Learning, Rational Expectations and Policy

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Learning, Rational Expectations and Policy 50 I James B. Bullard I James B. Bullard is an economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. David H. Kelly provided research assistance. 1 I Learning, Rational Expecta- I tions and Policy: A Summary I of Recent Research I I I N THE THREE DECADES since the publica- eliminated may have important implications for tion of the seminal work on rational expecta- macroeconomic policy. Researchers who focus tions, a steely consensus has been forged in the on this question are studying what is called I economics profession regarding acceptable “learning,” because any method of expectations modeling procedures.’ Simply stated, the con- formation is known as a learning mechanism.’ sensus is that economic actors do not persist in making foolish mistakes in forecasting over This paper provides a synopsis of some of the I time. People are presumed to be able to both recent research on learning. Three important detect past patterns in their prediction errors points are emphasized within the context of the and base their behavior on the “best possible” survey. The most salient point is the close rela- I forecast of future economic conditions. In the tionship between learning issues and macroeco- classic phrase of Robert Lucas, the predictions nomic policy. In fact, the topic attracts attention precisely because of its perceived policy implica- of individuals must be “. - free of systematic I and easily correctable biases.” The current tions. The second point is more subtle: learning wide acceptability of this notion is testament to is implicitly an integral part of rational expecta- the success of the rational expectations tions models, and current research only makes this fact explicit. There is little prospect that revolution. I one can avoid the study of learning by assuming Unfortunately, the consensus that in equilibri- rational expectations. The third point is that in- um systematic forecast errors should be elimi- cluding learning in macroeconomic models is I nated has been insufficient to end the debate in unlikely to either confirm or overturn completely macroeconomics over expectational assumptions. the results from rational expectations macro- In particular, some current research examines models. Instead, the concept of rational expecta- the idea that how systematic forecast errors are tions equilibrium seems to provide the appropri- I 1 The seminal work is Muth (1960, 1961). 2 for different readers. This terminology developed because Lucas (1977), p. 224. rational expectations is justified by the notion that people I eliminate systematic forecast errors over time, and the ‘The phrase “learning mechanism” is used in this paper in dynamic elimination of errors is a definition of learning. a broad way, even though it conjures up different images I FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF St LOUIS a I 51 ate benchmark for the study of learning in that, model” and thus can predict as well as the I when systems converge under learning, they economist manipulating the model.’ These are typically converge to stationary rational expecta- the tenets of the theory and are often espoused tions equilibria. by its advocates. I The next section provides a non-technical in- The first tenet, the heuristic notion that in- troduction to learning and rational expectations. dividuals eliminate systematic forecast errors, is The subsequent section looks at the effects of the one most responsible for the rise of the ra- introducing learning through a simple example tional expectations hypothesis. In a deterministic I attributable to Albert Marcet and Thomas environment, this idea implies that, once learn- Sargent. Some interpretation and discussion ing is complete, people have perfect foresight. of the example is offered in the third section, In a stochastic environment, it means that the I along with a review of other attempts to intro- remaining forecast errors are white noise. duce learning into macroeconomic models. The Since the consensus is that the elimination of final section provides summary comments. systematic forecast errors is a sensible postu- I late, all reasonable long-run equilibria must be THE LEARNING IMPLICIT IN RA- rational expectations equilibria. Macroeconomists TIONAL EXPECTATIONS generally are interested in the effects of changes I in policy parameters at these steady-state equi- Why Study Learning? librium points.’ Given such equilibria, there is at least one reason why the explicit specification of Since decisions made today affecting produc- learning could matter: in a model with multiple I tive behavior are presumed to be based, in part, rational expectations equilibria, the learning on individual assessments of the future, macro- mechanism may serve to select the actual out- economic theories and models generally have come.7 The next section contains an example of I provided a role for expectations. Around 1970, learning as a selection mechanism. however, researchers began to realize that the policy implications of their models were often Representing Learning Via Econ” quite sensitive to the choice of expectational ometric Techniques I assumptions.4 This failure of robustness has been increasingly apparent in the last 20 years Macroeconomists generally have avoided speci- and has drawn increased attention to the prob- fying explicitly the optimal learning mechanism I lem of how expectations are formed. This line underlying rational expectations for a number of research constitutes what has been called the of reasons. First and foremost, they considered rational expectations revolution. rational expectations a shortcut in expectations modeling that made explicit