The Wages of Sin Taxes

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Wages of Sin Taxes e Wages of Sin Taxes Christopher Snowdon Adam Smith Institute 2012 !e Wages of Sin Taxes Executive Summary 1. Governments have long relied on indirect taxes on consumer goods as a source of revenue. ‘Sinful’ items such as alcohol and tobacco have traditionally been taxed punitively and some have called for new taxes on fatty foods and sugary drinks, as well as a minimum price on a unit of alcohol. 2. Campaigners and politicians often cite astronomical figures as being the ‘cost to the taxpayer’ of certain products, but these statements have no foundation in economics. e studies which produce these figures are dominated by ‘costs’ which are neither financial nor borne by the taxpayer. ey include hypothetical estimates of the value of a life year lost, earnings forgone due to premature mortality and expenditure by the consumer on the product itself. ese figures are usually inflated, but even when they are plausible they cannot be used to justify sin taxes because these ‘costs’ affect only the individual; they are not paid by the taxpayer. 3. It is frequently claimed that consumers of ‘unhealthy’ products place an excessive burden on public services— healthcare, in particular—and that this justifies additional taxation in order to (a) reduce consumption of the sinful product, and (b) reimburse the state for the extra money it is forced to spend. is is not true. ere is ample evidence that, on average, smokers and the obese are less of a ‘drain on public services’ than nonsmokers and the slim because they spend fewer years withdrawing pensions, prescriptions, nursing home provision and other benefits. eir lifetime healthcare costs are usually lower than those who lead ‘healthy lives’. If making consumers pay their way is truly the aim of public policy, the government would be more justified in placing a tax on fruit and vegetables. 2 !e Wages of Sin Taxes 4. e case of alcohol differs from that of tobacco and ‘unhealthy’ food in so far as there are additional externalities relating to violence, drink-driving and property damage. It is likely that drinking and drunkenness result in additional costs to the public purse which are not offset by savings and benefits, but these are covered by existing alcohol taxes with several billion pounds to spare. Just as smokers are subsidising nonsmokers, so drinkers are subsidising teetotallers. 5. As instruments of social engineering, sin taxes are blunt tools which are largely ignored by the target group while creating a range of unintended consequences which damage health, stoke criminality and, beyond a certain point, lead to the government receiving less tax revenue. ey are a costly and inefficient means of attempting behavioural change. 6. Taxing goods which are price inelastic, especially those which are addictive, is far more likely to impoverish consumers than it is to turn them into abstainers. Alcoholics are rarely deterred from drinking by higher prices and there is evidence that tobacco taxes are now so high that further increases will yield diminishing returns. Many studies have concluded that ‘fat taxes’ and ‘soda taxes’ have little or no effect on rates of obesity. Such levies are better seen as stealth taxes than sin taxes. 7. Like virtually all indirect taxation, sin taxes hit the poor harder than the rich. Taxes on tobacco, sugar-sweetened drinks and ‘junk food’ are doubly regressive because they are disproportionally consumed by people on lower incomes. Placing a minimum price on alcohol would be extraordinarily regressive since it would deliberately target drinks which are consumed by the poor while leaving the drinks of the rich untouched. 3 !e Wages of Sin Taxes 4 !e Wages of Sin Taxes Introduction “e art of taxation consists of so plucking the goose as to obtain the most feathers with the least possible amount of hissing.” —Jean-Baptiste Colbert Pianos, yachts, playing cars, medicine, alcohol, tobacco, beards, windows, carbon dioxide, lap dancers, airline tickets, petrol, salt, chocolate and tea. All and more have been taxed by impecunious governments; some because they are luxuries, others because they are essential. Commodities which are considered sinful or unhealthy traditionally attract the heaviest duties and it is these that are the focus of this paper. In particular, we shall look at the current bête noires of public health: alcohol, tobacco, sugar and fat. We shall call those who consume them ‘the sinners’ and those who abstain from them ‘the saints’. e duties levied for the good of our physical and moral well-being we call ‘sin taxes’. It is easy to assume that sin taxes, like all other taxes, exist to raise money for the government and history gives us little cause to dismiss that assumption. Sin taxes have a uncanny habit of being imposed when politicians need