The Role of International Reserves and Foreign Debt in the External Adjustment Process

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Role of International Reserves and Foreign Debt in the External Adjustment Process The Role of International Reserves and Foreign Debt in the External Adjustment Process SEBASTIAN EDWARDS* 1. INTRODUCTION During the 1970s the developing countries underwent serious current account deficits in their balance of payments, which led, inter alia, to major increases in their foreign debt. Whereas in 1970 the public and publicly guaranteed debt of the low-income countries (excluding the People's Republic of China and India) amounted to 16.5 percent of their gross national product (GNP), in 1980 it had risen to 31.5 percent of GNP. On the other hand, the ratio of foreign public and publicly guaranteed debt of the middle-income countries increased from 11.8 percent of GNP in 1970 to 17.4 percent of GNP in 1980.1 More recently, some developing countries—Mexico, Brazil, Costa Rica, and Argentina, for instance—have faced serious problems in servicing their foreign debt. The analysis of the determinants of the current account of the balance of payments, and its relation to macroeconomic adjustment, has lately made significant progress. Particular emphasis has been given to the intertemporal nature of the current account, and the distinction has been made between temporary and permanent shocks.2 It has been postulated, for instance, that whereas the most appropriate policy to face temporary shock is to increase the level of foreign debt (or reduce the level of international reserves), reduction of the level of internal absorption is the optimum policy in response to a permanent shock.3 Despite renewed interest in analyzing the macroeconomic adjustment process in an open economy, most of the papers, theoretical as well as empirical, emphasize the use of a particular tool to achieve such adjustment. Thus, for instance, while certain authors have made a detailed analysis of the *I am indebted to Sergio Malaga and Juan Guillermo Espinosa for their valuable comments. (The original version of this paper was written in Spanish.) 1See World Bank, World Development Report, 1982. 2See, for example, Sachs (1981), (1982). 3See Sachs (1981), Obstfeld (1982) and Svensson and Razin (1983). 143 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 144 SEBASTIAN EDWARDS use of foreign debt as an instrument for adjustment, others have focused on the use of reserves, and a third group has examined in detail the role of the exchange rate and its relation to the current account.4 Exceptions to this rule are Eaton and Gersovitz (1980), who have analyzed the joint determination of international reserves and foreign debt; Edwards (1983 a), who has explicitly considered the use of the exchange rate as an adjustment tool in the analysis of demand for international reserves; and Frenkel and Aizenman (1982), who have theoretically examined the joint determination of the optimum degree of float for a currency and the level of reserves the country wishes to maintain. The purpose of this paper is to analyze in some detail the role of international reserves and external debt in the process of macroeconomic adjustment in developing countries, with particular emphasis on Latin American countries. The discussion explicitly recognizes that both reserves and debt are alternative instruments that countries may use to achieve external balance.5 In addition, it is recognized that foreign debt plays a twofold role in the economic process. First, in the short run, changes in the external debt make it possible to cope with temporary external disequilibria. Second, foreign debt plays a long-run role connected with financing gross domestic investment. In fact, insofar as the current account deficit—which is equal to external savings—is partly or totally financed by new (net) foreign borrowing, the foreign debt will be playing a major long-term role in the development and economic growth process. It is precisely this twofold role played by foreign debt that requires developing countries to find ways to manage it carefully. In this context it is important, for example, to make the needs for external resources to finance gross investment compatible with the uses of debt for short-term purposes. Appropriate planning of the evolution of external liabilities and assets of the monetary system will prevent imbalances that may turn out very costly in the long run.6 In this paper various problems connected with the role of international reserves and foreign debt in the external adjustment process are empirically analyzed. Section 2 contains a general discussion of the subject, emphasizing the fact that most of the economic literature dealing with demand for international reserves has failed to consider explicitly the role played by debt (or exchange rate variations) in the external adjustment process. This section also presents a discussion—and a word of caution—on the use of dynamic optimization models to determine the optimum degree of debt for a country. Section 3, in turn, presents new empirical evidence on the determinants of 4See, for example, Dornbusch and Fischer (1980) and Rodriguez (1980). 5It is further recognized, theoretically, that adjustments in the exchange rate play a similar role. In the empirical analysis the inclusion of such adjustments did not affect the results, hence they are not presented in this paper. 6See Loser (1977). ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution INTERNATIONAL RESERVES AND FOREIGN DEBT 145 demand for international reserves in the developing countries, using data for 1975-80. This section also presents results obtained when reserves and debt are considered to be alternative instruments for achieving external equilib- rium. The main conclusions reached in this section are that: (a) the demand for reserves in the developing countries has been a stable function in the past few years, although from a legal standpoint the international monetary system has been characterized by a dirty float;7 (b) demand for reserves in the developing countries displays diseconomies of scale showing that, as a result of economic growth, such countries' need for international liquidity will grow more than proportionately in the next few years; (c) reserves and foreign debt are substitutes, in the sense that both have been used by these countries as alternative ways to finance their external adjustment processes. Section 4 of the paper examines a critical issue for macroeconomic management of reserves and foreign debt. The section discusses in what way the levels of debt and reserves, among other variables, affect the level of country risk perceived by the international financial community. The importance of this discussion lies in the fact that should a relation exist between these variables and the probability of default perceived by the international financial community, countries may manage these variables in such a way that the degree of risk of default perceived is kept at relatively low levels. This in turn will lead to more favorable terms for obtaining foreign funds and continuing maintenance of such loans. The results presented in this section, based on data from over 700 public and publicly guaranteed loans granted in the period 1976-80 in the Eurocurrency market, show that the higher the debt/output ratio the higher the perceived probability of default. It was further found that a higher international liquidity ratio will result in a lower perceived country risk. In Section 5 an empirical analysis on the relation between the dynamic adjustment of international reserves and monetary market equilibrium is presented. This analysis shows that international reserve movements over time arise essentially from two factors: (a) discrepancies between desired reserves and reserves actually maintained; and (b) imbalances in the monetary market. These results—which basically correspond to the analysis presented in the monetary approach to the balance of payments—point out that situations of excess supply of money will tend to result in international reserves dropping below desired levels. The above findings, in the light of results obtained from analysis of country risk determinants, have obvious implications in terms of economic policy. Insofar as a country wishes to 7Of course while the currencies of industrial countries have tended to float (dirtily), developing countries have adhered to the most diverse exchange arrangements. See the introduction in any recent issue of the International Monetary Fund publication International Financial Statistics (IFS) for a list of such agreements. ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution 146 SEBASTIAN EDWARDS maintain an acceptable (conservative) degree of perceived country risk, it must be particularly careful in the way it handles its monetary policy. Section 6 of the paper contains some considerations on the case of the Latin American countries, with emphasis on the importance of designing a coherent exchange rate policy to deal with macroeconomic adjustment problems. Finally, some concluding remarks are offered in Section 7. 2. INTERNATIONAL RESERVES AND FOREIGN DEBT IN THE MACROECONOMIC ADJUSTMENT PROCESS There is an extensive literature, empirical as well as theoretical, on the role of international reserves in the external adjustment process, which has been reviewed, among others, by Clower and Lipsey (1968), Gruebel (1971), Williamson (1973), and Bird (1978). Generally speaking, most of the studies on the subject assume that countries maintain reserves both for financing international transactions and for facing unforeseen international payment difficulties. Hippie (1974), for instance,
Recommended publications
  • Capitalists and Revolution
    CAPITALISTS AND REVOLUTION Rose J. Spalding Working Paper #202 - March 1994 Rose J. Spalding, residential fellow at the Institute during the fall semester 1991, is Associate Professor of Political Science at DePaul University. Her publications include The Political Economy of Revolutionary Nicaragua (Boston: Allen and Unwin, 1987) and Capitalists and Revolution: Opposition and Accommodation in Nicaragua, 1979-1992 (Chapel Hill, NC: University of North Carolina Press, forthcoming 1994). Research for this paper was conducted with support from the College of Liberal Arts and Sciences and University Research Council of DePaul University, the Social Science Research Council and American Council of Learned Societies, and the Heinz Endowment. ABSTRACT This paper explores the relationship between the state and the economic elite during four cases of structural reform. Analyzing state-capital relations in Chile under the Allende government, El Salvador following the 1979 reforms, Mexico during the Cárdenas era, and Peru under the Velasco regime, the author finds substantial variation in the ways in which the business elite responded to state-led reform efforts. In the first two cases, the bourgeoisie tended to unite in opposition to the regime; in the second two, it was relatively fragmented and notable sectors sought an accommodation with the regime. To explain this variation, the paper focuses on the role of five factors: the degree to which class hegemony is exercised by a traditional oligarchy; the level of organizational autonomy attained by business elites; the perception of a class-based threat; the degree to which the regime consolidates politically; and the viability of the economic model introduced by the reform regime.
