3 the New Neoclassical Synthesis and Monetary Policy 3.1 Monopolistic Competition and Aggregate Demand Externalities

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

3 the New Neoclassical Synthesis and Monetary Policy 3.1 Monopolistic Competition and Aggregate Demand Externalities 3 The New Neoclassical Synthesis and Monetary Policy 3.1 Monopolistic Competition and Aggregate Demand Externalities Up to now we considered dynamic macro models with flexible prices. 1) Standard Growth Models: Consumption smoothing; capital accumulation 2) Models with Money: In that model, tax distortion (inflation tax) creates inefficiency. Friedman rule as solution: zero nominal rate of interest or payment of interest on money The welfare cost of inflation in these models (welfare triangle under the money demand function) is rather small (empirically: money balances small) Monetary policy is not only concerned with long run aspects, but also with short run fluctuations. The standard Keynesian view considered Monetary and fiscal policy as instruments to stabilise the economy [IS/LM model]. This view came under attack with the rational expectation revolution by Lucas /Sargent/ Wal- lace: They are argued that systematic stabilisation policy is ineffective. In this Real Business Cycle view, fluctuations are seen as an efficient response to real shocks. In contrast, the New Keynesian Economics re-established a role for monetary policy in the presence of coordination failures/sticky prices in models with rational expectations. In order to try to understand the role of price rigidities, we need a model which allows for explicit price setting. The first generation of models to introduce mo- nopolistic competition was the static model of Blanchard /Kiyotaki. We first look at this setting in the absence of nominal rigidities and show how imperfect competition creates aggregate demand externalities on the macro level. When introducing sticky prices, we can look at the effects of nominal money and shocks, to understand the effects on output and welfare. If firms have monopoly power, they may want to accommodate shifts in demand as long as price exceeds marginal cost. So movements in demand, both positive or negative, will have an effect on output, at least within some range (as long as MC < P). Section 3.3, looks at the implications of fluctuations for monetary policy in a simple stylized setup. Section 3.4 discusses designs for credible monetary policy. Much of the macro research during the last 10 years has integrated key elements of these Keynesian features into the dynamic model we have developed until now, with explicit modelling choices for consumption, saving, money holding and leisure in a dynamic stochastic environment with sticky price setting. In the last part of the lecture (section 3.5), we will derive the current workhorse if macro, which incorporates all these aspects, known as the “New Keynesian" model or The New Neoclassical Synthesis. In that context, we will analyse the effects of dynamic price staggering and reexamine implications for monetary and fiscal policy. 88 Note: The intertemporal versions of IS/AS Model based on explicit microfoun- dations with dynamic optimisation are fairly sophisticated models with forward looking behaviour. At the same time, however, they are drastically simplified to allow for explicit solutions (such as: assume Constant Elasticity of Substitution; abstract from capital formation; focus on specific price setting assumptions, rep- resentative agent type models (despite heterogeneity). General equilibrium with specific preferences, designed to give explicit solu- tions (allow for approximation to linear functions) Key features: Monopolistic competition (price setting); heterogenous goods; representative agent models with aggregate externalities (aggregation) This approach provides some important general insights: a) Forward looking behaviour allows to analyse impact of change in policies b) Captures realistic features of current monetary policy: Under what condi- tions yield interest rate rules stable solutions? c) Helps to understand the role of institutions (independent, credible central bank) d) Allows for welfare analysis e) Empirical analysis: Allows to confront theory with data Some key features of the new generation dynamic models can be more easily captured in the static set up of the first generation of New Keynesian models. Therefore we start first with a simpler (static) approach to gain intuition for some insights: A) Systematic, anticipated stabilisation policy can be quite effective in the presence of price rigidities B) When market equilibrium is inefficient, a surprise in monetary policy may be welfare improving (nature of aggregate demand externalities) C) But it is not possible to implement a policy of systematic surprise → there is the problem of dynamic inconsistency, calling for credible commitment mechanisms. 