to find cash quickly, particularly during wars. Beer duty increased tenfold in Britain during the First World War and rose sharply again during the Second World War. e USA fought both World Wars, the Civil War and the War of 1812 on the back of alcohol taxes. In 5 !e Wages of Sin Taxes Germany, taxes on cigarettes rose dramatically during the Second World War, particularly in the later years, until they made up 80 to 95 per cent of the price of a pack.1 Fiscal shortfalls during peacetime are just as likely to inspire taxes on vice. In 1791, George Washington introduced a tax on whiskey as a means of solving the fledgling US government’s debt problem (it was swiftly followed by the Whiskey Rebellion). Two centuries later, Britain’s Conservative government introduced a tax escalator on cigarettes to recoup some of the billions it had wasted trying to shore up sterling on Black Wednesday. In 2008, when the Labour Chancellor Alistair Darling had a credit crunch to tackle, taxes on tobacco, alcohol and petrol were the first to rise (unlike in the USA, the use of motor fuel has long been regarded as a minor sin in Europe). In so doing, Darling honoured the long-standing British tradition of turning the screw on smokers and drinkers when times are tough. Prior to the First World War, more than a third of all government revenue in both Britain and the USA came from duty paid on drink and tobacco. Faced with his own budget deficit in 2009, Barack Obama raised the federal cigarette tax by 156 per cent, despite having promised a year earlier that “no family making less than $250,000 a year will see any form of tax increase.”2 Largely as a result of the president’s U-turn, the federal government’s sin tax revenue—including tobacco, alcohol, guns and ammunition— leapt from $14 billion in 2008 to over $20 billion.3 As the recession deepened, state governments raised taxes on petrol, tobacco, soda and bottled water.4 Colorado started taxing sweets, Texas introduced a tax on lap dancing clubs (the “pole tax”) and several states contemplated a tax on pornography (the “skin tax”).5 In Phoenix, Arizona, a 2 per cent tax on all food was levied to help pay off the city’s $277 million debt, but when the policy encountered opposition from citizens, politicians considered taxes on tattoo parlours, strip clubs and escort agencies instead.6 Meanwhile in Europe, Denmark and 6 !e Wages of Sin Taxes Hungary became the first countries in the world to introduce a ‘fat tax’ and, in 2012, France began levying a tax on sugar sweetened beverages. Politicians appealed to public health concerns to get these measures through, but with a tariff of just one cent per bottle, the French soda tax seemed more of a stealth tax than a sin tax. e remarkable correlation between sin taxes and budget shortfalls suggests either that politicians become unusually puritanical when times are tough or that they see sinners as a ready source of cash. e evidence that austerity breeds morality is scant indeed. On the contrary, fiscal constraints are more likely to blind lawmakers’ eyes to vice than to fill them with moral indignation. As early as the sixteenth century, the profligate, debt-ridden Pope Leo X was taxing prostitution, something Nevada is still contemplating in 2012. In 1964, America’s first state lottery was established in New Hampshire as a means of repaying government debt without raising taxes.7 In 2011, Washington DC became the first US jurisdiction to legalise (and, of course, tax) online gambling. California’s decision to discuss marijuana legalisation in 2010 was unashamedly inspired by the state’s crippling budget deficit. Prohibition itself was ended primarily because the government could no longer afford to keep alcohol revenues in the hands of gangsters once the Great Depression began. Various US states and several EU countries have recently been accused of lowering alcohol and tobacco duties to lure in their neighbours. ese actions do not betray an overt concern for health and purity over base financial considerations. Occasionally, a bona fide zealot will use sin taxes to register his heartfelt disapproval if he feels unable to enact total prohibition. In 1604, King James I raised tobacco duty by 4,000 per cent in a bid to stamp out a habit which he described as “loathsome to the eye [and] hateful to the nose”.8 His ideological descendent Michael Bloomberg, Mayor of New York City, has been on a crusade against tobacco ever since he gave up 7 !e Wages of Sin Taxes a 60-a-day habit. When he increased the tax on a pack of cigarettes from 8 cents to $1.42 in 2002, he announced: “If it were totally up to me, I would raise the cigarette tax so high the revenues from it would go to zero.”9 He has since jacked the tax up to $4.35 per pack, so we should hesitate before questioning his sincerity, but the revenues continue to pour in whether he is sincere or not.