    [Show full text]
  • Modern Monetary Theory: Cautionary Tales from Latin America
    Modern Monetary Theory: Cautionary Tales from Latin America Sebastian Edwards* Economics Working Paper 19106 HOOVER INSTITUTION 434 GALVEZ MALL STANFORD UNIVERSITY STANFORD, CA 94305-6010 April 25, 2019 According to Modern Monetary Theory (MMT) it is possible to use expansive monetary policy – money creation by the central bank (i.e. the Federal Reserve) – to finance large fiscal deficits that will ensure full employment and good jobs for everyone, through a “jobs guarantee” program. In this paper I analyze some of Latin America’s historical episodes with MMT-type policies (Chile, Peru. Argentina, and Venezuela). The analysis uses the framework developed by Dornbusch and Edwards (1990, 1991) for studying macroeconomic populism. The four experiments studied in this paper ended up badly, with runaway inflation, huge currency devaluations, and precipitous real wage declines. These experiences offer a cautionary tale for MMT enthusiasts.† JEL Nos: E12, E42, E61, F31 Keywords: Modern Monetary Theory, central bank, inflation, Latin America, hyperinflation The Hoover Institution Economics Working Paper Series allows authors to distribute research for discussion and comment among other researchers. Working papers reflect the views of the author and not the views of the Hoover Institution. * Henry Ford II Distinguished Professor, Anderson Graduate School of Management, UCLA † I have benefited from discussions with Ed Leamer, José De Gregorio, Scott Sumner, and Alejandra Cox. I thank Doug Irwin and John Taylor for their support. 1 1. Introduction During the last few years an apparently new and revolutionary idea has emerged in economic policy circles in the United States: Modern Monetary Theory (MMT). The central tenet of this view is that it is possible to use expansive monetary policy – money creation by the central bank (i.e.
    [Show full text]
  • The Macroeconomics of Populism in Latin America
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: The Macroeconomics of Populism in Latin America Volume Author/Editor: Rudiger Dornbusch and Sebastian Edwards, editors Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-15843-8 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/dorn91-1 Conference Date: May 18-19, 1990 Publication Date: January 1991 Chapter Title: The Macroeconomics of Populism Chapter Author: Rudiger Dornbusch, Sebastian Edwards Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c8295 Chapter pages in book: (p. 7 - 13) 1 The Macroeconomics of Populism Rudiger Dornbusch and Sebastian Edwards Latin America’s economic history seems to repeat itself endlessly, following irregular and dramatic cycles. This sense of circularity is particularly striking with respect to the use of populist macroeconomic policies for distributive purposes. Again and again, and in country after country, policymakers have embraced economic programs that rely heavily on the use of expansive fiscal and credit policies and overvalued currency to accelerate growth and redistrib- ute income. In implementing these policies, there has usually been no concern for the existence of fiscal and foreign exchange constraints. After a short pe- riod of economic growth and recovery, bottlenecks develop provoking unsus- tainable macroeconomic pressures that, at the end, result in the plummeting of real wages and severe balance of payment difficulties. The final outcome of these experiments has generally been galloping inflation, crisis, and the col- lapse of the economic system. In the aftermath of these experiments there is no other alternative left but to implement, typically with the help of the Inter- national Monetary Fund (IMF), a drastically restrictive and costly stabiliza- tion program.
