Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on New Keynesian Model

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on New Keynesian Model Graduate Macro Theory II: Notes on New Keynesian Model Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Spring 2011 1 Introduction This note describes the simplest version of the New Keynesian model. The NK model takes a real business cycle model as its backbone and adds to it sticky prices. The sticky prices give rise to non-trivial monetary neutralities and also give rise to a serious role for active economic policy. 2 Households The household side of the model ends up looking very standard. Households consume goods, supply labor, and hold money. We assume that they receive utility from holding money. They can save through bonds, which pay nominal interest rate i. The household problem can be written: 1−ν 0 M 1 1 1−ξ t+1 − 1 X t (1 − nt) − 1 pt max E0 β Bln ct + θ + C ct;nt;Bt+1;Mt+1 @ 1 − ξ 1 − ν A t=0 s.t. Bt+1 − Bt Mt+1 − Mt Bt ct + + ≤ wtnt + Πt + it pt pt pt We can set the problem up using a Lagrangian: 1−ν 0 M 1 1−ξ t+1 − 1 X (1 − nt) − 1 pt L = E βt Bln c + θ + + ::: 0 @ t 1 − ξ 1 − ν t=0 Bt Bt+1 Mt+1 − Mt ··· + λt wtnt + Πt + (1 + it) − ct − − pt pt pt The first order conditions are: 1 @L 1 = 0 , = λt (1) @ct ct @L −ξ = 0 , θ(1 − nt) = λtwt (2) @nt @L pt = 0 , λt = βEt λt+1(1 + it+1) (3) @Bt+1 pt+1 −ν @L Mt+1 pt = 0 , = λt − βEt λt+1 (4) @Mt+1 pt pt+1 T Bt+T +1 TV : lim β Etλt+T = 0 (5) T !1 pt+T We can use (1) to simplify this to three first order conditions (plus the transversality condition): −ξ 1 θ(1 − nt) = wt (6) ct 1 1 pt = βEt (1 + it+1) (7) ct ct+1 pt+1 M −ν i 1 t+1 = t+1 (8) pt 1 + it+1 ct (6) is the standard static labor supply condition; (7) is the dynamic consumption Euler equation, with 1 + r = E (1 + i ) pt ; and (8) implicitly defines a demand for real balances: m ≡ Mt+1 . t+1 t t+1 pt+1 t pt 3 Firms As in our earlier discussion of monopolostic competition, we break production up into two sectors: final goods and intermediate goods. We discuss each in turn. 3.1 Final Goods Firm There is a single final goods firm which bundles intermediate goods into a final good available for consumption. There are a continuum of intermediate goods producers populating the unit interval; index these firms by j. The final good is a CES aggregate of these intermediate goods: " Z 1 "−1 "−1 " yt = yj;t 0 The profit maximization problem is: " Z 1 "−1 "−1 Z 1 " max pt yj;t − pj;tyj;t yj;t 0 0 The first order condition is: 2 " −1 Z 1 "−1 "−1 "−1 " " −1 pt yj;t yj;t = pj;t 0 This can be simplified to: 1 Z 1 "−1 "−1 1 " − " pj;t yj;t yj;t = 0 pt Simplifying further, and noting the definition of the final good, we get the demand function for each intermediate good j: −" pj;t yj;t = yt (9) pt The nominal value of the final good is the sum of prices times quantities of intermediates: Z 1 ptyt = pj;tyj;tdj 0 Plug in the demand curve for intermediate goods and simplify: Z 1 1−" " ptyt = pj;t pt ytdj 0 Z 1 1−" 1−" pt = pj;t dj 0 1 Z 1 1−" 1−" pt = pj;t dj (10) 0 3.2 Intermediate Goods Firms Intermediate goods use labor as the only input of production. They are affected by aggregated TFP. The production function is linear in labor input: yj;t = atnj;t (11) Given the downward sloping demand curve, firms have some market power and can set prices. It is assumed that they are not freely able to adjust prices in any period, however. In particular, firms face a constant hazard, 1 − φ, of being able to adjust their price in any period. With probability φ then pj;t = pj;t−1. This is a form of price stickiness due to Calvo (1983). Firms are nevertheless able to freely choose how much labor to use each period, whether they can adjust their price or not. Hence, let's first consider the problem of optimal labor choice for a given price. Since the firm can freely hire labor each period, we can write this as a static problem. Let's write it as the