University of Warwick Institutional Repository

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

University of Warwick Institutional Repository University of Warwick institutional repository: http://go.warwick.ac.uk/wrap A Thesis Submitted for the Degree of PhD at the University of Warwick http://go.warwick.ac.uk/wrap/4063 This thesis is made available online and is protected by original copyright. Please scroll down to view the document itself. Please refer to the repository record for this item for information to help you to cite it. Our policy information is available from the repository home page. 1G 19 1 MENS TAT AI OLEM Models for the Price of a Storable Commodity by Diana Ribeiro Thesis Submitted in partial fulfilment of the requirements to the University of Warwick for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy Financial Options Research Centre, Warwick Business School May 2004 THE UNIVERSITY OF WARWICK Contents List of Tables V List of Figures vii Acknowledgments x Declarations xii Abstract AV Abbreviations xvi Chapter 1 Introduction 1 1.1 Background 1 ......... ................. 1.2 Summary Current Research 5 of ................. 1.3 Objectives 8 .......... ................. 1.4 Overview 9 ........... ................. Chapter 2 Literature Review 13 2.1 Introduction 13 ......... ................ 2.2 The theory of Storage 14 .... ................ 2.2.1 Convenience Yield 14 ................ 2.2.2 Risk-Premium ..................... 18 2.3 Commodity Price Models ................... 19 2.3.1 Structural Models ................... 20 2.3.2 A Partial Equilibrium Real Options Model 41 2.3.3 Reduced Form Models ................. 46 24 Conchicion 65 Chapter 3A Structural Model for the Price Dynamics: Competitive and Monopolistic Markets 70 3.1 Introduction 70 ............................ 3.2 Storage Equilibrium 75 ........................ 3.2.1 Model Formulation 77 ..................... 3.2.2 Linear Inverse Demand Function 85 .............. 3.3 Numerical Implementation 86 ..................... 3.3.1 Space-time Discretization the Explicit Solution 87 and .... 3.4 Results 90 ............................... 3.4.1 Competitive Case 92 ..................... 3.4.2 Monopolistic Case 96 ..................... 3.4.3 Comparison Between the Competitive and the Monopolistic Markets 96 .......................... 3.5 Extension Model to Include Seasonality 100 of the .......... 3.6 Conclusion 101 ............................. Chapter 4A Structural Model for the Price Dynamics: Analysis of the Forward Curve 105 4.1 Introduction 105 ............................ 4.2 Description of the Lattice Model 108 ................. 4.2.1 The Branching Process 108 .................. 4.2.2 The Merging Process 113 ................... 4.3 Calculation of the Forward Curve the Convenience Yield 114 and ... 4.3.1 Results 115 ........................... 4.4 Conclusion 124 ............................. Chapter 5A Contango Constrained Reduced Form Model 126 5.1 Introduction 126 ............................ 5.2 Model Definition 129 .......................... 5.3 Numerical Implementation 134 ..................... 5.3.1 Lattice Description 135 ..................... 5.4 Numerical Results 138 ......................... 5.4.1 Results from Lattice Model 138 the .............. 5.5 Conclusion 146 ............................. Chapter 6A Two-Factor Model for Commodity Prices and Futures Valuation 149 6.1 Introduction 149 ............................ 6.2 Valuation Model 153 .......................... 6.3 Empirical Estimation the Joint Stochastic Process 160 of ....... 6.3.1 State Space Formulation 162 .................. 6.3.2 Empirical Results 165 ...................... 6.4 Conclusion 171 ............................. Chapter 7 Conclusion 173 7.1 Summary Contributions 173 and ... ............... T2 Limitations Further Research 179 and ............... Appendix A Derivation of the Stochastic Dynamic Programming Equa- tion 182 Appendix B Calculation of the Spot Prices Variability 185 Appendix C Lattice Model for the Ornstein- Uhlenbeck Process 187 Appendix D Shepard Local Interpolation 191 Appendix E Derivation Process Followed by In (pt) 193 of the xt - Appendix F Derivation of the Futures Partial Differential Equation 195 Appendix G Derivation of the ODEs and corresponding solution 197 G.1 Derivation ODEs 197 of the .......... G.2 Solution to the system of differential equations (6-14) and (6.15) with initial conditions (6.16) 198 Appendix H Kalman Filter Procedure 201 IV List of Tables 3.1 Value of the Parametersused to obtain the numerical solutions of both competitive and monopolistic markets 91 3.2 zA,, and ým,;, represent the lower and upper values of the grid for "I z-,,, . the exogenous supply rate, z. s,ývj,;, represents the storage capacity. 91 4.1 T represents the maximum time to maturity considered, dt repre- sents the time-step, I represents maximum number of combinations (s, 7.) allowed at each node of the tree, and is the new number (, the takes 116 of 5, z) combinations after merging place........ 