89 Rational expectation equilibrium revolution: Lucas-Critique of Keynesian Approach: You may fool all of the people some time, and you can fool some people all of the time, but you can't fool all of the people all of the time. Key Argument: Private Agents react consciously to changes in policy – seem- ingly stable relations may break down → Proper modelling of economic policy has to be based on sound microeconomic foundations Policy Conclusions in Lucas type models: 1) Ineffectiveness of a policy of systematic stabilisation Monetary policy can have real effects only if it tries to fool 2) Fooling is welfare reducing, since it distorts optimal rational choice. But these policy conclusions are based on two special conditions: 1) In the absence of intervention, market will reach equilibrium with flexi- ble prices (no price rigidities; no disequilibrium) 2) Market equilibrium is socially efficient (no externalities)) (1) does not hold in the presence of price rigidities [see Stanley Fisher (1977) and John Taylor (1980)]; Monetary policy as a public good in the presence of coordination failure, if nominal contracts have to be arranged before ob- serving shocks): after the realisation of shocks, monetary policy as central coordination mechanism allows for a smoother reversion to the flexible price outcome, saving on private adjustment and coordination costs (Summer time analogy). (2) In the presence of aggregate demand externalities, market equilibrium is at best constrained efficient. Due to structural inefficiencies, the market out- come is below the efficient level. 90 Intuition behind aggregate demand externality: Blanchard /Kiyotaki (1987) We first analyse a one-period problem without uncertainty. [Later, we will add (a) uncertainty (shocks) and (b) will consider a dynamic ver- sion with bonds and money]. For the moment, we also abstract from nominal rigidities. The objective of the representative household is to M Max U= u(;)() C j − v N j j j P j st. per period budget constraint: M j+T j+ PC j= Y j where nominal 1 income is Yj= w N j +∫ ∏ j () i di + M j . 0 1 This budget constraint is a short cut for a dynamic budget constraint. α 1−α ⎛ CMPj ⎞ ⎛ j / ⎞ 1 1+γ For U we use the specification: ⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟ − N n j ⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟ j ⎝ α⎠ ⎝ 1− α ⎠ 1+ γ n Note: This model specification is designed to separate intratemporal problem and intertemporal problem to allow for straightforward ag- gregation for demand for composite goods. Among the advantages of this specification will be a very simple relation between consumption and real money balances, and constant marginal utility of income. Each household gets utility out of consuming a consumption basket, composed of all goods produced (Dixit Stiglitz version of monopolis- tic competition – heterogenous producers with market power, derived from preferences with constant elasticity of substitution). Here, we consider the continuous case (see Blanchard/Kiyotaki for discrete ver- sion): θ θ −1 ⎡1 ⎤θ −1 θ Cj= ⎢∫ c j () i di⎥ ⎣⎢0 ⎦⎥ 1 1 ⎡ 1−θ ⎤1−θ with Dixit Stiglitz price index: P= ∫ p() i di . ⎢⎣0 ⎦⎥ 1 Note: In a dynamic setting, we should only include the opportunity cost for real money bal- ances in the per period budget constraint (see Woodford)! 91 Production: Each firm produces a differentiated good using labor with a constant returns technology y()() i = A N i . A is the level of technology. We can think of movements in A as technological shocks. We have to derive the demand curve each firm is facing for its prod- uct from the demand for the good by all consumers. To characterize the equilibrium, proceed in 4 steps: 1) Given spending on consumption, derive consumption de- mands for each good by each household. 2) Derive of the relation between aggregate consumption and aggregate real money balances. 