Recommended publications
  • German Tax & Corporate Insights
    Flick Gocke Schaumburg German Tax & Corporate Insights — Issue #08 / December 2015 1 Contents Editorial International Tax Dear readers, Proposed abandonment of the tax exemption regime for Again in this new issue of GTCI we highlight a number of portfolio investments — need for action? .................. 2 German legal developments and court rulings particularly relevant CFC income not subject to trade tax in Germany ......... 3 to international corporations and investors in Germany. Tax & Corporate BEPS & information exchange: Tax court affirms principle of confidentiality and secrecy in tax matters ... 4 We start with summing up a discussion draft regarding a Insights Accounting for tax uncertainties under IAS 12 — reform of the German Investment Tax Act published by the new developments .......................................... 5 Federal Ministry of Finance in July. Then, we take a closer Updates on recent business trends, look at a ruling by the Federal Tax Court according to legislation and case law in Germany Real Estate Transfer Tax which income attributed to German shareholders under German real estate transfer tax provisions — substitute the rules on controlled foreign companies (CFCs) is not tax base unconstitutional .................................. 6 subject to trade tax. Investment Taxation On October 5, the OECD presented the final BEPS package Reform of the German Investment Tax Act ............... 8 of measures for a comprehensive and coordinated reform Corporate Law of international tax rules. We explain what consequences Bonn Hamburg Breaking old habits in German corporate finance: New the package will have in practice. Also, we outline the main Johanna-Kinkel-Straße 2-4 Amelungstraße 8–10 53175 Bonn 20354 Hamburg rules on convertible bonds and preference shares and proposals made in the long-awaited draft “Uncertainty Phone +49 228/95 94-0 Phone +49 40/30 70 85-0 their tax implications ......................................
    [Show full text]
  • Examination of Taxation on Sugar-Sweetened Beverages Alex Smith University of North Georgia, [email protected]
    University of North Georgia Nighthawks Open Institutional Repository Honors Theses Honors Program Spring 2018 Examination of Taxation on Sugar-Sweetened Beverages Alex Smith University of North Georgia, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.northgeorgia.edu/honors_theses Part of the Accounting Commons Recommended Citation Smith, Alex, "Examination of Taxation on Sugar-Sweetened Beverages" (2018). Honors Theses. 32. https://digitalcommons.northgeorgia.edu/honors_theses/32 This Honors Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the Honors Program at Nighthawks Open Institutional Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Honors Theses by an authorized administrator of Nighthawks Open Institutional Repository. Examination of Taxation on Sugar-Sweetened Beverages A Thesis Submitted to The Faculty of the University of North Georgia In Partial Fulfillment Of the Requirements for the Degree Bachelor of Business Administration in Accounting With Honors Alex Smith Spring 2018 Examination of the Taxation on Sugar-Sweetened Beverages 2 Acknowledgements I would like to thank Dr. Ellen Best for her support and insight throughout my research. I would like to thank Dr. Stephen Smith for agreeing to serve on my committee and providing support during my research. I would like to thank Dr. Poff for his guidance in the early development of my literature review. I would also like to thank Dr. Parker for agreeing to serve on my thesis committee Examination of the Taxation on Sugar-Sweetened Beverages 3 Contents 1. Introduction 2. Sin Tax 3. Sugar-Sweetened Beverage Tax Overview 4. Sugar-Sweetened Beverage Tax Response 5. Current Research on Sugar-Sweetened Beverage Tax 6.
    [Show full text]
  • Criminal Justice Review 2010/11
    Centre for Criminal Justice Studies SCHOOL OF LAW Criminal Justice Review Twenty Third Annual Report 2010/11 Centre for Criminal Justice Studies CRIMINAL JUSTICE REVIEW 2010/11 Twenty Third Annual Report CONTENTS The Centre for Criminal Justice Studies ...................................................................................................... 1 Introduction .................................................................................................................................................... 3 Research Projects ............................................................................................................................................ 5 Security and Justice Research Group: Building Sustainable Societies Transformation Fund ............. 9 Teaching Related Initiatives ........................................................................................................................ 10 The Innocence Project: Enhancing Student Experience and Investigating Wrongful Conviction .......................................................................................................................................... 10 HMP Leeds ......................................................................................................................................... 13 Publications ................................................................................................................................................... 15 Conference Presentations and Public Seminars ......................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Parental Alcohol Consumption and Adult Children's Educational Attainment
    DEA WP no. 79 Working Paper Series Parental Alcohol Consumption and Adult Children's Educational Attainment Lucia Mangiavacchi Universitat de les Illes Balears E-mail: [email protected] Luca Piccoli Universitat de les Illes Balears E-mail: [email protected] May 2016 Parental Alcohol Consumption and Adult Children's Educational Attainment∗ Lucia Mangiavacchiy Luca Piccoliz May 8, 2016 Abstract This study analyses whether parents' alcohol consumption can affect long run children's ed- ucational attainments. Using 19 waves of the Russia Longitudinal Monitoring Survey (RLMS), where individuals and their families are followed from childhood to adulthood, this study anal- yses how parental alcohol consumption during childhood (between 1994 and 2001) may affect children's educational attainment about twelve years later (from 2006 to 2014). Panel estima- tions show that mother total grams of alcohol consumption during childhood is consistently negatively associated with adult children educational outcomes, as the probability of having an university degree, the highest level of education achieved and years of schooling. By using direct observation of past parental behaviour, the proposed empirical strategy avoids endo- geneity issues that may arise when using contemporaneous retrospective information, while endogeneity deriving from unobserved characteristics determining both parental drinking and adult children educational attainment is addressed using an Hausman-Taylor estimator. This permits the identification of a negative causal relationship between mother alcohol consump- tion during childhood and long-run children's educational attainment. The study also explores the transmission mechanisms suggested by the literature, identifying a possible role for possi- ble excessive prenatal exposure to alcohol, family disruption, health issues during childhood, parental care needs and intergenerational transmission of drinking habits of the father.