4.2 Value of the parameters used to implement the tree for both com- 116 petitive and monopolistic markets .................. lower for 4.3 z,,Ili,. and represent the and upper values of the grid the exogenous supply rate, represents the storage capacity, 116 Values lattice 138 5.1 of the parameters used in the computation ..... 5.2 Sample moments at final T=5 for the log price sample paths c7,. 145 6.1 Light Crude Oil Futures weekly data from 17" of March 1999 to 241h,of December 2003 165 V 6.2 Estimation results and standard errors (in parentheses) for both our model and Schwartz (1997) [82] two-factor model using all the futures contracts FO, Fl, F2, F3, F4, F5 and F6 from 17" of March 1999 to 24'ý` December 2003 167 of ................... 6.3 Summary statistics both our model's and Schwartz (1997) [82] two- factor model's pricing errors in valuing futures contracts during the 17'h March 1999 to 24th December 2003. 168 whole period of of ... 6.4 Market, our model and Schwartz (1997) [82] Two-Factor Model log-returns futures 170 implied volatilities of annualized of prices. ... vi List of Figures 3.1 Competitive Case Storage - rate, u, as a function of the two state variables inventory level, 94 s, and exogenous rate of supply, z. --- 3.2 Competitive Case - Super-position of two graphs for the prices in the absence and in the presence of storage, respectively. The price is represented as a function of the two state variables inventory level, 94 s, and exogenous rate of supply, .-,. ............. Case 3.3 Competitive - Difference between prices in the presence of storage and prices in the absence of storage as a function of supply different fixed levels inventory 95 rate, at of .............. Case function 3.4 Competitive - Price variability as a of supply rate, at different fixed levels 95 of inventory .................. Storage function 3.5 Monopolistic Case - rate, v, as a of the two state variables inventory level, s, and exogenous rate of supply, 98 Super-position for in 3.6 Monopolistic Case - of two graphs the prices the absence and in the presence of storage, respectively. The price is represented as a function of the two state variables inventory level, 98 s, and exogenous rate of supply, ýý.............. Vil 3.7 Monopolistic Case - Difference between prices in the presence of storage and prices in the absence of storage as a function of supply different fixed levels 99 rate, at of inventory.............. Monopolistic Case 3.8 - Price variability as a function of supply rate, different fixed levels 99 at of inventory ................. 4.1 Part the tree for the forward 112 of computing curve .......... 4.2 Competitive case: Evolution of the forward curve when the initial 4.5 the inventory is 120 supply rate is and initial empty......... 4.3 Competitive case: Evolution of the convenience yield curve when initial is 4.5 the initial is 120 the supply rate and inventory empty. .. 4.4 Monopolistic case: Evolution of the forward curve when the initial supply rate is 4.5 and the initial inventory is empty 121 4.5 Monopolistic case: Evolution of the convenience yield curve when initial 4.5 the inventory is 121 the supply rate is and initial empty. .. 4.6 Competitive case: Evolution of the forward curve when the initial supply rate is 4.5 and the initial inventory is equal to 1.125,2.25 4.5, 122 and respectively......................... 4.7 Competitive case: Evolution of the convenience yield curve when the initial supply rate is 4.5 and the initial inventory is equal to 1.125,2.25 4.5, 122 and respectively.................. 4,8 Monopolistic case: Evolution of the forward curve when the initial supply rate is 4.5 and the initial inventory is equal to 1.125,2.25 4.5, 123 and respectively......................... 4.9 Monopolistic case: Evolution of the convenience yield curve when the initial supply rate is 4.5 and the initial inventory is equal to 1.125,2.25 4.5, 123 and respectively ................ Vill 5.1 Forward curves generated by the one-factor mean-reverting model different levels for 5-year 143 at spot price a period ........... 5.2 Forward curves generated by our model at different spot price levels for 5-year 143 a period. ................. 5.3 Convenience yield term structures generated by the one-factor mean- different levels for 5-year 144 reverting model at spot price a period. 5.4 Convenience yield term structures generated by our model at dif- ferent levels for 5-year 144 spot price a period ............. 5.5 Probability density function for the spot prices sample paths at final time T=0 for the unconstrained model. 145 5.6 Probability density function for the spot prices sample paths at final T for 146 time -- 1") our model. .......... 6.1 This figure illustrates the evolution of the forward curve for the market of futures prices and both our model and the Schwartz (1997) [82] 5th November 2002. 169 two-factor model on the of ... 6.2 This figure illustrates the evolution of the forward curve for the market of futures prices and both our model and the Schwartz (1997) [82] 18th July 2001 169 two-factor model on the of ...... 6.3 This figure illustrates the annualized volatility of futures returns implied by our model, Schwartz (1997) [82] Two-Factor Model 170 and the market data ..........
