German Tax & Corporate Insights

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

German Tax & Corporate Insights Flick Gocke Schaumburg German Tax & Corporate Insights — Issue #08 / December 2015 1 Contents Editorial International Tax Dear readers, Proposed abandonment of the tax exemption regime for Again in this new issue of GTCI we highlight a number of portfolio investments — need for action? .................. 2 German legal developments and court rulings particularly relevant CFC income not subject to trade tax in Germany ......... 3 to international corporations and investors in Germany. Tax & Corporate BEPS & information exchange: Tax court affirms principle of confidentiality and secrecy in tax matters ... 4 We start with summing up a discussion draft regarding a Insights Accounting for tax uncertainties under IAS 12 — reform of the German Investment Tax Act published by the new developments .......................................... 5 Federal Ministry of Finance in July. Then, we take a closer Updates on recent business trends, look at a ruling by the Federal Tax Court according to legislation and case law in Germany Real Estate Transfer Tax which income attributed to German shareholders under German real estate transfer tax provisions — substitute the rules on controlled foreign companies (CFCs) is not tax base unconstitutional .................................. 6 subject to trade tax. Investment Taxation On October 5, the OECD presented the final BEPS package Reform of the German Investment Tax Act ............... 8 of measures for a comprehensive and coordinated reform Corporate Law of international tax rules. We explain what consequences Bonn Hamburg Breaking old habits in German corporate finance: New the package will have in practice. Also, we outline the main Johanna-Kinkel-Straße 2-4 Amelungstraße 8–10 53175 Bonn 20354 Hamburg rules on convertible bonds and preference shares and proposals made in the long-awaited draft “Uncertainty Phone +49 228/95 94-0 Phone +49 40/30 70 85-0 their tax implications ....................................... 9 over Income Tax Treatments” interpretation published for [email protected] [email protected] Transposition of the EU Accounting Directive public comment by the IFRS Interpretations Committee. Frankfurt (2013/34/EU) .............................................. 11 MesseTurm, Friedrich-Ebert-Anlage 49 In addition, we take a closer look at German real estate 60308 Frankfurt/Main Representative offices: Competition Law transfer tax provisions, outline the main changes to be Phone +49 69/717 03-0 expected from the reform of the German Investment Tax [email protected] Vienna Crying over spilt milk: German Federal Cartel Office Am Heumarkt 7 requires organic dairies to demerge following incorrect Act and examine the new rules on convertible bonds and Berlin 1030 Vienna information in merger control notification ............... 12 preference shares and their tax implications. Finally, we Friedrichstraße 69 Austria deal with the transposition of the EU Accounting Directive 10117 Berlin Phone +43 1/713 08 14 News .......................................................... 14 Phone +49 30/21 00 20-20 [email protected] (2013/34/EU) and report on a recent post-merger investi- [email protected] gation initiated by the Federal Cartel Office. Zurich Contact ....................................................... 15 Munich Bahnhofstraße 69a Brienner Straße 29 8001 Zurich We hope our current choice of topics finds your interest. 80333 Munich Switzerland Phone +49 89/80 00 16-0 Phone +41 44/225 70-10 The FGS editorial team [email protected] [email protected] German Tax & Corporate Flick Gocke Schaumburg Insights German Tax & Corporate Insights — Issue #08 / December 2015 2 from less-than-10% shareholdings in subsidiaries was abol- owned foreign subsidiary. The foreign subsidiary should Proposed abandonment of the ished with effect from March 1, 2013. As a result, the be based in a country which does not tax capital gains tax exemption regime for announced amendments should complement the amend- and dividends from portfolio investments in (foreign) ments realized to date. companies — neither under national law nor under the law portfolio investments — need for of double taxation treaties. The portfolio shares should be action? Limitations of loss offsetting transferred before the new provisions of Sec. 8b(4) CITA- According to the discussion draft any losses in connection draft will be set into force. But given the fact that only a In July 2015, German’s Federal Ministry of Finance pub- with portfolio shareholdings, e.g. from a disposal or a discussion draft exists at the moment, corporate share- lished a discussion draft regarding a reform of the Ger- write-down to market value, could be offset only against holders should not be too hasty in transferring their port- man Investment Tax Act. Besides fundamental changes capital gains from portfolio shareholdings. Any remaining folio investments. It is not yet clear whether the govern- to the taxation of income received by German investors balance of losses from portfolio shareholdings could be mental draft