3) Derive labour supply 4) Derive the demand curve facing each firm, and its pricing decision 5) Characterise the general equilibrium The households problem is α 1−α ⎛ CMP⎞ ⎛ / ⎞ 1 U = ⎜ j ⎟ ⎜ j ⎟ − N1+γ with j ⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟ j ⎝ α⎠ ⎝ 1− α ⎠ 1+ γ θ θ −1 ⎡1 ⎤θ −1 θ Cj= ⎢∫ c j () i di⎥ ⎣⎢0 ⎦⎥ 1 subject to ∫ p()() i cj i di+ Mj = Y j = w N j + Π j + M j 0 We solve the problem step by step: 1) Choose optimal cj () i for a given budget X j spent on the consumption −θ −θ ⎛ p() i ⎞ X j ⎛ p( i) ⎞ basket: cj () i = ⎜ ⎟ = ⎜ ⎟ C j with P C j= X j ⎝ p ⎠ p ⎝ p ⎠ 2) Choose optimal mix between C j and M j for given total income Yj: α 1−α ⎛ CMPj ⎞ ⎛ j / ⎞ 1 1+γ U = ⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟ − N s.t. PCMYM+ = + j ⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟ j j j j j ⎝ α ⎠ ⎝ 1−α ⎠ 1+ γ 92 M j 1−α This gives as FOC: = C , so P α j Πj +w N j + M j M j Π j+ w N j+ M j C = α [ ]; =(1 −α ) [ ] j P P P −θ 1 ⎛ p() i ⎞ t and Note that Pt C t= ∫ p t()() i c t i di since cj() i= C j ⎜ ⎟ 0 ⎝ Pt ⎠ 1−θ 1−θ pt = ∫ ( pt ( i )) di From the FOC we get as indirect utility: 1 Y j 1 1+γ w 1 1+γ 1 ⎡ ⎤ U j = − N j =NNj − j +⎢∫ ∏ j ()i di+ M j ⎥ P 1+ γ P 1+ γ P ⎣0 ⎦ 3) So it is straightforward to characterise labour supply as
Recommended publications
  • Calculating the Output Gap
    ECONOMIC AND MONETARY DEVELOPMENTS AND PROSPECTS Appendix 2 Calculating the output gap The output gap is an important concept in the preparation of inflation forecasts and assessments of the economic outlook. However, the output gap is difficult to measure and subject to great uncertainty in practice. The techniques used by the Central Bank of Iceland and elsewhere to calculate the output gap, which have previously been described in Monetary Bulletin (2000/4 pp. 14-15), will be recapitulated here taking particular account of investments in the aluminium and power sectors, since these have a substantial impact on both the level of production and output potential in the economy, not only during the construction phase but also when the investments 1 have been completed. 2005•1 MONETARY BULLETIN Definition of the output gap The output gap is defined as the difference between actual and potential GDP as a per cent of potential GDP, i.e.: (1) P where GAPt is the output gap, Yt is GDP in real terms and Y t is the potential output of the economy, all during the year t. Potential output is defined as the level of GDP that is consistent with full utilisation of all factors of production under conditions of stable inflation. Thus potential output is determined on the supply side of the economy, i.e. by capital stock, labour use and available technology. Potential output in the long term is determined by how effici- ently the available factors of production can be utilised for a given level of productivity. In the short run, however, aggregate demand can drive the level of production beyond long-term potential output.
    [Show full text]
  • Output Gaps and Robust Monetary Policy Rules
    SVERIGES RIKSBANK WORKING PAPER SERIES 260 Output Gaps and Robust Monetary Policy Rules Roberto M. Billi MARCH 2012 WORKING PAPERS ARE OBTAINABLE FROM Sveriges Riksbank • Information Riksbank • SE-103 37 Stockholm Fax international: +46 8 787 05 26 Telephone international: +46 8 787 01 00 E-mail: [email protected] The Working Paper series presents reports on matters in the sphere of activities of the Riksbank that are considered to be of interest to a wider public. The papers are to be regarded as reports on ongoing studies and the authors will be pleased to receive comments. The views expressed in Working Papers are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not to be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Executive Board of Sveriges Riksbank. Output Gaps and Robust Monetary Policy Rules Roberto M. Billiy Sveriges Riksbank Working Paper Series No. 260 March 2012 Abstract Policymakers often use the output gap, a noisy signal of economic activity, as a guide for setting monetary policy. Noise in the data argues for policy caution. At the same time, the zero bound on nominal interest rates constrains the central bank’sability to stimulate the economy during downturns. In such an environment, greater policy stimulus may be needed to stabilize the economy. Thus, noisy data and the zero bound present policymakers with a dilemma in deciding the appropriate stance for monetary policy. I investigate this dilemma in a small New Keynesian model, and show that policymakers should pay more attention to output gaps than suggested by previous research. Keywords: output gap, measurement errors, monetary policy, zero lower bound JEL: E52, E58 I thank Tor Jacobson, Per Jansson, Ulf Söderström, David Vestin, Karl Walentin, and seminar participants at Sveriges Riksbank for helpful comments and discussions.