Recommended publications
  • Futures and Options Workbook
    EEXAMININGXAMINING FUTURES AND OPTIONS TABLE OF 130 Grain Exchange Building 400 South 4th Street Minneapolis, MN 55415 www.mgex.com [email protected] 800.827.4746 612.321.7101 Fax: 612.339.1155 Acknowledgements We express our appreciation to those who generously gave their time and effort in reviewing this publication. MGEX members and member firm personnel DePaul University Professor Jin Choi Southern Illinois University Associate Professor Dwight R. Sanders National Futures Association (Glossary of Terms) INTRODUCTION: THE POWER OF CHOICE 2 SECTION I: HISTORY History of MGEX 3 SECTION II: THE FUTURES MARKET Futures Contracts 4 The Participants 4 Exchange Services 5 TEST Sections I & II 6 Answers Sections I & II 7 SECTION III: HEDGING AND THE BASIS The Basis 8 Short Hedge Example 9 Long Hedge Example 9 TEST Section III 10 Answers Section III 12 SECTION IV: THE POWER OF OPTIONS Definitions 13 Options and Futures Comparison Diagram 14 Option Prices 15 Intrinsic Value 15 Time Value 15 Time Value Cap Diagram 15 Options Classifications 16 Options Exercise 16 F CONTENTS Deltas 16 Examples 16 TEST Section IV 18 Answers Section IV 20 SECTION V: OPTIONS STRATEGIES Option Use and Price 21 Hedging with Options 22 TEST Section V 23 Answers Section V 24 CONCLUSION 25 GLOSSARY 26 THE POWER OF CHOICE How do commercial buyers and sellers of volatile commodities protect themselves from the ever-changing and unpredictable nature of today’s business climate? They use a practice called hedging. This time-tested practice has become a stan- dard in many industries. Hedging can be defined as taking offsetting positions in related markets.
    [Show full text]
  • Implied Volatility Modeling
    Implied Volatility Modeling Sarves Verma, Gunhan Mehmet Ertosun, Wei Wang, Benjamin Ambruster, Kay Giesecke I Introduction Although Black-Scholes formula is very popular among market practitioners, when applied to call and put options, it often reduces to a means of quoting options in terms of another parameter, the implied volatility. Further, the function σ BS TK ),(: ⎯⎯→ σ BS TK ),( t t ………………………………(1) is called the implied volatility surface. Two significant features of the surface is worth mentioning”: a) the non-flat profile of the surface which is often called the ‘smile’or the ‘skew’ suggests that the Black-Scholes formula is inefficient to price options b) the level of implied volatilities changes with time thus deforming it continuously. Since, the black- scholes model fails to model volatility, modeling implied volatility has become an active area of research. At present, volatility is modeled in primarily four different ways which are : a) The stochastic volatility model which assumes a stochastic nature of volatility [1]. The problem with this approach often lies in finding the market price of volatility risk which can’t be observed in the market. b) The deterministic volatility function (DVF) which assumes that volatility is a function of time alone and is completely deterministic [2,3]. This fails because as mentioned before the implied volatility surface changes with time continuously and is unpredictable at a given point of time. Ergo, the lattice model [2] & the Dupire approach [3] often fail[4] c) a factor based approach which assumes that implied volatility can be constructed by forming basis vectors. Further, one can use implied volatility as a mean reverting Ornstein-Ulhenbeck process for estimating implied volatility[5].