will contain the described provisions. A through investment funds, the draft proposes a signifi- carried forward and offset against future profits from premature transfer of shares would result in a — probably cant amendment to the participation exemption rules in portfolio shareholdings, with no time limitations. The loss unnecessary — tax burden. Also, according to current law Sec. 8b of the German Corporate Income Tax Act carryforward would be subject to the general change-in- capital gains would be tax-exempt up to 95%, 5% would (CITA), namely that the 95% tax exemption for capital ownership rules and, therefore, could be forfeited upon a still be taxable. gains derived by corporate shareholders from portfolio relevant shareholder change. investments would be abandoned. According to the Contact draft law (Sec. 8b(4) CITA), such gains would be fully Reduced tax rate for venture capital investments Dr. Arne von Freeden taxable. If the draft is adopted and enacted, the new The discussion draft also proposes that capital gains from Phone +49 228/95 94-266 [email protected] rules will take effect on January 1, 2018. Capital gains certain venture capital (e.g. start-up) investments would (Bonn office) realized after December 31, 2017 would then be taxed. benefit from a reduced tax on capital gains during the period 2018–2027. The tax on eligible capital gains would Dr. Dietmar Lange be reduced to 30% of the acquisition costs of the shares Phone +49 228/95 94-0 Current law and proposed new rules [email protected] Under the current law, capital gains realized from sales of sold, but would be limited to the amount of corporation (Bonn office) shareholdings by German corporate shareholders are (in tax paid on the capital gains derived from the shares. To most cases) effectively 95% exempt from tax, with no benefit from the reduced tax rate, the shares would have minimum shareholding requirement. The discussion draft to be newly issued shares bearing voting rights, not be proposes abolishing the participation exemption for capi- listed on a stock exchange, and have been held for at least tal gains in cases where a German corporate shareholder three years. directly holds less than 10% of the share capital of the cor- poration whose shares are being sold. Until 2013, the 95% Practical consequences tax exemption also applied to dividends received by Ger- To avoid tax liability for capital gains on shareholdings of man corporate shareholders, with no minimum sharehold- less than 10% in Germany, German corporate shareholders ing requirement. The 95% exemption for dividends derived could transfer their portfolio investments to a wholly German Tax & Corporate Flick Gocke Schaumburg Insights German Tax & Corporate Insights — Issue #08 / December 2015 3 the German shareholder at the end of the CFC’s fiscal year. income as a matter of course. On top of 15% of corpora- CFC income not subject to trade At the level of the German shareholder, it is treated as tion tax and an effective 0.875% of solidarity surcharge, a tax in Germany capital income in the case of a natural person. If the share- German corporation owes an additional 7–18% of trade holder holds the shares in the CFC as business assets for tax on CFC income, depending on the municipality in The German Federal Tax Court in Munich ruled in March tax purposes, the income is treated as business income. which it maintains domestic permanent establishments. that income attributed to German shareholders under the No credit for foreign taxes is available for trade tax pur- German rules on controlled foreign companies (CFCs) is The usual exemptions or methods of mitigating double poses. What’s more, the trade tax itself does not consti- not subject to trade tax. The decision aligns the tax treat- taxation available under German tax law, such as Germa- tute a deductible business expense, so no mitigation ment of CFCs with the treatment of income from foreign ny’s participation exemption (Sec. 8b of the Corporate whatsoever is available for the trade tax on a corpora- permanent establishments. Now, the response of the Ger- Income Tax Act (Körperschaftsteuergesetz), the partial tion’s CFC income. man legislature and tax authorities remains to be seen. income system (Teileinkünfteverfahren) or the final with- holding tax (Abgeltungsteuer), do not apply to CFC To complement the CFC rules, Sec. 20(2) of the Foreign German CFC legislation has long been a bone of conten- income. For income tax purposes, the CFC income is Tax Act stipulates a switch-over from the exemption tion between taxpayers and the German tax authorities. therefore subject to full taxation at the level of the share- method applicable under a double tax treaty to the credit First introduced in 1972, its main provisions are contained holder, either (progressive) personal income tax or (flat) method. The switch-over applies to income of a foreign in Secs. 7–14 of the German Foreign Tax Act (Außensteu- corporate income tax. A credit for foreign taxes borne by permanent establishment if that income were subject to ergesetz). Under these rules, German resident taxpayers the CFC is available upon application.