specification un- I A capsule characterization of rational expecta- 8 necessary. Further, ascertaining the full im- tions contains the following themes: (1) In equi- plications of the rational expectations hypothesis librium (a steady state in dynamic terms), ex- turned out to be a difficult problem; presumably, I pectations are “correct” in the sense that in- these implications must be understood before dividuals make no systematic forecast errors; the issue of learning can be investigated. (2) Individuals use all available information (as defined by the researcher) in forming forecasts; There was, however, at least one additional I (3) Expectations vary with changes in govern- reason why learning was essentially ignored— ment policy; and (4) Individuals know “the explicit specifications of how agents form expec- I 4 Sargent (1987) has documented some of this early can be made. This is called global stability. Alternatively, research in rational expectations. one can define local stability, where a particular stationary ‘A more formal approach to defining rational expectations equilibrium is stable only if the initial conditions are near is pursued in the next section. that equilibrium. I 6 ‘Lucas’ comment, “ --take the rational expectations For a discussion of policy along the transition path, see Taylor (1975). equilibrium ---as the model to be tested and view [learn- ing] as -- .an adjunct to the theory that serves to lend it ‘This is the same as saying that learning provides a stabili- plausibility,” hints at this pragmatism. See Lucas (1987a), I ty theory for rational expectations equilibria. In the best p.231. case, given initial conditions and some parameter values, statements claiming that the dynamic evolution of the I economy always leads to a particular stationary equilibrium a JANUARY/FEBRUARy 1991 52 I tations have often been attacked. In particular, ‘the impetus for a detailed analysis of learning one key criticism of the adaptive expectations has come from both advances in research tech- I formulation was that it allowed systematic er- nology and one pressing problem: many rational rors to persist over time.’ expectations models are characterized by multi- ple equilibria. Moreover, these different equilib- The notion of adaptive expectations is essen- ria can have different policy implications, as the 1 tially that people predict the future value of a next section illustrates.” variable via a geometric distributed lag (or Koyck lag) of its past values. One of Muth’s results was that adaptive expectations is an optimal predic- LEARNING AND THE UNPLEAS- I tion method if the variable being forecast follows ANT MONETARIST ARITHMETIC a random walk.”’ Muth’s result makes it clear that, from the beginning, rational expectations This section examines a simple expository ex- I theorists had econometric techniques in mind ample of Marcet and Sargent;14 it is a simplified when thinking about ways to model optimal version of the “unpleasant monetarist arithmetic” forecasting. of Sargent and Neil Wallace.” The example is meant only to illustrate the types of issues that I The idea of looking to econometrics to model can arise; it is not intended as a definitive state- learning obviously can be extended, since the ment of the effects of including learning in eco- Koyck lag is only one of many available econ- nomic models. As the next section will discuss, I ometric techniques. In principle, it should be these effects are still uncertain. possible to take advantage of the developments The model’s most important feature is that in econometric theory to shed light on the prob- there are two steady states (high inflation and lem of how expectations are formed. Further- I low inflation) with differing policy implications. more, if econometric methods are to be applied At the low-inflation steady state, a permanent to solve the inference problem faced by individ- increase
Recommended publications
  • The Process of Inflation Expectations' Formation
    The Process of Inflation Expectations’ * Formation Anna Loleyt** Ilya Gurov*** Bank of Russia July 2010 Abstract The aim of the investigation is to classify and systematize groups of economic agents with different types of inflation expectations in information economy. Particularly it’s found out that it is not feasible to exclude the possibility of current signals perception by economic agents. The analysis has also shown that there is an uncertainty in economy when authorities redeem monetary policy promises, but their action wouldn’t influence on average inflation expectations of economic agents. The investigation results testify the flat existence of agents in economy which are characterizing with rational, quasi-adaptive (including adaptive) and also arbitral inflation expectations. Keywords: information economy, information signal, information perception, agent belief in information, inflation expectations, quasi-adaptive expectations, arbitral expectations. *Acknowledgments: The first authors gratefully acknowledge support through the Bank of Russia. Especially we would like to thank Mr. Alexey V. Ulyukaev for helpful research assistance and Mrs. Nadezhda Yu. Ivanova for strong support. We are also grateful to Mr. Sergey S. Studnikov for his comments. **General Economic Department, Bank of Russia, 12 Neglinnaya Street, Moscow, 107016 Russia Faculty of Economics, Lomonosov Moscow State University, Moscow, Russia Email: [email protected] ***General Economic Department, Bank of Russia, 12 Neglinnaya Street, Moscow, 107016 Russia Faculty of Economics, Lomonosov Moscow State University, Moscow, Russia Email: [email protected] Abbreviations: a variety of information signals. W an element of a variety of information signals that is an information signal. w economic agents. x q a number of signals.