    [Show full text]
  • Evaluating the Performance of the WTI
    An Evaluation of the Performance of Oil Price Benchmarks During the Financial Crisis Craig Pirrong Professor of Finance Energy Markets Director, Global Energy Management Institute Bauer College of Business University of Houston I. IntroDuction The events of late‐summer, 2008 through the spring of 2009 have attracted considerable attention to the performance of oil price benchmarks, most notably the Chicago Mercantile Exchange’s West Texas Intermediate crude oil contract (“WTI” or “CL” hereafter) and ICE Futures’ Brent crude oil contract (“Brent futures” or “CB” hereafter). In particular, the behavior of spreads between the prices of futures contracts of different maturities, and between futures prices and cash prices during the period following the Lehman Brothers collapse has sparked allegations that futures prices have become disconnected from the underlying cash market fundamentals. The WTI contract has been the subject of particular criticisms alleging the unrepresentativeness of the Midcontinent market as a global price benchmark. I have analyzed extensive data from the crude oil cash and futures markets to evaluate the performance of the WTI and Brent futures contracts during the LH2008‐FH2009 period. Although the analysis focuses on this period, it relies on data extending back to 1990 in order to put the performance in historical context. I have also incorporated some data on physical crude market fundamentals, most 1 notably stocks, as these are essential in providing an evaluation of contract performance and the relation between pricing and fundamentals. My conclusions are as follows: 1. The October, 2008‐March 2009 period was one of historically unprecedented volatility. By a variety of measures, volatility in this period was extremely high, even compared to the months surrounding the First Gulf War, previously the highest volatility period in the modern oil trading era.
    [Show full text]
  • An Efficient Lattice Algorithm for the LIBOR Market Model
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Xiao, Tim Article — Accepted Manuscript (Postprint) An Efficient Lattice Algorithm for the LIBOR Market Model Journal of Derivatives Suggested Citation: Xiao, Tim (2011) : An Efficient Lattice Algorithm for the LIBOR Market Model, Journal of Derivatives, ISSN 2168-8524, Pageant Media, London, Vol. 19, Iss. 1, pp. 25-40, http://dx.doi.org/10.3905/jod.2011.19.1.025 , https://jod.iijournals.com/content/19/1/25 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/200091 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu AN EFFICIENT LATTICE ALGORITHM FOR THE LIBOR MARKET MODEL 1 Tim Xiao Journal of Derivatives, 19 (1) 25-40, Fall 2011 ABSTRACT The LIBOR Market Model has become one of the most popular models for pricing interest rate products.
    [Show full text]
  • Encana Distinguished Lecture Series
    Oil Futures Prices and OPEC Spare Capacity J.P. Morgan Center for Commodities Encana Distinguished Lecture Series September 18, 2014 Ms. Hilary Till, Principal, Premia Risk Consultancy, Inc., http://www.premiarisk.com; Research Associate, EDHEC-Risk Institute, http://www.edhec-risk.com; and Co-Editor, Intelligent Commodity Investing, http://www.riskbooks.com/intelligent-commodity-investing Disclaimers • This presentation is provided for educational purposes only and should not be construed as investment advice or an offer or solicitation to buy or sell securities or other financial instruments. • The opinions expressed during this presentation are the personal opinions of Hilary Till and do not necessarily reflect those of other organizations with which Ms. Till is affiliated. • The information contained in this presentation has been assembled from sources believed to be reliable, but is not guaranteed by the presenter. • Any (inadvertent) errors and omissions are the responsibility of Ms. Till alone. 2 Oil Futures Prices and OPEC Spare Capacity I. Crude Oil’s Importance for Commodity Indexes II. Structural Curve Shape of Individual Futures Contracts III. Structural Curve Shape and the Implications for Crude Oil Futures Contracts IV. Commodity Futures Curve Shape and Inventories Icon above is based on the statue in the Chicago Board of Trade plaza. 3 Oil Futures Prices and OPEC Spare Capacity V. Special Features of Crude Oil Markets VI. What Happens When OPEC Spare Capacity Becomes Quite Low? VII. The Plausible Link Between OPEC Spare Capacity and a Crude Oil Futures Curve Shape VIII. Current (Official) Expectations on OPEC Spare Capacity IX. Trading and Investment Conclusion 4 Oil Futures Prices and OPEC Spare Capacity Appendix A: Portfolio-Level Returns from Rebalancing Appendix B: Month-to-Month Factors Influencing a Crude Oil Futures Curve Appendix C: Consideration of the “1986 Oil Tactic” 5 I.