problem of cost-minimization. The reason for this is that the firm will always 3 choose labor to minimize costs regardless of the price chosen, but they are not able to choose price to maximize profits: min Wtnj;t nj;t s.t. −" pj;t atnj;t ≥ yt pt The problem is to minimize nominal costs subject to the restriction that the firm produces at least as much as is demanded at the given price. Wt is the nominal wage common to all firms. Since we take the price as given, the constraint is not a choice variable. Set the problem up as a Lagrangian: −" ! pj;t L = −Wtnj;t + 'j;t atnj;t − yt pt The first order condition is: @L = 0 , Wt = 'j;tat @nj;t 'j;t has the interpretation as (nominal) marginal cost { how much do costs go up if the firm has to produce one more unit of output. Hence the first order condition says to hire labor up until the point where the wage equals marginal cost times the marginal product of labor. Now let's consider the pricing decision. Recall that a firm can change its price in any period only with probability 1 − φ. In expectation it will be \stuck" with that price going forward into the future. Hence, the pricing problem of a firm that gets to update its price in period t is dynamic { the price it picks today will, in expectation, affect the profits it earns both today and in the future. t 0 The firm discounts future profits flows by the stochastic discount factor, Mt = β u (ct). In addition, it will discount future profit flows by φt. Profits as measured are in nominal terms; divide by pt+s to put them into real terms (since that is what the households care about). Conditional on choosing its price today, there is a φ probability of having that price in effect the next period, φ2 for the period after that, and so on. This profit maximization problem is conditional on (i) the demand function, (ii) the production function, and (iii) the first order condition for labor choice holding: 1 X 1 s max Et Mt+s φ (pj;tyj;t+s − Wt+snj;t+s) pj;t p s=0 t+s s.t. −" pj;t yj;t+s = yt+s pt+s yj;t+s = atnj;t+s Wt+s = 'j;t+sat+s 4 We can make this an unconstrained problem by substituting the constraints in to the objective function: 1 −" −" ! X s 0 1 pj;t pj;t max Et (βφ) u (ct+s) pj;t yt+s − 'j;t+s yt+s pj;t p p p s=0 t+s t+s t+s This follows because n = yj;t+s , and multiplying by W eliminates the a . Let's take j;t+s at+s t+s t+s the derivative with respect to pj;t: 1 X s 0 −" "−1 −"−1 "−1 Et (βφ) u (ct+s) (1 − ")pj;t pt+s yt+s + "pj;t 'j;t+spt+s yt+s = 0 s=0 We can simplify this by noting that we can pull the pj;t out of the sum since it does not depend on s: 1 1 −" X s 0 "−1 −"−1 X s 0 "−1 (" − 1)pj;t Et (βφ) u (ct+s) pt+s yt+s = "pj;t Et (βφ) u (ct+s) 'j;t+spt+s yt+s s=0 s=0 Simplifying further: 1 X s 0 "−1 Et (βφ) u (ct+s) 't+spt+s yt+s " p# = s=0 t " − 1 1 X s 0 "−1 Et (βφ) u (ct+s) pt+s yt+s s=0 I do two things in the final step. First, I remove the j subscript from 'j;t+s, which has the interpretation of marginal cost. From the first order condition for optimal labor choice given above, marginal cost is just the ratio of the wage to at. Since this ratio does not depend on j, marginal cost is the same for all firms. Hence, looking at the above, all firms able to update their price will choose the same price. I denote this with a # and call it the \optimal reset price". This formula essentially says that the optimal reset price is a markup over expected future marginal costs. It is easy to see that, if prices are not sticky, then φ = 0 and this reduces to a # " condition we've seen before: pt = "−1 't. With φ > 0, the pricing decision will be forward-looking. 4 Aggregate Conditions and Market-Clearing We assume the existence of a central bank that sets the money supply according to a money growth rule similar to what we've seen before: ∗ ln Mt+1 − ln Mt = (1 − ρm)π + ρm (ln Mt − ln Mt−1) + "m;t We want to write this in terms of real money balances (which will be stationary).