    [Show full text]
  • Adaptive Expectations Versus Rational Expectations: Evidence from the Lab
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Repositori Institucional de la Universitat Jaume I Adaptive Expectations versus Rational Expectations: Evidence from the lab Annarita Colasante1, Antonio Palestrini, Alberto Russo, Mauro Gallegati Universit`aPolitecnica delle Marche, Piazzale Martelli 8, Ancona, Italy. Abstract The aim of the present work is to shed light on the extensive debate about expectations in financial market. We analyze the behavior of subjects in an exper- imental environment in which it is possible to directly observe expectations since the sole task of each player is to predict the future price of an asset. We investi- gate the mechanism of expectation formation in two different contexts: in the first, the fundamental value is constant; in the second, the fundamental price increases over repetitions. First of all we observe if, according to the main results shown in Palestrini and Gallegati (2015), there is a convergence to the rational equilibrium even if agents have adaptive expectations. Moreover, we concentrate on the accu- racy of aggregate forecasts compared with the individual forecasts. We find that there is collective rationality instead of individual rationality. In the context of increasing fundamental value, contrary to the theoretical predictions, players are able to capture the trend but they underestimate that value. This implies that if all agents make their forecasts according to an adaptive scheme, there is no full convergence to the rational expectations equilibrium. Keywords: Price forecasting, Financial market, Experiment, Panel data, Forecasting practice 1. Introduction The recent financial crisis highlighted the importance of agents' behaviour in the financial market and, in turn, the impact of individual financial choices in the real economy.
    [Show full text]
  • How the Rational Expectations Revolution Has Enriched
    How the Rational Expectations Revolution Has Changed Macroeconomic Policy Research by John B. Taylor STANFORD UNIVERSITY Revised Draft: February 29, 2000 Written versions of lecture presented at the 12th World Congress of the International Economic Association, Buenos Aires, Argentina, August 24, 1999. I am grateful to Jacques Dreze for helpful comments on an earlier draft. The rational expectations hypothesis is by far the most common expectations assumption used in macroeconomic research today. This hypothesis, which simply states that people's expectations are the same as the forecasts of the model being used to describe those people, was first put forth and used in models of competitive product markets by John Muth in the 1960s. But it was not until the early 1970s that Robert Lucas (1972, 1976) incorporated the rational expectations assumption into macroeconomics and showed how to make it operational mathematically. The “rational expectations revolution” is now as old as the Keynesian revolution was when Robert Lucas first brought rational expectations to macroeconomics. This rational expectations revolution has led to many different schools of macroeconomic research. The new classical economics school, the real business cycle school, the new Keynesian economics school, the new political macroeconomics school, and more recently the new neoclassical synthesis (Goodfriend and King (1997)) can all be traced to the introduction of rational expectations into macroeconomics in the early 1970s (see the discussion by Snowden and Vane (1999), pp. 30-50). In this lecture, which is part of the theme on "The Current State of Macroeconomics" at the 12th World Congress of the International Economic Association, I address a question that I am frequently asked by students and by "non-macroeconomist" colleagues, and that I suspect may be on many people's minds.