    [Show full text]
  • Option Prices Under Bayesian Learning: Implied Volatility Dynamics and Predictive Densities∗
    Option Prices under Bayesian Learning: Implied Volatility Dynamics and Predictive Densities∗ Massimo Guidolin† Allan Timmermann University of Virginia University of California, San Diego JEL codes: G12, D83. Abstract This paper shows that many of the empirical biases of the Black and Scholes option pricing model can be explained by Bayesian learning effects. In the context of an equilibrium model where dividend news evolve on a binomial lattice with unknown but recursively updated probabilities we derive closed-form pricing formulas for European options. Learning is found to generate asymmetric skews in the implied volatility surface and systematic patterns in the term structure of option prices. Data on S&P 500 index option prices is used to back out the parameters of the underlying learning process and to predict the evolution in the cross-section of option prices. The proposed model leads to lower out-of- sample forecast errors and smaller hedging errors than a variety of alternative option pricing models, including Black-Scholes and a GARCH model. ∗We wish to thank four anonymous referees for their extensive and thoughtful comments that greatly improved the paper. We also thank Alexander David, Jos´e Campa, Bernard Dumas, Wake Epps, Stewart Hodges, Claudio Michelacci, Enrique Sentana and seminar participants at Bocconi University, CEMFI, University of Copenhagen, Econometric Society World Congress in Seattle, August 2000, the North American Summer meetings of the Econometric Society in College Park, June 2001, the European Finance Association meetings in Barcelona, August 2001, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, INSEAD, McGill, UCSD, Universit´edeMontreal,andUniversity of Virginia for discussions and helpful comments.
    [Show full text]
  • Option Prices and Implied Volatility Dynamics Under Ayesian Learning
    T|L? hUit @?_ W4T*i_ VL*@|*|) #)?@4Ut ?_ih @)it@? wi@h??} @tt4L B_L*? **@? A44ih4@?? N?iht|) Lu @*uLh?@c 5@? #i}L a?i 2bc 2fff Devwudfw Wklv sdshu vkrzv wkdw pdq| ri wkh hpslulfdo eldvhv ri wkh Eodfn dqg Vfkrohv rswlrq sulflqj prgho fdq eh h{sodlqhg e| Ed|hvldq ohduqlqj hhfwv1 Lq wkh frqwh{w ri dq htxloleulxp prgho zkhuh glylghqg qhzv hyroyh rq d elqrpldo odwwlfh zlwk xqnqrzq exw uhfxuvlyho| xsgdwhg suredelolwlhv zh gh0 ulyh forvhg0irup sulflqj irupxodv iru Hxurshdq rswlrqv1 Ohduqlqj lv irxqg wr jhqhudwh dv|pphwulf vnhzv lq wkh lpsolhg yrodwlolw| vxuidfh dqg v|vwhpdwlf sdwwhuqv lq wkh whup vwuxfwxuh ri rswlrq sulfhv1 Gdwd rq V)S 833 lqgh{ rswlrq sulfhv lv xvhg wr edfn rxw wkh sdudphwhuv ri wkh xqghuo|lqj ohduqlqj surfhvv dqg wr suhglfw wkh hyroxwlrq lq wkh furvv0vhfwlrq ri rswlrq sulfhv1 Wkh sursrvhg prgho ohdgv wr orzhu rxw0ri0vdpsoh iruhfdvw huuruv dqg vpdoohu khgjlqj huuruv wkdq d ydulhw| ri dowhuqdwlyh rswlrq sulflqj prghov/ lqfoxglqj Eodfn0Vfkrohv1 Zh zlvk wr wkdqn Doh{dqghu Gdylg/ Mrvh Fdpsd/ Ehuqdug Gxpdv/ Fodxglr Plfkhodffl/ Hq0 ultxh Vhqwdqd dqg vhplqdu sduwlflsdqwv dw Erffrql Xqlyhuvlw|/ FHPIL/ Ihghudo Uhvhuyh Edqn ri Vw1 Orxlv/ LQVHDG/ PfJloo/ XFVG/ Xqlyhuvlw| ri Ylujlqld dqg Xqlyhuvlw| ri \run iru glvfxvvlrqv dqg khosixo frpphqwv1 W?|hL_U|L? *|L} *@U! @?_ 5UL*it< Eb. uLh4*@ hi4@?t |i 4Lt| UL44L?*) ti_ LT |L? ThU?} 4L_i* ? ?@?U@* 4@h!i|tc @ *@h}i *|ih@|hi @t _LU4i?|i_ |t t|hL?} i4ThU@* M@tit Lt| UL44L?*)c tU M@tit @hi @ttLU@|i_ | |i @TTi@h@?Ui Lu t)t|i4@|U T@||ih?t Et4*it Lh t!it ? |i 4T*i_ L*@|*|) thu@Ui ThL_Ui_ M) ?ih|?}
    [Show full text]
  • VIX Futures As a Market Timing Indicator