Recommended publications
  • Calculating the Output Gap
    ECONOMIC AND MONETARY DEVELOPMENTS AND PROSPECTS Appendix 2 Calculating the output gap The output gap is an important concept in the preparation of inflation forecasts and assessments of the economic outlook. However, the output gap is difficult to measure and subject to great uncertainty in practice. The techniques used by the Central Bank of Iceland and elsewhere to calculate the output gap, which have previously been described in Monetary Bulletin (2000/4 pp. 14-15), will be recapitulated here taking particular account of investments in the aluminium and power sectors, since these have a substantial impact on both the level of production and output potential in the economy, not only during the construction phase but also when the investments 1 have been completed. 2005•1 MONETARY BULLETIN Definition of the output gap The output gap is defined as the difference between actual and potential GDP as a per cent of potential GDP, i.e.: (1) P where GAPt is the output gap, Yt is GDP in real terms and Y t is the potential output of the economy, all during the year t. Potential output is defined as the level of GDP that is consistent with full utilisation of all factors of production under conditions of stable inflation. Thus potential output is determined on the supply side of the economy, i.e. by capital stock, labour use and available technology. Potential output in the long term is determined by how effici- ently the available factors of production can be utilised for a given level of productivity. In the short run, however, aggregate demand can drive the level of production beyond long-term potential output.
    [Show full text]
  • Output Gaps and Robust Monetary Policy Rules
    SVERIGES RIKSBANK WORKING PAPER SERIES 260 Output Gaps and Robust Monetary Policy Rules Roberto M. Billi MARCH 2012 WORKING PAPERS ARE OBTAINABLE FROM Sveriges Riksbank • Information Riksbank • SE-103 37 Stockholm Fax international: +46 8 787 05 26 Telephone international: +46 8 787 01 00 E-mail: [email protected] The Working Paper series presents reports on matters in the sphere of activities of the Riksbank that are considered to be of interest to a wider public. The papers are to be regarded as reports on ongoing studies and the authors will be pleased to receive comments. The views expressed in Working Papers are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not to be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Executive Board of Sveriges Riksbank. Output Gaps and Robust Monetary Policy Rules Roberto M. Billiy Sveriges Riksbank Working Paper Series No. 260 March 2012 Abstract Policymakers often use the output gap, a noisy signal of economic activity, as a guide for setting monetary policy. Noise in the data argues for policy caution. At the same time, the zero bound on nominal interest rates constrains the central bank’sability to stimulate the economy during downturns. In such an environment, greater policy stimulus may be needed to stabilize the economy. Thus, noisy data and the zero bound present policymakers with a dilemma in deciding the appropriate stance for monetary policy. I investigate this dilemma in a small New Keynesian model, and show that policymakers should pay more attention to output gaps than suggested by previous research. Keywords: output gap, measurement errors, monetary policy, zero lower bound JEL: E52, E58 I thank Tor Jacobson, Per Jansson, Ulf Söderström, David Vestin, Karl Walentin, and seminar participants at Sveriges Riksbank for helpful comments and discussions.
    [Show full text]
  • Mind the Output Gap: the Disconnect of Growth and Inflation During Recessions and Convex Phillips Curves in the Euro Area
    Working Paper Series Marco Gross, Willi Semmler Mind the output gap: the disconnect of growth and inflation during recessions and convex Phillips curves in the euro area Task force on low inflation (LIFT) No 2004 / January 2017 Disclaimer: This paper should not be reported as representing the views of the European Central Bank (ECB). The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the ECB. Task force on low inflation (LIFT) This paper presents research conducted within the Task Force on Low Inflation (LIFT). The task force is composed of economists from the European System of Central Banks (ESCB) - i.e. the 29 national central banks of the European Union (EU) and the European Central Bank. The objective of the expert team is to study issues raised by persistently low inflation from both empirical and theoretical modelling perspectives. The research is carried out in three workstreams: 1) Drivers of Low Inflation; 2) Inflation Expectations; 3) Macroeconomic Effects of Low Inflation. LIFT is chaired by Matteo Ciccarelli and Chiara Osbat (ECB). Workstream 1 is headed by Elena Bobeica and Marek Jarocinski (ECB) ; workstream 2 by Catherine Jardet (Banque de France) and Arnoud Stevens (National Bank of Belgium); workstream 3 by Caterina Mendicino (ECB), Sergio Santoro (Banca d’Italia) and Alessandro Notarpietro (Banca d’Italia). The selection and refereeing process for this paper was carried out by the Chairs of the Task Force. Papers were selected based on their quality and on the relevance of the research subject to the aim of the Task Force. The authors of the selected papers were invited to revise their paper to take into consideration feedback received during the preparatory work and the referee’s and Editors’ comments.