    [Show full text]
  • Mind the Output Gap: the Disconnect of Growth and Inflation During Recessions and Convex Phillips Curves in the Euro Area
    Working Paper Series Marco Gross, Willi Semmler Mind the output gap: the disconnect of growth and inflation during recessions and convex Phillips curves in the euro area Task force on low inflation (LIFT) No 2004 / January 2017 Disclaimer: This paper should not be reported as representing the views of the European Central Bank (ECB). The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the ECB. Task force on low inflation (LIFT) This paper presents research conducted within the Task Force on Low Inflation (LIFT). The task force is composed of economists from the European System of Central Banks (ESCB) - i.e. the 29 national central banks of the European Union (EU) and the European Central Bank. The objective of the expert team is to study issues raised by persistently low inflation from both empirical and theoretical modelling perspectives. The research is carried out in three workstreams: 1) Drivers of Low Inflation; 2) Inflation Expectations; 3) Macroeconomic Effects of Low Inflation. LIFT is chaired by Matteo Ciccarelli and Chiara Osbat (ECB). Workstream 1 is headed by Elena Bobeica and Marek Jarocinski (ECB) ; workstream 2 by Catherine Jardet (Banque de France) and Arnoud Stevens (National Bank of Belgium); workstream 3 by Caterina Mendicino (ECB), Sergio Santoro (Banca d’Italia) and Alessandro Notarpietro (Banca d’Italia). The selection and refereeing process for this paper was carried out by the Chairs of the Task Force. Papers were selected based on their quality and on the relevance of the research subject to the aim of the Task Force. The authors of the selected papers were invited to revise their paper to take into consideration feedback received during the preparatory work and the referee’s and Editors’ comments.
    [Show full text]
  • Measuring Potential Output and Output Gap and Macroeconomic Policy: the Ac Se of Kenya Angelica E
    University of Connecticut OpenCommons@UConn Economics Working Papers Department of Economics October 2005 Measuring Potential Output and Output Gap and Macroeconomic Policy: The aC se of Kenya Angelica E. Njuguna Kenyatta University and KIPPRA Stephen N. Karingi United Nations Economic Commission for Africa Mwangi S. Kimenyi University of Connecticut Follow this and additional works at: https://opencommons.uconn.edu/econ_wpapers Recommended Citation Njuguna, Angelica E.; Karingi, Stephen N.; and Kimenyi, Mwangi S., "Measuring Potential Output and Output Gap and Macroeconomic Policy: The asC e of Kenya" (2005). Economics Working Papers. 200545. https://opencommons.uconn.edu/econ_wpapers/200545 Department of Economics Working Paper Series Measuring Potential Output and Output Gap and Macroeco- nomic Policy: The Case of Kenya Angelica E. Njuguna Kenyatta University and KIPPRA Stephen N. Karingi United Nations Economic Commission for Africa Mwangi S. Kimenyi University of Connecticut Working Paper 2005-45 October 2005 341 Mansfield Road, Unit 1063 Storrs, CT 06269–1063 Phone: (860) 486–3022 Fax: (860) 486–4463 http://www.econ.uconn.edu/ This working paper is indexed on RePEc, http://repec.org/ Abstract Measuring the level of an economy.s potential output and output gap are essen- tial in identifying a sustainable non-inflationary growth and assessing appropriate macroeconomic policies. The estimation of potential output helps to determine the pace of sustainable growth while output gap estimates provide a key bench- mark against which to assess inflationary or disinflationary pressures suggesting when to tighten or ease monetary policies. These measures also help to provide a gauge in the determining the structural fiscal position of the government.
