spring at the end of the 1960s, no significant experiments with the liberalization of the economic and political system were implemented in the 1970s and 1980s, and the rigid party nomenclature running the country had to live with the legacy of post-1968 normalization, when the more liberal segments of the Communist Party and of the Czechoslovak political and intellectual establishment were eliminated, expelled from the country, or isolated and persecuted for two long decades.
    [Show full text]
  • Iamerican Crseciprocal Trade ^Agreement of 1874: Ia Pennsylvania^ S "View
    c The Canadian-<iAmerican Rseciprocal Trade ^Agreement of 1874: iA Pennsylvania^ s "View wo issues that attracted a good deal of public attention in nineteenth-century America were tariffs and Canadian- TAmerican foreign relations. Protectionists and free traders chose up opposing sides on the first question; the dividing line for the second fell between expansionists who sought the annexation of Canada and those who preferred that these two nations live as independent, peaceful neighbors.1 While these issues were separable, it also happened that they became intertwined on several occasions, most notably when reciprocal trade agreements were proposed as a means of governing trade between the United States and Canada. Those who sought annexation supported such agreements, because they offered economic penetration of Canadian markets as a substi- tute for forcible conquest of that country.2 Protectionists, on the other hand, opposed them, but not because they feared that free 1 There is, of course, a wide variety of sources (and views) on Canadian-American rela- tions. See, for example, Hugh Aitlcen, "The Changing Structure of the Canadian Economy, with Particular Reference to the Influence of the United States," in The American Impact on Canada, Hugh Aitken, ed. (Durham, N. C, 1959); Harold Innis, Essays in Canadian Economic History (Toronto, 1962); American Assembly, The United States and Canada (Engle- wood Cliffs, N. J., 1964); and Gerald Craig, The United States and Canada (Cambridge, Mass., 1968). 2 Two specific examples of reciprocal-trade agreements between Canada and the United States are an 1855-66 treaty and an agreement proposed in 1902.
    [Show full text]
  • Michael Perelman
    MICHAEL PERELMAN The Perverse Imbalances between Town and Country Introduction At a time when environmental constraints are becoming increasingly obvious, understanding the disconnect between town and country becomes urgent. In early 2000 after having worked for a number of years on The Invention of Capitalism (Perelman 2000), a book devoted to the classical political economists' enthusiasm for primitive accumulation -- the brutal confiscation of resources traditionally belonging to poor people in the countryside -- I was attending the annual economics meetings in Boston. I found myself repeatedly looking out my hotel window at an office building across the street. I wondered what all those people were doing, whether sitting at their desks or moving about. I could not help asking myself what these people might actually be contributing to the economy. Some probably earned modest incomes, but the people ordering them around must be paid very well. As I continued to look into the office building, I continued to think about the glaring inversion of priorities -- low-paid, low-status caregivers for the elderly, alongside great windfalls for hedge fund managers. These disparities between the town and the countryside set my mind flashing back to the farm workers back home in California. I could not help but contrast the conditions of the people in the comfortable offices with those of the workers picking tomatoes in the sweltering heat of the Central Valley. These meditations led me to formulate what I called the farmworker paradox -- the idea that market economies underprice the most essential goods and services; moreover, that the people who do the most essential work get paid the least.
    [Show full text]
  • Henry C Carey and the Republican Tariff
    Henry C Carey and the Republican Tariff HE Republican Party did not begin as a protectionist party. It was organized in 1854 out °f the popular reaction to the TKansas-Nebraska bill, and probably contained as many free traders within its ranks as tariff supporters. All issues other than slavery were deliberately avoided in order to bring together men of a variety of political faiths.1 There is no discernible pattern of eco- nomic foundations in the earliest organization of the party, no assur- ance of what direction later developments would take—practically no evidence of economic purpose or intent at all. In the national platform of 1856 rivers and harbors improvements and a Pacific railroad were supported as relatively safe economic measures, but no mention was made of the controversial question of a protective tariff.2 Throughout the campaign Republican dedication to a single issue remained almost unbroken. In the words of the bangor Whig and Courier, "The present is a crisis so momentous, that all other issues—State and national—should be suspended—all old prejudices forgotten."3 The Rational 8ra warned, "On former ques- tions, of bank or no bank, tariff or no tariff, appropriations or not for internal improvements, and similar ones of utility, real or fancied, there might be opposite views entertained."4 If anyone tried to add something of an economic nature to the main crusade, he was met with disapproval. George W. Julian wanted to give homesteads a play, and he thought he could persuade Greeley—one of the noisiest land reformers of the day—to go along 1 See New York Tribune, July n, 19, 1854, Sept.