    [Show full text]
  • A New Keynesian Model with Heterogeneous Expectations
    ARTICLE IN PRESS Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 33 (2009) 1036–1051 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jedc A New Keynesian model with heterogeneous expectations William A. Branch a, Bruce McGough b,Ã a University of California, Irvine, USA b Department of Economics, Oregon State University, Corvallis, OR 97330, USA article info abstract Article history: Within a New Keynesian model, we incorporate bounded rationality at the individual Received 30 January 2008 agent level, and we determine restrictions on expectations operators sufficient to imply Accepted 14 November 2008 aggregate IS and AS relations of the same functional form as those under rationality. This Available online 14 February 2009 result provides dual implications: the strong nature of the restrictions required to JEL classification: achieve aggregation serve as a caution to researchers—imposing heterogeneous E52 expectations at an aggregate level may be ill-advised; on the other hand, accepting E32 the necessary restrictions provides for tractable analysis of expectations heterogeneity. D83 As an example, we consider a case where a fraction of agents are rational and the D84 remainder are adaptive, and find specifications that are determinate under rationality may possess multiple equilibria in case of expectations heterogeneity. Keywords: & 2009 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. Heterogeneous expectations Monetary policy Adaptive learning Aggregation 1. Introduction During the
    [Show full text]
  • Das Maynard Keynes Problem: Rethinking Rationality
    Das Maynard Keynes Problem: Rethinking Rationality Ailian Gan Abstract As with Adam Smith in Das Adam Smith Problem, critics have observed that, across the large body of work produced in John Maynard Keynes’s lifetime, Keynes displays a shifting or even inconsistent view of rationality. In the Treatise on Probability, Keynes argues that economic actors use all available information to make rational decisions. In The General Theory, however, Keynes argues that people are irrational and are highly susceptible to psychological forces. This paper seeks to reconcile both views by arguing that, if one allows economic actors to display a range of rationality, Keynes’s work is wholly consistent. I. Introduction For any great intellectual who produces an enormous body of work, tracing his philosophical foundations and precise intentions is a valuable but daunting task. For Adam Smith, critics were intrigued by the transformations and inconsistencies in arguments of his two most prominent works. In The Theory of Moral Sentiments, Smith was an advocate of sympathy for our fellow human being. In The Wealth of Nations, however, he became a strong advocate of self-interest, arguing that it was the primary motive behind economic behavior and the driving force of the economy. This selfless/selfish mismatch has led many economists following in Smith’s footsteps to question which stance he truly intended and whether the two can be reconciled. Either reading of his intentions can lead to vastly different interpretations of his theories and his legacy. Such was the nature of das Adam Smith problem. For John Maynard Keynes, interpreters of his work face a similar problem.
    [Show full text]
  • Overview of Models and Methods for Measuring Economic Agent's Expectations
    Overview of models and methods for measuring economic agent's expectations Tine Janžek, Petra Ziherl Abstract Agents' expectations play an important role as one of the basic building blocks of theoretical macroeconomic models. In practise, though, their intangible nature has always caused consistency difficulties regarding their measurement and estimation methods. Increased importance and use of econometric modelling in contemporary financial stability analyses has triggered numerous advances in methods for measuring empirical expectations. Due to the shortage of empirical data for a more detailed evaluation of expectation measures, this article focuses more on the presentation of the most commonly established methods for their capturing and the methodological aspect of the prevailing models. KEYWORDS: expectations, rational expectations, surveys, qualitative measures, quantitative measures, probabilistic measures, visual analog scale, probability approach, regression approach, inflation, VAR. Expectation examination approaches Modern economic theory recognizes that the main difference between economics and natural sciences lies in the forward-looking decisions made by economic agents. Expectations play a key role in every segment of macroeconomics. In consumption theory the paradigm life-cycle and permanent income approaches stress the role of expected future incomes. In investment decisions present-value calculations are conditional on expected future prices and sales. Asset prices (equity prices, interest rates, and exchange rates) also clearly depend on expected future prices. Today we can distinct two major expectation paradigms and concepts, where the second became the mainstream approach for further development of expectation examination: Adaptive expectations (AE) represent a hypothesis in economics which states that people form their expectations about what will happen in the future based on what has happened in the past.
    [Show full text]
  • The Alleged Necessity of Microfoundations*
    CORE Metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk Provided by Erasmus University Digital Repository MAARTEN C. W. JANSSEN Erasmus University Rotterdam Rotterdam, The Netherlands The Alleged Necessity of Microfoundations* It is often said that models in the microfoundations literature derive macroeconomic results from the theory of individual behavior only. This paper examines two of the assumptions that are usually made in these models: market clearing and rational expectations. In the context of simple models it is shown that only in some special cases these assumptions can be derived from the fundamental notion that individ- uals behave rationally. Thus, the usual rationale for the microfoundations literature is challenged. The paper concludes with a more modest rationale for the "necessity" of microfoundations. 1. Introduction Macroeconomics is in need of a microeconomic foundation. Nowadays, this is a widely accepted doctrine in the economics profession. Most economists take the necessity for a microeconomic foundation for granted. If arguments in favor of the necessity for microfoundations are cited, they often are of the following reduc- tionist form. Society consists of individuals who are the only sub- jects that make economic decisions. So, in order to explain what is going on in the economy as a whole--for example, unemployment, inflation, business cycles--we have to understand the individual de- cisions from which a particular situation originates. I think that this "'reductionist credo" itself is largely correct. However, if it is used as an argument in favor of the necessity for microeconomic foun- dations it is presupposed either that microeconomics is only con- cerned with individual behavior or that all microeconomic propo- sitions can be derived from statements concerning individual decision *This paper was written while I was visiting Duke University.