    [Show full text]
  • Capital Controls, Sudden Stops, and Current Account Reversals
    This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Capital Controls and Capital Flows in Emerging Economies: Policies, Practices and Consequences Volume Author/Editor: Sebastian Edwards, editor Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-18497-8 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/edwa06-1 Conference Date: December 16-18, 2004 Publication Date: May 2007 Title: Capital Controls, Sudden Stops, and Current Account Reversals Author: Sebastian Edwards URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c0149 2 Capital Controls, Sudden Stops, and Current Account Reversals Sebastian Edwards 2.1 Introduction During the last few years a number of authors have argued that free cap- ital mobility produces macroeconomic instability and contributes to fi- nancial vulnerability in the emerging nations. For example, in his critique of the U.S. Treasury and the International Monetary Fund (IMF), Stiglitz (2002) has argued that pressuring emerging and transition countries to re- lax controls on capital mobility during the 1990s was a huge mistake. Ac- cording to him, the easing of controls on capital mobility was at the center of most (if not all) currency crises in the emerging markets during the last decade—Mexico in 1994, East Asia in 1997, Russia in 1998, Brazil in 1999, Turkey in 2001, and Argentina in 2002. These days, even the IMF seems to criticize free capital mobility and to provide (at least some) support for capital controls. Indeed, on a visit to Malaysia in September 2003 Horst Koehler, then the IMF’s managing director, praised the policies of Prime Minister Mahathir, and in particular his use of capital controls in the after- math of the 1997 currency crisis (Beattie 2003).
    [Show full text]
  • Left Behind Latin America and the False Promise of Populism
    Left Behind Latin America and the False Promise of Populism Sebastian Edwards THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO PRESS I CHICAGO AND LONDON Contents Preface xi 1 Latin America: The Eternal Land of the Future 1 • The Economic Future of Latin America and the United States • From the Washington Consensus to the Resurgence of Populism: A Brief Overview - The Main Argument: A Summary • A Conceptual Framework: The Economic Prosperity of -. Nations and the Mechanics of Successful Growth Transitions PART ONE A Long Decline: From Independence to the Washington Consensus 2 Latin America's Decline: A Long Historical View 21 • A Gradual and Persistent Decline j The Poverty of Institutions and Long-Term Mediocrity - Currency Crises, Instability, and Inflation - Inequality and Poverty - So Far from God, and So Close to the United States 3 From the Alliance for Progress to the Washington Consensus 47 • The Cuban Revolution and the Alliance for Progress • Protectionism and. Social Conditions ' Informality and Unemployment • Fiscal Profligacy, Monetary Largesse, Instability, and Currency Crises • - Oil Shocks and Debt Crisis • The Lost Decade, Market Reforms, and the Washington Consensus PART TWO The Washington Consensus and the Recurrence of Crises, 1989-2002 4 Fractured Liberalism: Latin Americas Incomplete Reforms 71 • Institutions and Economic Performance - Institutions Interrupted: A Latin American Scorecard - Economic Policy Reform: A Decalogue Manque * Summing Up: Mediocre Policies and Weak Institutions v __^ 5 Chile, Latin America's Brightest Star 101 *
    [Show full text]
  • Nber Working Paper Series Latin America's Decline: A
    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES LATIN AMERICA'S DECLINE: A LONG HISTORICAL VIEW Sebastian Edwards Working Paper 15171 http://www.nber.org/papers/w15171 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 July 2009 ¸˛I thank Alberto Naudon and Jéssica Roldán for their excellent assistance and comments. The views expressed herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research. NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer- reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official NBER publications. © 2009 by Sebastian Edwards. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Latin America's Decline: A Long Historical View Sebastian Edwards NBER Working Paper No. 15171 July 2009 JEL No. F30,F32,N26,O40,O54 ABSTRACT In this paper I analyze Latin America's very long term economic performance (since the early 18th century), and I compare it with that of the United States, Australia, New Zealand and the countries of Western Europe. I begin with an analysis of long term data and an attempt at determining when the region's decline really began. The next section deals with the relation between the strength of institutions since colonial rule and the region’s economic performance. Next I move to an analysis of Latin America's long history with instability, crises and debt defaults.