    [Show full text]
  • Measuring Potential Output and Output Gap and Macroeconomic Policy: the Ac Se of Kenya Angelica E
    University of Connecticut OpenCommons@UConn Economics Working Papers Department of Economics October 2005 Measuring Potential Output and Output Gap and Macroeconomic Policy: The aC se of Kenya Angelica E. Njuguna Kenyatta University and KIPPRA Stephen N. Karingi United Nations Economic Commission for Africa Mwangi S. Kimenyi University of Connecticut Follow this and additional works at: https://opencommons.uconn.edu/econ_wpapers Recommended Citation Njuguna, Angelica E.; Karingi, Stephen N.; and Kimenyi, Mwangi S., "Measuring Potential Output and Output Gap and Macroeconomic Policy: The asC e of Kenya" (2005). Economics Working Papers. 200545. https://opencommons.uconn.edu/econ_wpapers/200545 Department of Economics Working Paper Series Measuring Potential Output and Output Gap and Macroeco- nomic Policy: The Case of Kenya Angelica E. Njuguna Kenyatta University and KIPPRA Stephen N. Karingi United Nations Economic Commission for Africa Mwangi S. Kimenyi University of Connecticut Working Paper 2005-45 October 2005 341 Mansfield Road, Unit 1063 Storrs, CT 06269–1063 Phone: (860) 486–3022 Fax: (860) 486–4463 http://www.econ.uconn.edu/ This working paper is indexed on RePEc, http://repec.org/ Abstract Measuring the level of an economy.s potential output and output gap are essen- tial in identifying a sustainable non-inflationary growth and assessing appropriate macroeconomic policies. The estimation of potential output helps to determine the pace of sustainable growth while output gap estimates provide a key bench- mark against which to assess inflationary or disinflationary pressures suggesting when to tighten or ease monetary policies. These measures also help to provide a gauge in the determining the structural fiscal position of the government.
    [Show full text]
  • Working Paper No. 563 Whither New Consensus Macroeconomics? the Role of Government and Fiscal Policy in Modern Macroeconomics
    Working Paper No. 563 Whither New Consensus Macroeconomics? The Role of Government and Fiscal Policy in Modern Macroeconomics by Giuseppe Fontana* May 2009 * University of Leeds (UK) and Università del Sannio (Benevento, Italy). Correspondence address: Economics, LUBS, University of Leeds, Leeds LS2 9JT, UK. E-mail: [email protected]; tel.: +44 (0) 113 343 4503; fax: +44 (0) 113 343 4465. The Levy Economics Institute Working Paper Collection presents research in progress by Levy Institute scholars and conference participants. The purpose of the series is to disseminate ideas to and elicit comments from academics and professionals. The Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, founded in 1986, is a nonprofit, nonpartisan, independently funded research organization devoted to public service. Through scholarship and economic research it generates viable, effective public policy responses to important economic problems that profoundly affect the quality of life in the United States and abroad. The Levy Economics Institute P.O. Box 5000 Annandale-on-Hudson, NY 12504-5000 http://www.levy.org Copyright © The Levy Economics Institute 2009 All rights reserved. ABSTRACT In the face of the dramatic economic events of recent months and the inability of academics and policymakers to prevent them, the New Consensus Macroeconomics (NCM) model has been the subject of several criticisms. This paper considers one of the main criticisms lodged against the NCM model, namely, the absence of any essential role for the government and fiscal policy. Given the size of the public sector and the increasing role of fiscal policy in modern economies, this simplifying assumption of the NCM model is difficult to defend.
    [Show full text]
  • Deflation: Economic Significance, Current Risk, and Policy Responses
    Deflation: Economic Significance, Current Risk, and Policy Responses Craig K. Elwell Specialist in Macroeconomic Policy August 30, 2010 Congressional Research Service 7-5700 www.crs.gov R40512 CRS Report for Congress Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress Deflation: Economic Significance, Current Risk, and Policy Responses Summary Despite the severity of the recent financial crisis and recession, the U.S. economy has so far avoided falling into a deflationary spiral. Since mid-2009, the economy has been on a path of economic recovery. However, the pace of economic growth during the recovery has been relatively slow, and major economic weaknesses persist. In this economic environment, the risk of deflation remains significant and could delay sustained economic recovery. Deflation is a persistent decline in the overall level of prices. It is not unusual for prices to fall in a particular sector because of rising productivity, falling costs, or weak demand relative to the wider economy. In contrast, deflation occurs when price declines are so widespread and sustained that they cause a broad-based price index, such as the Consumer Price Index (CPI), to decline for several quarters. Such a continuous decline in the price level is more troublesome, because in a weak or contracting economy it can lead to a damaging self-reinforcing downward spiral of prices and economic activity. However, there are also examples of relatively benign deflations when economic activity expanded despite a falling price level. For instance, from 1880 through 1896, the U.S. price level fell about 30%, but this coincided with a period of strong economic growth.