    [Show full text]
  • The Misspecification of Expectations in New Keynesian Models: a DSGE
    The Misspecification of Expectations in New Keynesian Models: A DSGE-VAR Approach Stephen J. COLE Fabio MILANI∗ Department of Economics Department of Economics University of California, Irvine University of California, Irvine April, 2014 Abstract This paper tests the ability of popular New Keynesian models, which are traditionally used to study monetary policy and business cycles, to match the data regarding a key channel for monetary transmission: the dynamic interactions between macroeconomic variables and their corresponding expectations. In the empirical analysis, we exploit direct data on expectations from surveys. To explain the joint evolution of realized variables and expectations, we adopt a DSGE-VAR approach, which allows us to estimate all models in the continuum between the extremes of an unrestricted VAR, on one side, and a DSGE model in which the cross-equation restrictions are dogmatically imposed, on the other side. Moreover, the DSGE-VAR approach allows us to assess the extent, as well as the main sources, of misspecification in the model. The paper’s results illustrate the failure of New Keynesian models under the rational expec- tations hypothesis to account for the dynamic interactions between observed macroeconomic expectations and macroeconomic realizations. Confirming previous studies, DSGE restrictions prove valuable when the New Keynesian model is exempted from matching observed expecta- tions. But when the model is required to match data on expectations, it can do so only by moving away, and hence substantially rejecting, DSGE restrictions. Finally, we investigate alternative models of expectations formation, including examples of extrapolative and heterogeneous expectations, and show that they can go some way toward reconciling the New Keynesian model with the data.
    [Show full text]
  • The Formation of Expectations, Inflation and the Phillips Curve 1
    The Formation of Expectations, Inflation and the Phillips Curve Olivier Coibion Yuriy Gorodnichenko Rupal Kamdar UT Austin & NBER UC Berkeley & NBER UC Berkeley March 25th , 2017 Abstract This paper argues for a careful (re)consideration of the expectations formation process and a more systematic inclusion of real-time expectations through survey data in macroeconomic analyses. While the rational expectations revolution has allowed for great leaps in macroeconomic modeling, the surveyed empirical micro-evidence appears increasingly at odds with the full-information rational expectation assumption. We explore models of expectation formation that can potentially explain why and how survey data deviate from full-information rational expectations. Using the New Keynesian Phillips curve as an extensive case study, we demonstrate how incorporating survey data on inflation expectations can address a number of otherwise puzzling shortcomings that arise under the assumption of full-information rational expectations. Keywords: Expectations, Inflation, Surveys JEL Codes: E3, E4, E5 1. Introduction Macroeconomists have long recognized the central role played by expectations: nearly all economic decisions contain an intertemporal dimension such that contemporaneous choices depend on agents’ perceptions about future economic outcomes. How agents form those expectations should therefore play a central role in macroeconomic dynamics and policy-making. While full-information rational expectations (FIRE) have provided the workhorse approach for modeling expectations for the past few decades, the increasing availability of detailed micro-level survey-based data on subjective expectations of individuals has revealed that expectations deviate from FIRE in systematic and quantitatively important ways including forecast-error predictability and bias. 1 How should we interpret these results from survey data? In this paper, we tackle this question by first reviewing the rise of the FIRE assumption and some of the successes that it has achieved.