    [Show full text]
  • Does J.S. Mill's Theory of Comparative Advantage Prove the Superiority of Free Trade?
    Kyoto Conference on Classical Political Economy – March 7-8, 2018 Does J.S. Mill’s theory of comparative advantage prove the superiority of free trade? Philippe Gillig BETA (Bureau d’économie théorique et appliquée) Université de Strasbourg, CNRS [email protected] -----WORK IN PROGRESS----- Abstract The theory of comparative advantage allegedly shows why free trade is beneficial for all. It is said to be both grounded on a competition hypothesis and to be applicable to any economic system. Does this view coincide with the presentation made by one of its major exponent, namely J.S. Mill? This contribution explores the complexity existing between Mill’s principles and practice on this topic. On the epistemological level, Mill defends the idea that the theory is based on decisions made by self-interested agents; however, he rejects clearly any pretension to universal applicability of the theory precisely because the maximising behaviour assumption has no universal relevance. Yet, we show that in practice, Mill’s presentation of the comparative advantage contains a macroeconomic explanation independent of any assumption concerning agents’ motivations. Indeed, the gains for countries highlighted by the theory are the result of specialisation, and not of free trade, contrary to what Mill and commentators traditionally claim. Further, this macro explanation appears to be of universal applicability, contrary to what Mill thought. Keywords J.S. Mill, comparative advantage, free trade, macroeconomics, economic methodology Kyoto Conference on Classical Political Economy – March 7-8, 2018 Introduction It is a commonplace to say that the principle of comparative advantage is the classical theoretical support for free trade.
    [Show full text]
  • Copyright © 1977, by the Author(S). All Rights Reserved
    Copyright © 1977, by the author(s). All rights reserved. Permission to make digital or hard copies of all or part of this work for personal or classroom use is granted without fee provided that copies are not made or distributed for profit or commercial advantage and that copies bear this notice and the full citation on the first page. To copy otherwise, to republish, to post on servers or to redistribute to lists, requires prior specific permission. INTERLIBRARY LOAN DEPARTMENT <PH«TODUPLICATION SECTION) THE GENBWAL LIBRARY UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA BERKELEY, CALIFORNIA 0472O A CRITIQUE OF URBAN ECONOMICS by Demetrio Alonso Ribeiro Memorandum No. UCB/ERL M77/37 31 May 1977 6 ELECTRONICS RESEARCH LABORATORY College of Engineering University of California, Berkeley 94720 A CRITIQUE OF URBAN ECONOMICS Copyright <c) 1976 &- by Demetrio Alonso Ribeiro Acknowledgements For both his spontaneous stimulus to scholarship and his invaluable friendship, the author feels deeply indebted to Professor Alberto Luiz Coimbra. * For their help in conceiving and preparing this work, the author wishes to express his appreciation to Drs. Pravin P. Varaiya, Roland A. Artie, Charles A. Desoer of the Uni versity of California, Berkeley. For their willingness to help in various and different ways, the author wishes to thank Saul Fuks, Carlos Humes Jr., Nelson Maculan Filho, Ignacio M. Rangel, Jack Schechtman; Mozart V. Serra, Zoe Snyder and Bernardo Szpigel. The author wishes to acknowledge the ways in which he profited from the discussions and the seminars promoted by the Urban Systems Group of the Electronics Research Labora tory, U.C. Berkeley. Financial support for this work was provided by the Coordenacao do Aperfeicoamento de Pessoal de Nivel Superior (CAPES), the Universidade Federal do Rio de Janeiro (UFRJ), and the National Science Foundation (NSF) grant ENG74-01551-A01.