    [Show full text]
  • The New Neoclassical Synthesis and the Role of Monetary Policy
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1997, Volume 12 Volume Author/Editor: Ben S. Bernanke and Julio Rotemberg Volume Publisher: MIT Press Volume ISBN: 0-262-02435-7 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/bern97-1 Publication Date: January 1997 Chapter Title: The New Neoclassical Synthesis and the Role of Monetary Policy Chapter Author: Marvin Goodfriend, Robert King Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c11040 Chapter pages in book: (p. 231 - 296) Marvin Goodfriendand RobertG. King FEDERAL RESERVEBANK OF RICHMOND AND UNIVERSITY OF VIRGINIA; AND UNIVERSITY OF VIRGINIA, NBER, AND FEDERAL RESERVEBANK OF RICHMOND The New Neoclassical Synthesis and the Role of Monetary Policy 1. Introduction It is common for macroeconomics to be portrayed as a field in intellectual disarray, with major and persistent disagreements about methodology and substance between competing camps of researchers. One frequently discussed measure of disarray is the distance between the flexible price models of the new classical macroeconomics and real-business-cycle (RBC) analysis, in which monetary policy is essentially unimportant for real activity, and the sticky-price models of the New Keynesian econom- ics, in which monetary policy is viewed as central to the evolution of real activity. For policymakers and the economists that advise them, this perceived intellectual disarray makes it difficult to employ recent and ongoing developments in macroeconomics. The intellectual currents of the last ten years are, however, subject to a very different interpretation: macroeconomics is moving toward a New NeoclassicalSynthesis. In the 1960s, the original synthesis involved a com- mitment to three-sometimes conflicting-principles: a desire to pro- vide practical macroeconomic policy advice, a belief that short-run price stickiness was at the root of economic fluctuations, and a commitment to modeling macroeconomic behavior using the same optimization ap- proach commonly employed in microeconomics.
    [Show full text]
  • Minding the Output Gap: What Is Potential GDP and Why Does It Matter?
    PAGE ONE Economics® GDP Minding the Output Gap: What Is Potential GDP and Why Does It Matter? Scott Wolla, Ph.D., Economic Education Coordinator GLOSSARY “Is real output greater or less than potential? And is real output growing Actual output (real GDP): The amount more or less rapidly than potential? The answer to these questions are that an economy actually produces, as central to policy decisions.” measured by real GDP. —Richard G. Anderson, Economist1 Business cycle: The fluctuating levels of economic activity in an economy over a period of time measured from the beginning of one recession to the Gross domestic product (GDP) is the total market value, expressed in dollars, beginning of the next. of all final goods and services produced in an economy in a given year. GDP Federal funds rate: The interest rate at indicates the size of the economy by measuring the economy’s output. It which a depository institution lends funds is also one of the key measures economists use to assess the health of the that are immediately available to another economy. For GDP to measure the “real” increase or decrease in output depository institution overnight. over time, however, the effect of price changes needs to be removed from Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC): the data. Real GDP does that: It controls for (takes out) inflation and more A Committee created by law that consists of the seven members of the Board of accurately reflects actual economic growth. But knowing the size of the Governors; the president of the Federal economy, or its growth rate, only tells part of the story.
    [Show full text]
  • The Output Gap: What Is It, How Can It Be Estimated and Are Estimates Fit for Policy Makers’ Purposes? Julia Darby and Stuart Mcintyre, University of Strathclyde
    The output gap: what is it, how can it be estimated and are estimates fit for policy makers’ purposes? Julia Darby and Stuart McIntyre, University of Strathclyde Introduction The Scottish Fiscal Commission (SFC), as part of its statutory remit to produce forecasts of the Scottish economy and revenues from devolved taxes, provide assessments of Scotland’s ‘output gap’, which in turn are derived from estimating ‘potential output’. The evolution of potential output and the output gap play key roles in any assessment of the current position of the Scottish economy, and in turn the outlook for future economic growth and tax revenues. This article looks at these concepts in more detail. In what follows we explain the concept of the output gap, its relevance to policy, how output gaps in a given economy can be estimated and why the estimates are always uncertain. We then discuss current views on the evolution of the UK’s output gap and the SFC’s estimates of Scotland’s output gap and end by discussing whether estimates of the output gap currently tell policymakers what they really need to know. What is the output gap30? In general, economists are not only interested in whether output is going up or down, but also in whether it is above or below its potential. The output gap provides an assessment, at a given point in time, of the difference between an economy’s estimated productive potential (typically referred to as ‘potential output’) and the actual level of output. Potential output is the maximum amount of goods and services an economy can produce when it operating efficiently, that is, at full capacity.