    [Show full text]
  • Curriculum Vitae
    CURRICULUM VITAE James A. Robinson University of Chicago Harris School of Public Policy 1307 E 60th St, Chicago, IL 60637 Telephone: (773) 702 6364 E-Mail: [email protected] Website: http://scholar.harris.uchicago.edu/jamesrobinson Nationality: British, USA Education: Ph.D. Yale University, 1993 M.A. University of Warwick, 1985-1986 BSc. (Econ) London School of Economics and Political Science, 1979-1982 Main Fields: Political Economy and Comparative Politics. Economic and Political Development. Current Positions: Reverend Dr. Richard L. Pearson Professor of Global Conflict Studies, since July 1, 2016. University Professor, University of Chicago, since July 1, 2015. Previous Positions: Wilbur A. Cowett Professor of Government, Harvard University, July 1, 2014- June 30, 2015. David Florence Professor of Government, Harvard University, July 1, 2009-June 30, 2014. Professor of Government, Harvard University, July 1, 2004-June 30, 2009. Associate Professor of Political Science and Economics, University of California at Berkeley, July 1, 2001-June 30, 2004. Assistant Professor of Political Science, University of California at Berkeley, July 1, 1999-July 1 2001. Assistant Professor of Economics, University of Southern California, September 1, 1995- June 30, 1999. Lecturer in Economics, University of Melbourne, September 1, 1992-August 30, 1995. Other Activities: Director of the Pearson Institute for the Study and Resolution of Global Conflicts since July 1, 2016. Academic Adviser to the World Bank’s World Development Report 2017. Member of the board of the Global Development Network, January 1, 2009 – December 31, 2011. Member of the Swedish Development Policy Council, a committee advising the Swedish Foreign Minister on Sweden’s International Development Policy, 2007-2010.
    [Show full text]
  • Financial Markets Volatility and Performance in Emerging Markets
    Financial Markets Volatility and Performance in Emerging Markets A National Bureau of Economic Research Conference Report Financial Markets Volatility and Performance in Emerging Markets Edited by Sebastian Edwards and Márcio G. P. Garcia The University of Chicago Press Chicago and London Sebastian Edwards is the Henry Ford II Professor of International Business Economics at the Anderson Graduate School of Management at the University of California, Los Angeles, and a research associate of the National Bureau of Economic Research. MÁRCIO G. P. GARCIA is an associate professor of economics at Pontifical Catholic University, Rio de Janeiro (PUC-Rio), and a researcher affiliated with the National Council of Scientific and Technological Development (CNPq) and the Research Support Foundation of Rio de Janeiro (FAPERJ). The University of Chicago Press, Chicago 60637 The University of Chicago Press, Ltd., London © 2008 by the National Bureau of Economic Research All rights reserved. Published 2008 Printed in the United States of America 1716151413121110090812345 ISBN-13: 978-0-226-18495-1 (cloth) ISBN-10: 0-226-18495-1 (cloth) Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Financial markets volatility and performance in emerging markets / edited by Sebastian Edwards and Márcio G. P. Garcia. p. cm. — (A National Bureau of Economic Research conference report) Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN-13: 978-0-226-18495-1 (cloth : alk. paper) ISBN-10: 0-226-18495-1 (cloth : alk. paper) 1. Capital market—Developing countries. 2. Capital movements—Developing countries. I. Edwards, Sebastian, 1953– II. Garcia, Márcio Gomes Pinto. HG5993.F558 2008 332'.0415091724—dc22 2007024129 o The paper used in this publication meets the minimum requirements of the American National Standard for Information Sciences— Permanence of Paper for Printed Library Materials, ANSI Z39.48-1992.
    [Show full text]
  • Sebastian Edwards
    Curriculum Vitae September 14, 2017 SEBASTIAN EDWARDS EDUCATION UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO Ph.D. (Economics), 1981 UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO M.A. (Economics), 1978 UNIVERSIDAD CATOLICA, CHILE Licenciado Economia, 1975 Ingeniero Comercial, 1975 ACADEMIC APPOINTMENTS 2003-present ANDERSON GRADUATE SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT, UCLA The Henry Ford II Distinguished Professor of International Economics. 1996-2002 ANDERSON GRADUATE SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT, UCLA The Henry Ford II Professor of International Economics. 1993-1996 THE WORLD BANK GROUP Chief Economist for the Latin America and Caribbean Region. 1990-1993 ANDERSON GRADUATE SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT, UCLA The Henry Ford II Professor of International Business Economics. 1981-present DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, UCLA Assistant Professor (1981-85), Associate Professor (1985-1988) Professor of Economics (1988-2003) Distinguished Professor (2003-present). AWARDS, PRIZES AND HONORS Carlos Diaz Alejandro Prize for lifelong scholarly contributions to the study of Latin America, 2012 Inaugural Lecture, Universidad de Chile Faculty of Engineering, 2008 Corden Lecture, Australian National University, 2007 1 4/18/2018 Figuerola Lecture, Universidad Carlos III, Madrid, Spain, 2006 Mundell-Fleming Lecture, International Monetary Fund, 2002 Inaugural Lecture, Kiel Institute World Economy, Kiel Germany, 2001 World Economy Lecture, University of Nottingham, 2000 OTHER PROFESSIONAL AND ACADEMIC ACTIVITIES ANDERSON GRADUATE SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT, Senior Associate Dean of Global Initiatives, and Director Center for Global Management,