    [Show full text]
  • Unemployment Did Not Rise During the Great Depression—Rather, People Took Long Vacations
    Working Paper No. 652 The Dismal State of Macroeconomics and the Opportunity for a New Beginning by L. Randall Wray Levy Economics Institute of Bard College March 2011 The Levy Economics Institute Working Paper Collection presents research in progress by Levy Institute scholars and conference participants. The purpose of the series is to disseminate ideas to and elicit comments from academics and professionals. Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, founded in 1986, is a nonprofit, nonpartisan, independently funded research organization devoted to public service. Through scholarship and economic research it generates viable, effective public policy responses to important economic problems that profoundly affect the quality of life in the United States and abroad. Levy Economics Institute P.O. Box 5000 Annandale-on-Hudson, NY 12504-5000 http://www.levyinstitute.org Copyright © Levy Economics Institute 2011 All rights reserved ABSTRACT The Queen of England famously asked her economic advisers why none of them had seen “it” (the global financial crisis) coming. Obviously, the answer is complex, but it must include reference to the evolution of macroeconomic theory over the postwar period— from the “Age of Keynes,” through the Friedmanian era and the return of Neoclassical economics in a particularly extreme form, and, finally, on to the New Monetary Consensus, with a new version of fine-tuning. The story cannot leave out the parallel developments in finance theory—with its efficient markets hypothesis—and in approaches to regulation and supervision of financial institutions. This paper critically examines these developments and returns to the earlier Keynesian tradition to see what was left out of postwar macro.
    [Show full text]
  • Agenda Extraordinary (10 March 2020) - Agenda
    Council agenda Extraordinary (10 March 2020) - Agenda MEETING AGENDA EXTRAORDINARY COUNCIL Tuesday 10 March 2020 (at the conclusion of the Strategy and Operations Committee) COUNCIL CHAMBER LIARDET STREET NEW PLYMOUTH Chairperson: Mayor Neil Holdom Members: Cr Tony Bedford Cr Sam Bennett Cr Gordon Brown Cr David Bublitz Cr Anneka Carlson Cr Murray Chong Cr Amanda Clinton-Gohdes Cr Harry Duynhoven Cr Richard Handley Cr Stacey Hitchcock Cr Colin Johnston Cr Richard Jordan Cr Dinnie Moeahu Cr Marie Pearce 1 Council agenda Extraordinary (10 March 2020) - Agenda Purpose of Local Government The reports contained in this agenda address the requirements of the Local Government Act 2002 in relation to decision making. Unless otherwise stated, the recommended option outlined in each report meets the purpose of local government and: Promote the social, economic, environmental, and cultural well-being of communities in the present and for the future. Would not alter significantly the intended level of service provision for any significant activity undertaken by or on behalf of the Council, or transfer the ownership or control of a strategic asset to or from the Council. END 2 Council agenda Extraordinary (10 March 2020) - Health and Safety Health and Safety Message In the event of an emergency, please follow the instructions of Council staff. Please exit through the main entrance. Once you reach the footpath please turn right and walk towards Pukekura Park, congregating outside the Spark building. Please do not block the foothpath for other users. Staff will guide you to an alternative route if necessary. If there is an earthquake – drop, cover and hold where possible.
    [Show full text]
  • Microfoundations
    TI 2006-041/1 Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper Microfoundations Maarten Janssen Department of Economics, Erasmus Universiteit Rotterdam, and Tinbergen Institute. Tinbergen Institute The Tinbergen Institute is the institute for economic research of the Erasmus Universiteit Rotterdam, Universiteit van Amsterdam, and Vrije Universiteit Amsterdam. Tinbergen Institute Amsterdam Roetersstraat 31 1018 WB Amsterdam The Netherlands Tel.: +31(0)20 551 3500 Fax: +31(0)20 551 3555 Tinbergen Institute Rotterdam Burg. Oudlaan 50 3062 PA Rotterdam The Netherlands Tel.: +31(0)10 408 8900 Fax: +31(0)10 408 9031 Please send questions and/or remarks of non- scientific nature to [email protected]. Most TI discussion papers can be downloaded at http://www.tinbergen.nl. MICROFOUNDATIONS Maarten C.W. Janssen1 Erasmus University Rotterdam and Tinbergen Institute Abstract. This paper gives an overview and evaluates the literature on Microfoundations. Key Words: Representative Agents, New Keynesian Economics, and New Classical Economics JEL code: B22, D40, E00 1 Correspondence Address: Erasmus University Rotterdam and Tinbergen Institute, Postbus 1738, 3000 DR Rotterdam, The Netherlands, e-mail: [email protected]. This paper is prepared as an entry for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics (3rd edition) that is currently being prepared. I thank the editors, Steven Durlauf and David Easley, for comments on an earlier version. 1 The quest to understand microfoundations is an effort to understand aggregate economic phenomena in terms of the behavior of
    [Show full text]