    [Show full text]
  • Henry C. Carey's Monetary Thought and American Industrialization in the Greenback Debate
    HENRY C. CAREY’S MONETARY THOUGHT AND AMERICAN INDUSTRIALIZATION IN THE GREENBACK DEBATE WORKING PAPER SOFIA VALEONTI1 Henry C. Carey was one of the main theoretical advocates of the greenback, the paper money issued in order to finance the American Civil War. The greenback established an inconvertible monetary standard from 1862 to 1879. Carey proposed greenbacks as the solution to both the internal and external constrains of the emerging industry, i.e. high interest rates and a de jure appreciation of the exchange rate. An elastic supply of money offered by a greenback monetary standard could foster low interest rates, which in combination with a depreciated exchange rate could promote industrialization. His greenback advocacy took into consideration American sectionalism by opposing different economic interests linked to different sections of the American territory. Carey believed that the development of the emerging industry could overcome sectional opposition, as it would favor the whole nation. This paper explains how Henry C. Carey’s monetary thought addressed American sectionalism by promoting greenback-fueled industrialization. I. INTRODUCTION Henry C. Carey, an editor and a 19th century economist, is mainly known for his promotion of protectionism and his opposition to Ricardo’s free trade doctrine and 1 P.H.A.R.E., Université Paris I Panthéon-Sorbonne, 106-112 Boulevard de l’Hôpital, 75013 Paris, France. I wish to thank Laurent Le Maux and Nathalie Sigot for their various comments and suggestions, and the participants in the 19th Summer School in the History of Economic Thought, Economic Philosophy and Economic History and the seminar Après-midi de Philosophie et Économie led by Phare laboratory.
    [Show full text]
  • The Spread of Political Economy and the Professionalisation of Economists
    The Spread of Political Economy and the Professionalisation of Economists This book presents the first systematic research and comparative analysis ever attempted on the rise and early developments of the Economic Associations founded in Europe, the USA and Japan during the nineteenth century. Individual chapters reconstruct the events that led to the foundation of economic societies in Britain, France, Italy, Belgium, Spain, Portugal, the Netherlands, Sweden, Germany, Japan and the USA. Contributors analyse the activities and debates promoted by these associations, evaluating their role in: • the dissemination of political economy • the institutionalisation of economics • the construction of professional self-consciousness among economists With contributions from outstanding experts, this book will be of essential interest not only to historians of economic thought, but also to those working more generally in the fields of economics or the history of scientific thought. Massimo M.Augello is Professor of History of Economic Thought and Head of the Department of Economics at the University of Pisa. He has published Joseph Alois Schumpeter. A Reference Guide (1990), and co-edited Le cattedre di economia politica in Italia (1988), Le riviste di economia in italia (1996), and Associazionismo e diffusione dell’economia politica nell’ltalia dell’Ottocento (2000). He is the managing editor of the journal Il pensiero economico italiano and a member of the Advisory Board of History of Economic Ideas. Marco E.L.Guidi is Associate Professor of History of Economic Thought at the Department of Social Studies at the University of Brescia. He is the author of several works on Bentham and classical utilitarianism.
    [Show full text]
  • The Tradition of Free Trade
    The Tradition of Free Trade Lars Magnusson Routledge Taylor & Francis Group LONDON AND NEW YORK -ix- First published 2004 by Routledge 2 Park Square, Milton Park, Abingdon, Oxfordshire OX 14 4RN Simultaneously published in the USA and Canada by Routledge 29 West 35th Street, New York, NY 10001 Routledge is an imprint of the Taylor & Francis Group © 2004 Lars Magnusson Typeset in Times by LaserScript Ltd, Mitcham, Surrey Printed and bound in Great Britain by TJ International, Padstow, Cornwall All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reprinted or reproduced or utilized in any form or by any electronic, mechanical, or other means, now known or hereafter invented, including photocopying and recording, or in any information storage or retrieval system, without permission in writing from the publishers. British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication Data A catalog record for this book has been requested ISBN 0-415-26215-1 -x- Contents Acknowledgements xiii 1 The invention of a tradition of free trade: an introduction 1 A historical reading of the history of economics 4 The use and diffusion of economic language 14 2 The heritage from Smith and classical political economy 20 Adam Smith as a system builder 27 The historical Smith 30 The real classical economists 36 3 The invention of a tradition: from the Corn Laws to the fair trade controversy 46 The Christian moralist-and others 53 Manchester uses of Adam Smith 57 Popular economics 61 The fair trade debate 64 4 The historical construction of mercantilism 70 Mercantilism 72 Adam Smith's mercantile system today 74 The historical construction of a concept 78 Manchester and the mercantile system 82 -xi- The role of mercantilism in nineteenth-century economic thought 90 5 The American system 92 The other face of American political economy 94 Henry C.
    [Show full text]