    Journal of Risk and Financial Management Article VIX Futures as a Market Timing Indicator Athanasios P. Fassas 1 and Nikolas Hourvouliades 2,* 1 Department of Accounting and Finance, University of Thessaly, Larissa 41110, Greece 2 Department of Business Studies, American College of Thessaloniki, Thessaloniki 55535, Greece * Correspondence: [email protected]; Tel.: +30-2310-398385 Received: 10 June 2019; Accepted: 28 June 2019; Published: 1 July 2019 Abstract: Our work relates to the literature supporting that the VIX also mirrors investor sentiment and, thus, contains useful information regarding future S&P500 returns. The objective of this empirical analysis is to verify if the shape of the volatility futures term structure has signaling effects regarding future equity price movements, as several investors believe. Our findings generally support the hypothesis that the VIX term structure can be employed as a contrarian market timing indicator. The empirical analysis of this study has important practical implications for financial market practitioners, as it shows that they can use the VIX futures term structure not only as a proxy of market expectations on forward volatility, but also as a stock market timing tool. Keywords: VIX futures; volatility term structure; future equity returns; S&P500 1. Introduction A fundamental principle of finance is the positive expected return-risk trade-off. In this paper, we examine the dynamic dependencies between future equity returns and the term structure of VIX futures, i.e., the curve that connects daily settlement prices of individual VIX futures contracts to maturities across time. This study extends the VIX futures-related literature by testing the market timing ability of the VIX futures term structure regarding future stock movements.
    [Show full text]
  • What's Price Got to Do with Term Structure?
    What’s Price Got To Do With Term Structure? An Introduction to the Change in Realized Roll Yields: Redefining How Forward Curves Are Measured Contributors: Historically, investors have been drawn to the systematic return opportunities, or beta, of commodities due to their potentially inflation-hedging and Jodie Gunzberg, CFA diversifying properties. However, because contango was a persistent market Vice President, Commodities condition from 2005 to 2011, occurring in 93% of the months during that time, [email protected] roll yield had a negative impact on returns. As a result, it may have seemed to some that the liquidity risk premium had disappeared. Marya Alsati-Morad Associate Director, Commodities However, as discussed in our paper published in September 2013, entitled [email protected] “Identifying Return Opportunities in A Demand-Driven World Economy,” the environment may be changing. Specifically, the world economy may be Peter Tsui shifting from one driven by expansion of supply to one driven by expansion of Director, Index Research & Design demand, which could have a significant impact on commodity performance. [email protected] This impact would be directly related to two hallmarks of a world economy driven by expansion of demand: the increasing persistence of backwardation and the more frequent flipping of term structures. In order to benefit in this changing economic environment, the key is to implement flexibility to keep pace with the quickly changing term structures. To achieve flexibility, there are two primary ways to modify the first-generation ® flagship index, the S&P GSCI . The first method allows an index to select contracts with expirations that are either near- or longer-dated based on the commodity futures’ term structure.