Recommended publications
  • Examination of Taxation on Sugar-Sweetened Beverages Alex Smith University of North Georgia, [email protected]
    University of North Georgia Nighthawks Open Institutional Repository Honors Theses Honors Program Spring 2018 Examination of Taxation on Sugar-Sweetened Beverages Alex Smith University of North Georgia, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.northgeorgia.edu/honors_theses Part of the Accounting Commons Recommended Citation Smith, Alex, "Examination of Taxation on Sugar-Sweetened Beverages" (2018). Honors Theses. 32. https://digitalcommons.northgeorgia.edu/honors_theses/32 This Honors Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the Honors Program at Nighthawks Open Institutional Repository. It has been accepted for inclusion in Honors Theses by an authorized administrator of Nighthawks Open Institutional Repository. Examination of Taxation on Sugar-Sweetened Beverages A Thesis Submitted to The Faculty of the University of North Georgia In Partial Fulfillment Of the Requirements for the Degree Bachelor of Business Administration in Accounting With Honors Alex Smith Spring 2018 Examination of the Taxation on Sugar-Sweetened Beverages 2 Acknowledgements I would like to thank Dr. Ellen Best for her support and insight throughout my research. I would like to thank Dr. Stephen Smith for agreeing to serve on my committee and providing support during my research. I would like to thank Dr. Poff for his guidance in the early development of my literature review. I would also like to thank Dr. Parker for agreeing to serve on my thesis committee Examination of the Taxation on Sugar-Sweetened Beverages 3 Contents 1. Introduction 2. Sin Tax 3. Sugar-Sweetened Beverage Tax Overview 4. Sugar-Sweetened Beverage Tax Response 5. Current Research on Sugar-Sweetened Beverage Tax 6.
    [Show full text]
  • Pigouvian Taxes
    2 Dereliction of duty: Are UK alcohol taxes too low? AN INSTITUTE OF ALCOHOL STUDIES REPORT PUBLISHED MARCH 2016 WRITTEN AND PRODUCED BY AVEEK BHATTACHARYA WITH THANKS TO Rob Pryce, Katherine Brown, Griffin Carpenter, Amanda Spalding, Siladitya Bhattacharya and Will Damazer, Chris Smith, Jon Foster and Habib Kadiri for reviewing earlier drafts of this report. Cover image by Leo Scanlon. About the Institute of Alcohol Studies The core aim of the Institute is to serve the public interest on public policy issues linked to alcohol, by advocating for the use of scientific evidence in policy-making to reduce alcohol- related harm. The IAS is a company limited by guarantee (no. 05661538) and a registered charity (no. 1112671). For more information visit www.ias.org.uk. 3 4 Executive summary There are three standard reasons why governments taX alcohol: 1. Externality Correction: to ensure that alcohol prices reflect the cost to third parties who are harmed by drinking 2. Paternalism: to reduce people’s consumption for their own good 3. Revenue Raising: to fund the government The UK Government estimates that eXternalities associated with alcohol cost England and Wales £21 billion every year Alcohol duty in England and Wales currently generates only £9 billion, less than half of the value of these externalities This suggests higher alcohol taxes can be justified on the basis of the harm drinking causes to wider society alone, without considering the impact on the drinker themselves The lost enjoyment suffered by moderate consumers as a result of alcohol duty is relatively small – we estimate £1.2 billion (less than 2% of market value) to be the absolute possible ceiling of the impact.