    [Show full text]
  • Pigouvian Taxes
    2 Dereliction of duty: Are UK alcohol taxes too low? AN INSTITUTE OF ALCOHOL STUDIES REPORT PUBLISHED MARCH 2016 WRITTEN AND PRODUCED BY AVEEK BHATTACHARYA WITH THANKS TO Rob Pryce, Katherine Brown, Griffin Carpenter, Amanda Spalding, Siladitya Bhattacharya and Will Damazer, Chris Smith, Jon Foster and Habib Kadiri for reviewing earlier drafts of this report. Cover image by Leo Scanlon. About the Institute of Alcohol Studies The core aim of the Institute is to serve the public interest on public policy issues linked to alcohol, by advocating for the use of scientific evidence in policy-making to reduce alcohol- related harm. The IAS is a company limited by guarantee (no. 05661538) and a registered charity (no. 1112671). For more information visit www.ias.org.uk. 3 4 Executive summary There are three standard reasons why governments taX alcohol: 1. Externality Correction: to ensure that alcohol prices reflect the cost to third parties who are harmed by drinking 2. Paternalism: to reduce people’s consumption for their own good 3. Revenue Raising: to fund the government The UK Government estimates that eXternalities associated with alcohol cost England and Wales £21 billion every year Alcohol duty in England and Wales currently generates only £9 billion, less than half of the value of these externalities This suggests higher alcohol taxes can be justified on the basis of the harm drinking causes to wider society alone, without considering the impact on the drinker themselves The lost enjoyment suffered by moderate consumers as a result of alcohol duty is relatively small – we estimate £1.2 billion (less than 2% of market value) to be the absolute possible ceiling of the impact.
    [Show full text]
  • External Support in Building Tax Capacity in Developing Countries
    Enhancing the Effectiveness of External Support in Building Tax Capacity in Developing Countries Prepared for Submission to G20 Finance Ministers July 2016 International Monetary Fund (IMF) Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) United Nations (UN) World Bank Group (WBG) 0 Acronyms AEOI Automatic Exchange of Information ATAF African Tax Administration Forum ATAIC Association of Tax Administrations in Islamic Countries ATI Addis Tax Initiative BEPS Base Erosion and Profit Shifting CATA Commonwealth Association of Tax Administrators CIAT Inter-American Center of Tax Administrations CD Capacity Development CREDAF Centre de rencontres et d’études des dirigeants des administrations fiscales DAC Development Assistance Committee DRM Domestic resource mobilization FARI Fiscal Analysis for the Resource Industries FTA Forum on Tax Administration IMF International Monetary Fund IOs International Organizations joined in the Platform for Collaboration on Tax: the IMF, OECD, UN and WBG IOTA Intra-European Organisation of Tax Administrations ISORA International Survey of Revenue Administrations ODA Official Development Assistance OECD Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development PITAA Pacific Islands Tax Administrators Association PCT Platform for Collaboration on Tax RA-FIT Revenue Administration’s Fiscal Information Tool RTO Regional Tax Organization SARA Semi-Autonomous Revenue Authority SDGs Sustainable Development Goals SGATAR Study Group on Asian Tax Administration and Research 1 TA Technical assistance TADAT Tax
    [Show full text]
  • Paternalism and Alcohol Policy
    This is an Author Accepted Manuscript (AAM). It has been deposited under the Creative Commons Attribution Non-commercial International Licence 4.0 (CC BY-NC 4.0). To do this, the deposit must clearly state that the AAM is deposited under this licence and that any reuse is allowed in accordance with the terms outlined by the licence. To reuse the AAM for commercial purposes, permission should be sought by contacting [email protected]. For the sake of clarity, commercial usage would be considered as, but not limited to: o Copying or downloading AAMs for further distribution for a fee; o Any use of the AAM in conjunction with advertising; o Any use of the AAM by for promotional purposes by for-profit organisations; o Any use that would confer monetary reward, commercial gain or commercial exploitation. Paternalism and alcohol policy Kari Poikolainen, University of Helsinki, Finland Drugs