    [Show full text]
  • Working Paper No. 563 Whither New Consensus Macroeconomics? the Role of Government and Fiscal Policy in Modern Macroeconomics
    Working Paper No. 563 Whither New Consensus Macroeconomics? The Role of Government and Fiscal Policy in Modern Macroeconomics by Giuseppe Fontana* May 2009 * University of Leeds (UK) and Università del Sannio (Benevento, Italy). Correspondence address: Economics, LUBS, University of Leeds, Leeds LS2 9JT, UK. E-mail: [email protected]; tel.: +44 (0) 113 343 4503; fax: +44 (0) 113 343 4465. The Levy Economics Institute Working Paper Collection presents research in progress by Levy Institute scholars and conference participants. The purpose of the series is to disseminate ideas to and elicit comments from academics and professionals. The Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, founded in 1986, is a nonprofit, nonpartisan, independently funded research organization devoted to public service. Through scholarship and economic research it generates viable, effective public policy responses to important economic problems that profoundly affect the quality of life in the United States and abroad. The Levy Economics Institute P.O. Box 5000 Annandale-on-Hudson, NY 12504-5000 http://www.levy.org Copyright © The Levy Economics Institute 2009 All rights reserved. ABSTRACT In the face of the dramatic economic events of recent months and the inability of academics and policymakers to prevent them, the New Consensus Macroeconomics (NCM) model has been the subject of several criticisms. This paper considers one of the main criticisms lodged against the NCM model, namely, the absence of any essential role for the government and fiscal policy. Given the size of the public sector and the increasing role of fiscal policy in modern economies, this simplifying assumption of the NCM model is difficult to defend.
    [Show full text]
  • Deflation: Economic Significance, Current Risk, and Policy Responses
    Deflation: Economic Significance, Current Risk, and Policy Responses Craig K. Elwell Specialist in Macroeconomic Policy August 30, 2010 Congressional Research Service 7-5700 www.crs.gov R40512 CRS Report for Congress Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress Deflation: Economic Significance, Current Risk, and Policy Responses Summary Despite the severity of the recent financial crisis and recession, the U.S. economy has so far avoided falling into a deflationary spiral. Since mid-2009, the economy has been on a path of economic recovery. However, the pace of economic growth during the recovery has been relatively slow, and major economic weaknesses persist. In this economic environment, the risk of deflation remains significant and could delay sustained economic recovery. Deflation is a persistent decline in the overall level of prices. It is not unusual for prices to fall in a particular sector because of rising productivity, falling costs, or weak demand relative to the wider economy. In contrast, deflation occurs when price declines are so widespread and sustained that they cause a broad-based price index, such as the Consumer Price Index (CPI), to decline for several quarters. Such a continuous decline in the price level is more troublesome, because in a weak or contracting economy it can lead to a damaging self-reinforcing downward spiral of prices and economic activity. However, there are also examples of relatively benign deflations when economic activity expanded despite a falling price level. For instance, from 1880 through 1896, the U.S. price level fell about 30%, but this coincided with a period of strong economic growth.