    [Show full text]
  • External Support in Building Tax Capacity in Developing Countries
    Enhancing the Effectiveness of External Support in Building Tax Capacity in Developing Countries Prepared for Submission to G20 Finance Ministers July 2016 International Monetary Fund (IMF) Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) United Nations (UN) World Bank Group (WBG) 0 Acronyms AEOI Automatic Exchange of Information ATAF African Tax Administration Forum ATAIC Association of Tax Administrations in Islamic Countries ATI Addis Tax Initiative BEPS Base Erosion and Profit Shifting CATA Commonwealth Association of Tax Administrators CIAT Inter-American Center of Tax Administrations CD Capacity Development CREDAF Centre de rencontres et d’études des dirigeants des administrations fiscales DAC Development Assistance Committee DRM Domestic resource mobilization FARI Fiscal Analysis for the Resource Industries FTA Forum on Tax Administration IMF International Monetary Fund IOs International Organizations joined in the Platform for Collaboration on Tax: the IMF, OECD, UN and WBG IOTA Intra-European Organisation of Tax Administrations ISORA International Survey of Revenue Administrations ODA Official Development Assistance OECD Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development PITAA Pacific Islands Tax Administrators Association PCT Platform for Collaboration on Tax RA-FIT Revenue Administration’s Fiscal Information Tool RTO Regional Tax Organization SARA Semi-Autonomous Revenue Authority SDGs Sustainable Development Goals SGATAR Study Group on Asian Tax Administration and Research 1 TA Technical assistance TADAT Tax
    [Show full text]
  • The Drawbacks of State Taxes on Financial Transactions
    The Drawbacks of State Taxes on Financial Transactions FISCAL Ulrik Boesen FACT Senior Policy Analyst, Excise Taxes No. 738 Jan. 2021 Key Findings: • A financial transaction tax (FTT) would raise transaction costs, which would result in a lower trading volume, lower liquidity, potentially increased volatility, and lower price of assets. Lower volume limits revenue potential, lower liquidity harms traders’ ability to buy and sell shares at the best price level, and increased volatility can increase risks. • An FTT might be targeted at limiting high frequency trading or speculative short-term investment However, it is highly unlikely that an FTT would only discourage “undesired” trading and would almost certainly result in a host of unintended consequences. The tax code is, moreover, not an appropriate policy tool to limit certain financial transactions. • Estimating revenue from a state-level FTT is difficult given the unknown reaction by the financial markets and high risk of tax avoidance. • States can either tax financial transactions by taxing data processing or stock exchanges, or tax the trader buying and selling financial products. States can either levy the tax at a flat rate or by value (ad valorem). • An FTT results in a version of tax pyramiding as the same instrument is traded multiple times, meaning that even at low rates, an FTT would add a significant tax burden. The Tax Foundation is the nation’s leading independent tax policy research organization. Since 1937, • If several states implement FTTs, the transfer of a security being taxed our research, analysis, and experts have informed smarter tax policy multiple times could emerge.
    [Show full text]
  • Regressive Sin Taxes, with an Application to the Optimal Soda Tax
    Regressive Sin Taxes, with an Application to the Optimal Soda Tax Hunt Allcott, Benjamin B. Lockwood, and Dmitry Taubinsky∗ First version: January 2017 This version: May 2019 Abstract A common objection to \sin taxes"|corrective taxes on goods that are thought to be over- consumed, such as cigarettes, alcohol, and sugary drinks|is that they often fall dispropor- tionately on low-income consumers. This paper studies the interaction between corrective and redistributive motives in a general optimal taxation framework and delivers empirically imple- mentable formulas for sufficient statistics for the optimal commodity tax. The optimal sin tax is increasing in the price elasticity of demand, increasing in the degree to which lower-income consumers are more biased or more elastic to the tax, decreasing in the extent to which con- sumption is concentrated among the poor, and decreasing in income effects, because income effects imply that commodity taxes create labor supply distortions. Contrary to common intu- itions, stronger preferences for redistribution can increase the optimal sin tax, if lower-income consumers are more responsive to taxes or are more biased. As an application, we estimate the optimal nationwide tax on sugar-sweetened beverages, using Nielsen Homescan data and a spe- cially designed survey measuring nutrition knowledge and self-control. Holding federal income tax rates constant, our estimates imply an optimal federal sugar-sweetened beverage tax of 1 to 2.1 cents per ounce, although optimal city-level taxes could be as much as 60% lower due to cross-border shopping. ∗Allcott: New York University and NBER. [email protected].
    [Show full text]
  • Vapor Products, Harm Reduction, and Taxation Principles, Evidence, and a Research Agenda
    Vapor products, harm reduction, and taxation Principles, evidence, and a research agenda Eric Fruits, Ph.D. ICLE Harm Reduction Research Program October 1, 2018 Summary More than 20 countries have introduced taxation on e-cigarettes and other vapor products. In the United States, several states and local jurisdictions have enacted e-cigarette taxes. Most of the harm from smoking is caused by the inhalation of toxicants released through the combustion of tobacco. Non-combustible nicotine de- livery systems, including e-cigarettes, “heat-not-burn” products, smokeless tobacco and other nicotine delivery systems, are generally considered to be significantly less harmful than combustible cigarettes. Policymakers face a wide range of strategies regarding the taxation of va- por products. On the one hand, principles of harm reduction suggest vapor products should face no taxes or low taxes relative to conventional ciga- rettes, to guide consumers toward a safer alternative to smoking. On the other hand, the precautionary principle as well as principles of tax equity point toward the taxation of vapor products at rates similar to conventional cigarettes. Analysis of tax policy issues is complicated by divergent—and sometimes obscured—intentions of such policies. Some policymakers claim that the objective of taxing nicotine products is to reduce nicotine consumption. Other policymakers indicate the objective is to raise revenues to support government spending. Often missed in the policy discussion is the effect of fiscal policies on innovation and the development and commercialization of harm-reducing products. Also, often missed are the consequences for cur- rent consumers of nicotine products, including smokers seeking to quit us- ing harmful conventional cigarettes.