    [Show full text]
  • Term Structure Lattice Models
    Term Structure Models: IEOR E4710 Spring 2005 °c 2005 by Martin Haugh Term Structure Lattice Models 1 The Term-Structure of Interest Rates If a bank lends you money for one year and lends money to someone else for ten years, it is very likely that the rate of interest charged for the one-year loan will di®er from that charged for the ten-year loan. Term-structure theory has as its basis the idea that loans of di®erent maturities should incur di®erent rates of interest. This basis is grounded in reality and allows for a much richer and more realistic theory than that provided by the yield-to-maturity (YTM) framework1. We ¯rst describe some of the basic concepts and notation that we need for studying term-structure models. In these notes we will often assume that there are m compounding periods per year, but it should be clear what changes need to be made for continuous-time models and di®erent compounding conventions. Time can be measured in periods or years, but it should be clear from the context what convention we are using. Spot Rates: Spot rates are the basic interest rates that de¯ne the term structure. De¯ned on an annual basis, the spot rate, st, is the rate of interest charged for lending money from today (t = 0) until time t. In particular, 2 mt this implies that if you lend A dollars for t years today, you will receive A(1 + st=m) dollars when the t years have elapsed.
    [Show full text]
  • Decision Analysis and Real Options: a Discrete Time Approach to Real Option Valuation
    Annals of Operations Research 135, 21–39, 2005 c 2005 Springer Science + Business Media, Inc. Manufactured in The Netherlands. Decision Analysis and Real Options: A Discrete Time Approach to Real Option Valuation LUIZ E. BRANDAO˜ [email protected] JAMES S. DYER [email protected] The University of Texas at Austin, McCombs School of Business, Department of Management Science and Information Systems, 1 University Station B6500, CBA 5.202, Austin, TX 78712-1175 Abstract. In this paper we seek to enhance the real options methodology developed by Copeland and Antikarov (2001) with traditional decision analysis tools to propose a discrete time method that allows the problem to be specified and solved with off the shelf decision analysis software. This method uses dynamic programming with an innovative algorithm to model the project’s stochastic process and real options with decision trees. The method is computationally intense, but simpler and more intuitive than traditional methods, thus allowing for greater flexibility in the modeling of the problem. Keywords: real options, lattice methods, decision trees Introduction Due to its importance for the creation of value for the shareholder, the investment decision in the firm has always been a focus of academic and managerial interest. The use of the discounted cash flow method (DCF), introduced in firms in the 1950’s, was initially considered a sophisticated approach for the valuation of projects due to the need to use present value tables. In spite of its obvious advantages over the obsolete payback method, its widespread use occurred only after the development of portable calculators and computers that automated the necessary financial calculations, and most practitioners currently consider it the model of choice.
    [Show full text]
  • Structural Position-Taking in Crude Oil Futures Contracts
    Structural Position-Taking in Crude Oil Futures Contracts November 2015 Hilary Till Research Associate, EDHEC-Risk Institute Principal, Premia Research LLC Abstract Should an investor enter into long-term positions in oil futures contracts? In answering this question, this paper will cover the following three considerations: (1) the case for structural positions in crude oil futures contracts; (2) useful indicators for avoiding crash risk; and (3) financial asset diversification for downside hedging of oil price risk. This paper will conclude by noting the conditions under which one might consider including oil futures contracts in an investment portfolio. This paper is provided for educational purposes only and should not be construed as investment advice or an offer or solicitation to buy or sell securities or other financial instruments. The views expressed in this article are the personal opinions of Hilary Till and do not necessarily reflect the views of institutions with which Ms. Till is affiliated. Research assistance from Katherine Farren, CAIA, of Premia Risk Consultancy, Inc. is gratefully acknowledged. EDHEC is one of the top five business schools in France. Its reputation is built on the high quality of its faculty and the privileged relationship with professionals that the school has cultivated since its establishment in 1906. EDHEC Business School has decided to draw on its extensive knowledge of the professional environment and has therefore focused its research on themes that satisfy the needs of professionals. EDHEC pursues an active research policy in the field of finance. EDHEC-Risk Institute carries out numerous research programmes in the areas of asset allocation and risk management in both the 2 traditional and alternative investment universes.
    [Show full text]