    [Show full text]
  • Money and Information in a New Neoclassical Synthesis Framework
    Money and Information in a New Neoclassical Synthesis Framework Philip Arestis Georgios Chortareas John D. Tsoukalas∗ University of Cambridge University of Athens University of Nottingham University of Essex Revised: May 2009 Abstract We consider an (otherwise standard) New Neoclassical Synthesis theoretical framework that allows a role for money. Money in our model has an informational role which consists in facilitating the estimation of the unobserved shocks that drive potential output and thus the state of the economy. For this purpose we estimate a small-scale sticky price model using Bayesian techniques. Our findings support the view that money has information value. This is reflected in higher precision in terms of unobserved model concepts such as the natural rate of output. Moreover, our results highlight how modelling money demand can provide insights about structural features of the economy that may be important for the design of interest rate rules. Focusing on money also allows for a step towards resolving the price puzzle. Money demand shocks can confound monetary policy shocks to generate a perverse price response in vector autoregressions (VAR). JEL classification: D58, E31, E32, E52. Key words: DSGE models; New Keynesian models; Money; Monetary Policy; Bayesian analysis. ∗ Corresponding author: [email protected]. We thank two anonymous referees for helpful suggestions and com- ments that improved the paper. We also like to thank Kostas Katirtzidis for excellent research assistance. 1 1 Introduction Conventional wisdom renders money redundant in the current consensus business cycle models used for policy analysis. The New Keynesian (or New Neoclassical Synthesis –NNS) model with sticky prices has become the standard workhorse for monetary policy analysis in the last fifteen years or so (see Rotemberg and Woodford (1997), Goodfriend and King (1997), Gal´ı (2003)).
    [Show full text]
  • Monetary Policy in the New Neoclassical Synthesis: a Primer
    Monetary Policy in the New Neoclassical Synthesis: A Primer Marvin Goodfriend¤ Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond September 2002 Abstract This primer provides an understanding of the mechanics and objectives of mone- tary policy using a benchmark new neoclassical synthesis (NNS) macromodel. The NNS model incorporates classical features such as a real business cycle (RBC) core, and Keynesian features such as monopolistically competitive …rms and costly price adjustment. Price stability maximizes welfare in the benchmark NNS model be- cause it keeps output at its potential de…ned as the outcome of an imperfectly competitive RBC model with a constant markup of price over marginal cost. ¤Senior Vice President and Policy Advisor. The paper was prepared for the July 2002 International Finance conference “Stabilizing the Economy: What Roles for Fiscal and Monetary Policy?” at the Council on Foreign Relations in New York. The discussant, Mark Gertler, provided valuable com- ments, as did Al Broaddus, Huberto Ennis, Robert Hetzel, Andreas Hornstein, Bennett McCallum, Adam Posen, and Paul Romer. Thanks are also due to students at the GSB University of Chicago, the GSB Stanford University, and the University of Virginia who saw earlier versions of this work and helped to improve the exposition. The views expressed are the author’s and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System. Correspondence: Mar- [email protected]. 1 Introduction Great progress was made in the theory of monetary policy in
    [Show full text]
  • The Impact of COVID on Potential Output
    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO WORKING PAPER SERIES The Impact of COVID on Potential Output John Fernald Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Huiyu Li Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco March 2021 Working Paper 2021-09 https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/working-papers/2021/09/ Suggested citation: Fernald, John, Huiyu Li. 2021 “The Impact of COVID on Potential Output,” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper 2021-09. https://doi.org/10.24148/wp2021-09 The views in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco or the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. The Impact of COVID on Potential Output John Fernald Huiyu Li∗ Draft: March 22, 2021 Abstract The level of potential output is likely to be subdued post-COVID relative to its pre-pandemic estimates. Most clearly, capital input and full-employment labor will both be lower than they previously were. Quantitatively, however, these effects appear relatively modest. In the long run, labor scarring could lead to lower levels of employment, but the slow pre-recession pace of GDP growth is unlikely to be substantially affected. Keywords: Growth accounting, productivity, potential output. JEL codes: E01, E23, E24, O47 ∗Fernald: Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco and INSEAD; Li: Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco. We thank Mitchell Ochse for excellent research support. Any opinions and conclusions expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the views of the Federal Reserve System.
    [Show full text]