    [Show full text]
  • Why Sin Taxes Are So Good
    Why Sin Taxes Are So Good Let’s say you’re the government, and there’s an unhealthy, dangerous, costly and environmentally damaging behavior you want to discourage. Plus, you could use some revenue. A handy solution: sin taxes. They’re those benevolent or heavy-handed (depending on who you ask) revenue generators that want to change the world for the better. Call them misguided or enlightened, but sin taxes are here to stay–because they are so darn effective. In fact, you probably already pay at least one. What Merits Taxing? Three things are likely to get a sin tax passed: 1. An obvious externality. This is the side effect of a behavior from health care costs imposed on governments and insurance companies by things like obesity, smoking and deaths from drunk driving accidents. 2. Demonstrable benefit. If possible, legislators and voters like to see that a tax decreases the undesirable behavior before implementing it. 3. Revenue for a good cause. To convince citizens that a brand-new tax merits taking their money, tell them how you’ll spend it. Here are some notable examples of taxes that have passed with flying colors, as well as taxes that have utterly failed. 1. Cigarettes Smoking costs the U.S. nearly $200 billion in health care costs and lost productivity each year. All 50 states have a cigarette tax, ranging from $0.17 per pack in Missouri to $4.35 in New York. Stacked on top of this are separate taxes from the federal government, as well as many cities (New York City has a $5.85 total tax) and even some counties.
    [Show full text]
  • Electoral Competitiveness and Fossil Fuel Taxation
    Changing prices in a changing climate: electoral competitiveness and fossil fuel taxation Jared Finnegan November 2018 Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy Working Paper No. 341 ISSN 2515-5709 (Online) Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment Working Paper No. 307 ISSN 2515-5717 (Online) The Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy (CCCEP) was established by the University of Leeds and the London School of Economics and Political Science in 2008 to advance public and private action on climate change through innovative, rigorous research. The Centre is funded by the UK Economic and Social Research Council. Its third phase started in October 2018 with seven projects: 1. Low-carbon, climate-resilient cities 2. Sustainable infrastructure finance 3. Low-carbon industrial strategies in challenging contexts 4. Integrating climate and development policies for ‘climate compatible development’ 5. Competitiveness in the low-carbon economy 6. Incentives for behaviour change 7. Climate information for adaptation More information about CCCEP is available at www.cccep.ac.uk The Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment was established by the London School of Economics and Political Science in 2008 to bring together international expertise on economics, finance, geography, the environment, international development and political economy to create a world-leading centre for policy-relevant research and training. The Institute is funded by the Grantham Foundation for the Protection of the Environment and the Global Green Growth Institute. It has six research themes: 1. Sustainable development 2. Finance, investment and insurance 3. Changing behaviours 4. Growth and innovation 5. Policy design and evaluation 6.
    [Show full text]
  • A Case for Zero Effect of Sin Taxes on Consumption? Evidence from A
    A case for zero effect of sin taxes on consumption? Evidence from a sweets tax reform∗ Sami Jysmä,† Tuomas Kosonen‡ Riikka Savolainen§ June 6, 2019 Work in progress Abstract Excise taxes on soda or other unhealthy products have become in- creasingly popular measures attempting to tackle the increasing obe- sity problem. We study one such attempt in Finland: a sweets tax introduced in 2011, consequent reforms increasing the tax and abol- ishment of the tax in 2017. We study the pass-through to prices and the quantity elasticity of this excise tax that applied to sweets, choco- lates, ice creams and soda. We are able to provide credibly causal estimates on the pass-through to prices and on the quantity elasticity because the tax reforms affected significantly the prices of sweets and soda and we can find credible control groups not affected by the reforms but resembling the sweets. We have access to a unique product- and week-level data on sales from a large Finnish retailer chain containing ∗We would like to thank the participants at numerous conferences and seminars for helpful comments. Miska Raivio provided very helpful research assistance. † Labour Research Institute for Economic Research ‡ Labour Research Institute for Economic Research, Academy of Finland and CESifo, tuomas.kosonen@labour.fi. § King’s College London, [email protected]. 1 the key information on the products and hundreds of millions of ob- servations. Our findings show that in general the tax was fully passed through to prices. Interestingly, we find that the general sweets tax reform-induced price increases did not reduce the demand for sweets or soda.