and Alcohol Today, Publication date: 23 September 2020 https://doi.org/10.1108/DAT-07-2020-0048 Abstract Purpose - To investigate to what degree scientific evidence supports contemporary paternalistic alcohol policy practices targeting fully competent adults. Design/methodology/approach - Paternalism may be acceptable if it is effective, fair and protects the safety of the citizen or a third party from the harms caused by the citizen's autonomic actions. To be justifiable, paternalistic actions should bring about clearly more benefits than harms. Otherwise autonomy should prevail. The evidence related to alcohol control policies is assessed against these principles. Findings - In peaceful civilized societies alcohol control policies (high prices, restrictions on supply and marketing) have no or only insignificant effectiveness.
    [Show full text]
  • The Drawbacks of State Taxes on Financial Transactions
    The Drawbacks of State Taxes on Financial Transactions FISCAL Ulrik Boesen FACT Senior Policy Analyst, Excise Taxes No. 738 Jan. 2021 Key Findings: • A financial transaction tax (FTT) would raise transaction costs, which would result in a lower trading volume, lower liquidity, potentially increased volatility, and lower price of assets. Lower volume limits revenue potential, lower liquidity harms traders’ ability to buy and sell shares at the best price level, and increased volatility can increase risks. • An FTT might be targeted at limiting high frequency trading or speculative short-term investment However, it is highly unlikely that an FTT would only discourage “undesired” trading and would almost certainly result in a host of unintended consequences. The tax code is, moreover, not an appropriate policy tool to limit certain financial transactions. • Estimating revenue from a state-level FTT is difficult given the unknown reaction by the financial markets and high risk of tax avoidance. • States can either tax financial transactions by taxing data processing or stock exchanges, or tax the trader buying and selling financial products. States can either levy the tax at a flat rate or by value (ad valorem). • An FTT results in a version of tax pyramiding as the same instrument is traded multiple times, meaning that even at low rates, an FTT would add a significant tax burden. The Tax Foundation is the nation’s leading independent tax policy research organization. Since 1937, • If several states implement FTTs, the transfer of a security being taxed our research, analysis, and experts have informed smarter tax policy multiple times could emerge.
    [Show full text]
  • Regressive Sin Taxes, with an Application to the Optimal Soda Tax
    Regressive Sin Taxes, with an Application to the Optimal Soda Tax Hunt Allcott, Benjamin B. Lockwood, and Dmitry Taubinsky∗ First version: January 2017 This version: May 2019 Abstract A common objection to \sin taxes"|corrective taxes on goods that are thought to be over- consumed, such as cigarettes, alcohol, and sugary drinks|is that they often fall dispropor- tionately on low-income consumers. This paper studies the interaction between corrective and redistributive motives in a general optimal taxation framework and delivers empirically imple- mentable formulas for sufficient statistics for the optimal commodity tax. The optimal sin tax is increasing in the price elasticity of demand, increasing in the degree to which lower-income consumers are more biased or more elastic to the tax, decreasing in the extent to which con- sumption is concentrated among the poor, and decreasing in income effects, because income effects imply that commodity taxes create labor supply distortions. Contrary to common intu- itions, stronger preferences for redistribution can increase the optimal sin tax, if lower-income consumers are more responsive to taxes or are more biased. As an application, we estimate the optimal nationwide tax on sugar-sweetened beverages, using Nielsen Homescan data and a spe- cially designed survey measuring nutrition knowledge and self-control. Holding federal income tax rates constant, our estimates imply an optimal federal sugar-sweetened beverage tax of 1 to 2.1 cents per ounce, although optimal city-level taxes could be as much as 60% lower due to cross-border shopping. ∗Allcott: New York University and NBER. [email protected].