    [Show full text]
  • The New Neoclassical Synthesis and the Role of Monetary Policy
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1997, Volume 12 Volume Author/Editor: Ben S. Bernanke and Julio Rotemberg Volume Publisher: MIT Press Volume ISBN: 0-262-02435-7 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/bern97-1 Publication Date: January 1997 Chapter Title: The New Neoclassical Synthesis and the Role of Monetary Policy Chapter Author: Marvin Goodfriend, Robert King Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c11040 Chapter pages in book: (p. 231 - 296) Marvin Goodfriendand RobertG. King FEDERAL RESERVEBANK OF RICHMOND AND UNIVERSITY OF VIRGINIA; AND UNIVERSITY OF VIRGINIA, NBER, AND FEDERAL RESERVEBANK OF RICHMOND The New Neoclassical Synthesis and the Role of Monetary Policy 1. Introduction It is common for macroeconomics to be portrayed as a field in intellectual disarray, with major and persistent disagreements about methodology and substance between competing camps of researchers. One frequently discussed measure of disarray is the distance between the flexible price models of the new classical macroeconomics and real-business-cycle (RBC) analysis, in which monetary policy is essentially unimportant for real activity, and the sticky-price models of the New Keynesian econom- ics, in which monetary policy is viewed as central to the evolution of real activity. For policymakers and the economists that advise them, this perceived intellectual disarray makes it difficult to employ recent and ongoing developments in macroeconomics. The intellectual currents of the last ten years are, however, subject to a very different interpretation: macroeconomics is moving toward a New NeoclassicalSynthesis. In the 1960s, the original synthesis involved a com- mitment to three-sometimes conflicting-principles: a desire to pro- vide practical macroeconomic policy advice, a belief that short-run price stickiness was at the root of economic fluctuations, and a commitment to modeling macroeconomic behavior using the same optimization ap- proach commonly employed in microeconomics.
    [Show full text]
  • Minding the Output Gap: What Is Potential GDP and Why Does It Matter?
    PAGE ONE Economics® GDP Minding the Output Gap: What Is Potential GDP and Why Does It Matter? Scott Wolla, Ph.D., Economic Education Coordinator GLOSSARY “Is real output greater or less than potential? And is real output growing Actual output (real GDP): The amount more or less rapidly than potential? The answer to these questions are that an economy actually produces, as central to policy decisions.” measured by real GDP. —Richard G. Anderson, Economist1 Business cycle: The fluctuating levels of economic activity in an economy over a period of time measured from the beginning of one recession to the Gross domestic product (GDP) is the total market value, expressed in dollars, beginning of the next. of all final goods and services produced in an economy in a given year. GDP Federal funds rate: The interest rate at indicates the size of the economy by measuring the economy’s output. It which a depository institution lends funds is also one of the key measures economists use to assess the health of the that are immediately available to another economy. For GDP to measure the “real” increase or decrease in output depository institution overnight. over time, however, the effect of price changes needs to be removed from Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC): the data. Real GDP does that: It controls for (takes out) inflation and more A Committee created by law that consists of the seven members of the Board of accurately reflects actual economic growth. But knowing the size of the Governors; the president of the Federal economy, or its growth rate, only tells part of the story.
    [Show full text]
  • The Output Gap: What Is It, How Can It Be Estimated and Are Estimates Fit for Policy Makers’ Purposes? Julia Darby and Stuart Mcintyre, University of Strathclyde
    The output gap: what is it, how can it be estimated and are estimates fit for policy makers’ purposes? Julia Darby and Stuart McIntyre, University of Strathclyde Introduction The Scottish Fiscal Commission (SFC), as part of its statutory remit to produce forecasts of the Scottish economy and revenues from devolved taxes, provide assessments of Scotland’s ‘output gap’, which in turn are derived from estimating ‘potential output’. The evolution of potential output and the output gap play key roles in any assessment of the current position of the Scottish economy, and in turn the outlook for future economic growth and tax revenues. This article looks at these concepts in more detail. In what follows we explain the concept of the output gap, its relevance to policy, how output gaps in a given economy can be estimated and why the estimates are always uncertain. We then discuss current views on the evolution of the UK’s output gap and the SFC’s estimates of Scotland’s output gap and end by discussing whether estimates of the output gap currently tell policymakers what they really need to know. What is the output gap30? In general, economists are not only interested in whether output is going up or down, but also in whether it is above or below its potential. The output gap provides an assessment, at a given point in time, of the difference between an economy’s estimated productive potential (typically referred to as ‘potential output’) and the actual level of output. Potential output is the maximum amount of goods and services an economy can produce when it operating efficiently, that is, at full capacity.