    [Show full text]
  • Excise Or Excise Tax (Sometimes Called a Duty of Excise Or a Special Tax
    excise or excise tax (sometimes called a duty of excise or a special tax) may be defined broadly as an inland tax on the production for sale; or sale, of specific goods,[1] or narrowly as a tax on a good produced for sale, or sold, within the country. Excises are distinguished from customs duties, which are taxes on importation. Excises, whether broadly defined or narrowly defined, are inland taxes, whereas customs duties are border taxes. An excise is an indirect tax, meaning that the producer or seller who pays the tax to the government is expected to try to recover the tax by raising the price paid by the buyer (that is, to shift or pass on the tax). Excises are typically imposed in addition to another indirect tax such as a sales tax or VAT. In common terminology (but not necessarily in law) an excise is distinguished from a sales tax or VAT in three ways: (i) an excise typically applies to a narrower range of products; (ii) an excise is typically heavier, accounting for higher fractions (sometimes half or more) of the retail prices of the targeted products; and (iii) an excise is typically specific (so much per unit of measure; e.g. so many cents per gallon), whereas a sales tax or VAT is ad valorem, i.e. proportional to value (a percentage of the price in the case of a sales tax, or of value added in the case of a VAT). Typical examples of excise duties are taxes on gasoline and other fuels, and taxes on tobacco and alcohol (sometimes referred to as sin tax) Excise tax is notable for the vagueness of its definition.
    [Show full text]
  • Pass-Through, Tax Avoidance, and Nutritional Effects
    The Impact of Soda Taxes: Pass-through, Tax Avoidance, and Nutritional Effects∗ Stephan Seiler Anna Tuchman Song Yao Stanford Northwestern University of University University Minnesota This draft: March 12, 2019 We analyze the impact of a tax on sweetened beverages, often referred to as a \soda tax," using a unique data-set of prices, quantities sold and nutritional information across several thousand taxed and untaxed beverages for a large set of stores in Philadelphia and its surrounding area. We find that the tax is passed through at an average rate of 97%, leading to a 34% price increase. Demand in the taxed area decreases by 46% in response to the tax. There is no significant substitution to untaxed beverages (water and natural juices), but there is a large amount of cross-shopping to stores outside of Philadelphia. After taking into account cross-shopping, the total demand reduction is equal to only 22%. We do not detect a significant reduction in calorie and sugar intake. ∗We thank seminar participants at Boston University, CKGSB, Cornell University, Northwestern University, UCL, UC Riverside, University of Minnesota, University of Washington, and Washington University in St. Louis, and par- ticipants at the 2017 Marketing in Israel, 2018 Yale Customer Insights, and 2018 INFORMS Marketing Science conferences for useful comments. Yuanchen Su and Weihong Zhao provided excellent research assistance. Thanks also to Piyush Chaudhari and the team at IRI for providing the data used in our analysis. Please contact Seiler ([email protected]), Tuchman ([email protected]), or Yao ([email protected]) for correspon- dence.
    [Show full text]
  • ARE STATES BETTING on SIN? the MURKY FUTURE of STATE TAXATION Lucy Dadayan October 2019 ABSTRACT
    ARE STATES BETTING ON SIN? THE MURKY FUTURE OF STATE TAXATION Lucy Dadayan October 2019 ABSTRACT “Sin taxes” are often viewed as budget saviors, though they play a rather small role in state budgets. Although states raise revenue from sin taxes, policymakers should be mindful of these taxes’ limitations. Absent policy changes (such as increased tax rates), long-term growth for sin tax revenue has often been weak and limited. Moreover, greater dependence on sin tax revenues can lead to odd incentives: part of the reason for taxing some of these activities is to discourage consumption and use rather than to maximize revenue. This report reviews the long-term revenue trends from the three most common sin taxes (alcohol, tobacco, and gambling) and explores how changes in economic activity may affect future revenues. The report also reviews the current status of emerging sin taxes, examining taxes on marijuana and providing overview for taxes on e-cigarettes and sugar- sweetened beverages. ABOUT THE TAX POLICY CENTER The Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center aims to provide independent analyses of current and longer-term tax issues and to communicate its analyses to the public and to policymakers in a timely and accessible manner. The Center combines top national experts in tax, expenditure, budget policy, and microsimulation modeling to concentrate on the areas of tax policy that are critical to future debate. Copyright © 2019. Tax Policy Center. Permission is granted for reproduction of this file, with attribution to the Urban-Brookings Tax
    [Show full text]