    [Show full text]
  • Vapor Products, Harm Reduction, and Taxation Principles, Evidence, and a Research Agenda
    Vapor products, harm reduction, and taxation Principles, evidence, and a research agenda Eric Fruits, Ph.D. ICLE Harm Reduction Research Program October 1, 2018 Summary More than 20 countries have introduced taxation on e-cigarettes and other vapor products. In the United States, several states and local jurisdictions have enacted e-cigarette taxes. Most of the harm from smoking is caused by the inhalation of toxicants released through the combustion of tobacco. Non-combustible nicotine de- livery systems, including e-cigarettes, “heat-not-burn” products, smokeless tobacco and other nicotine delivery systems, are generally considered to be significantly less harmful than combustible cigarettes. Policymakers face a wide range of strategies regarding the taxation of va- por products. On the one hand, principles of harm reduction suggest vapor products should face no taxes or low taxes relative to conventional ciga- rettes, to guide consumers toward a safer alternative to smoking. On the other hand, the precautionary principle as well as principles of tax equity point toward the taxation of vapor products at rates similar to conventional cigarettes. Analysis of tax policy issues is complicated by divergent—and sometimes obscured—intentions of such policies. Some policymakers claim that the objective of taxing nicotine products is to reduce nicotine consumption. Other policymakers indicate the objective is to raise revenues to support government spending. Often missed in the policy discussion is the effect of fiscal policies on innovation and the development and commercialization of harm-reducing products. Also, often missed are the consequences for cur- rent consumers of nicotine products, including smokers seeking to quit us- ing harmful conventional cigarettes.
    [Show full text]
  • Contents (Click on an Item/ Page No
    Vol. 25 No. 1 April 2009 Contents (Click on an item/ page no. to be taken directly to your choice of article) This month’s edition features an article by Dr Erik Skovenborg on the recent ‘Expert Report on Lifestyle and Cancer’ on P 3. The article explores evidence on which reasonable recommendations for women’s drinking can be based. This month also saw the publication of the latest results from the European School Survey Project on Alcohol and other Drugs (ESPAD)that monitors trends of adolescent substance use in European countries and to compare trends between countries. The report is on P 14. News from around the world • College men unimpressed by female binge drinkers Article: Expert report on lifestyle and cancer - 19 findings for alcohol by Dr. Erik Skovenborg, • The health and economic consequences of Scandinavian Medical Alcohol Board 3 moderate alcohol consumption in Germany Medical news • Pioneering move from Scottish and Newcastle - lowering the alcohol content of an established • Abstracts related to alcohol consumption brand 20 presented at the American Heart Association • Vinexpo survey finds that women say wine and Council on Epidemiology & Prevention healthy diet go together Annual Meetings, March 11-14, 2009 7 • UK Chief Medical Officer calls for minimum • Support network may play role in benefits pricing on alcohol and targets ‘passive drinking’ 21 of drinking - Heart risks are found to be less • Minimum pricing will receive full public pronounced in highly social men 8 consultation in Scotland • Alcohol and pancreatic
    [Show full text]
  • Why Sin Taxes Are So Good
    Why Sin Taxes Are So Good Let’s say you’re the government, and there’s an unhealthy, dangerous, costly and environmentally damaging behavior you want to discourage. Plus, you could use some revenue. A handy solution: sin taxes. They’re those benevolent or heavy-handed (depending on who you ask) revenue generators that want to change the world for the better. Call them misguided or enlightened, but sin taxes are here to stay–because they are so darn effective. In fact, you probably already pay at least one. What Merits Taxing? Three things are likely to get a sin tax passed: 1. An obvious externality. This is the side effect of a behavior from health care costs imposed on governments and insurance companies by things like obesity, smoking and deaths from drunk driving accidents. 2. Demonstrable benefit. If possible, legislators and voters like to see that a tax decreases the undesirable behavior before implementing it. 3. Revenue for a good cause. To convince citizens that a brand-new tax merits taking their money, tell them how you’ll spend it. Here are some notable examples of taxes that have passed with flying colors, as well as taxes that have utterly failed. 1. Cigarettes Smoking costs the U.S. nearly $200 billion in health care costs and lost productivity each year. All 50 states have a cigarette tax, ranging from $0.17 per pack in Missouri to $4.35 in New York. Stacked on top of this are separate taxes from the federal government, as well as many cities (New York City has a $5.85 total tax) and even some counties.
    [Show full text]