    [Show full text]
  • Money and Information in a New Neoclassical Synthesis Framework
    Money and Information in a New Neoclassical Synthesis Framework Philip Arestis Georgios Chortareas John D. Tsoukalas∗ University of Cambridge University of Athens University of Nottingham University of Essex Revised: May 2009 Abstract We consider an (otherwise standard) New Neoclassical Synthesis theoretical framework that allows a role for money. Money in our model has an informational role which consists in facilitating the estimation of the unobserved shocks that drive potential output and thus the state of the economy. For this purpose we estimate a small-scale sticky price model using Bayesian techniques. Our findings support the view that money has information value. This is reflected in higher precision in terms of unobserved model concepts such as the natural rate of output. Moreover, our results highlight how modelling money demand can provide insights about structural features of the economy that may be important for the design of interest rate rules. Focusing on money also allows for a step towards resolving the price puzzle. Money demand shocks can confound monetary policy shocks to generate a perverse price response in vector autoregressions (VAR). JEL classification: D58, E31, E32, E52. Key words: DSGE models; New Keynesian models; Money; Monetary Policy; Bayesian analysis. ∗ Corresponding author: [email protected]. We thank two anonymous referees for helpful suggestions and com- ments that improved the paper. We also like to thank Kostas Katirtzidis for excellent research assistance. 1 1 Introduction Conventional wisdom renders money redundant in the current consensus business cycle models used for policy analysis. The New Keynesian (or New Neoclassical Synthesis –NNS) model with sticky prices has become the standard workhorse for monetary policy analysis in the last fifteen years or so (see Rotemberg and Woodford (1997), Goodfriend and King (1997), Gal´ı (2003)).
    [Show full text]
  • Monetary Policy in the New Neoclassical Synthesis: a Primer
    Monetary Policy in the New Neoclassical Synthesis: A Primer Marvin Goodfriend¤ Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond September 2002 Abstract This primer provides an understanding of the mechanics and objectives of mone- tary policy using a benchmark new neoclassical synthesis (NNS) macromodel. The NNS model incorporates classical features such as a real business cycle (RBC) core, and Keynesian features such as monopolistically competitive …rms and costly price adjustment. Price stability maximizes welfare in the benchmark NNS model be- cause it keeps output at its potential de…ned as the outcome of an imperfectly competitive RBC model with a constant markup of price over marginal cost. ¤Senior Vice President and Policy Advisor. The paper was prepared for the July 2002 International Finance conference “Stabilizing the Economy: What Roles for Fiscal and Monetary Policy?” at the Council on Foreign Relations in New York. The discussant, Mark Gertler, provided valuable com- ments, as did Al Broaddus, Huberto Ennis, Robert Hetzel, Andreas Hornstein, Bennett McCallum, Adam Posen, and Paul Romer. Thanks are also due to students at the GSB University of Chicago, the GSB Stanford University, and the University of Virginia who saw earlier versions of this work and helped to improve the exposition. The views expressed are the author’s and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System. Correspondence: Mar- [email protected]. 1 Introduction Great progress was made in the theory of monetary policy in
    [Show full text]
  • The Impact of COVID on Potential Output
    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO WORKING PAPER SERIES The Impact of COVID on Potential Output John Fernald Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Huiyu Li Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco March 2021 Working Paper 2021-09 https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/working-papers/2021/09/ Suggested citation: Fernald, John, Huiyu Li. 2021 “The Impact of COVID on Potential Output,” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper 2021-09. https://doi.org/10.24148/wp2021-09 The views in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco or the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. The Impact of COVID on Potential Output John Fernald Huiyu Li∗ Draft: March 22, 2021 Abstract The level of potential output is likely to be subdued post-COVID relative to its pre-pandemic estimates. Most clearly, capital input and full-employment labor will both be lower than they previously were. Quantitatively, however, these effects appear relatively modest. In the long run, labor scarring could lead to lower levels of employment, but the slow pre-recession pace of GDP growth is unlikely to be substantially affected. Keywords: Growth accounting, productivity, potential output. JEL codes: E01, E23, E24, O47 ∗Fernald: Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco and INSEAD; Li: Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco. We thank Mitchell Ochse for excellent research support. Any opinions and conclusions expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the views of the Federal Reserve System.
    [Show full text]