    [Show full text]
  • Sebastián Edwards University of California at Los Angeles
    THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN EXCHANGE RATES AND INFLATION TARGETING REVISITED Sebastián Edwards University of California at Los Angeles For decades, the exchange rate was at the center of macroeconomic policy debates in emerging markets. Many countries used the nominal exchange rate to bring down inflation; –others—mostly in Latin America—used the exchange rate to implicitly tax the export sector.1 Currency crises were common and usually resulted from acute real exchange rate overvaluation. In the 1990s, academics and policymakers debated the merits of alternative exchange rate regimes for emerging economies. Many authors drew on credibility-based theories to argue that developing and transition countries should have hard peg regimes, preferably currency boards or dollarization. One of the main arguments in favor of rigid exchange rate regimes was that emerging economies exhibited a fear of floating.2 After the currency crashes of the late 1990s and early 2000s, however, a growing number of emerging economies moved away from exchange rate rigidity and adopted a combination of flexible exchange rates and inflation targeting. Because of this move, the exchange rate I benefited from discussions with John Taylor and Ed Leamer. I thank Roberto Álvarez for his help and support. I am grateful to Andrea Tokman and Edi Hochreiter for helpful comments. 1. Argentina is perhaps the best example of a country that has used the nominal exchange rate to achieve alternative policy objectives. In the 1960s and 1970s, the real exchange rate was deliberately kept at an overvalued level to implicitly tax the agriculture sector (Díaz-Alejandro, 1970). In the early 1980s, the exchange rate was devalued at a slow, predefined rate to bring down inflation; this was the so-called tablita episode.
    [Show full text]
  • Public Sector Deficits and Macroeconomic Stability in Developing Economies
    Public Sector Deficits and Macroeconomic Stability in Developing Economies Sebastian Edwards For many developing and Eastern European countries the 1980s and early 1990s were years of macroeconomic upheaval. For instance, the debt crisis that erupted in 1982 generated significant dislocations throughout Latin America, where balance of payments deficits soared and inflation increased rapidly. In the former com- munist countries, on the other hand, the fall of the Berlin Wall was accompanied by serious macroeconomic disequilibria, large public sector deficits, and very high inflation rates. During the last few years most countries in these regions—as well as in other parts of the world, including Asia—have embarked on major structural reforms and have struggled to regain macroeconomic stability. Much of the policy discussion in these countries has centered on the most effective way of implementing stabilization programs, and has focused on a handful of key issues, including (1) alternative ways of reducing public sector deficits; (2) the appropriate use of credit and monetary policies in programs aimed at taming inflation and eliminating unsustainable external deficits; and (3) on the role of nominal exchange rate anchors as a device for reducing inflation and maintaining stability over the longer run. In many countries the stabilization efforts of the last few years have began to bear fruit, and inflation rates have declined signifi- cantly. In Latin America the average rate of inflation was reduced from over 1,200 percent in 1989 to 14 percent in 1994. Progress has also been impressive in many former communist nations: for 307 308 Sebastian Edwards instance, in Poland yearly inflation has declined from over 460 percent in 1990 to less than 33 percent in 1993.
    [Show full text]
  • Financial Openness, Currency Crises, and Output Losses
    This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Financial Markets Volatility and Performance in Emerging Markets Volume Author/Editor: Sebastian Edwards and Márcio G. P. Garcia, editors Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-18495-1 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/edwa05-1 Conference Date: December 1-3, 2005 Publication Date: March 2008 Title: Financial Openness, Currency Crises, and Output Losses Author: Sebastian Edwards URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c4775 3 Financial Openness, Currency Crises, and Output Losses Sebastian Edwards 3.1 Introduction In early March, 2006, India’s Prime Minister Manmohan Singh, an- nounced that his country would take measures toward making the rupee a convertible currency. Capital controls would be dismantled, and freer in- ternational mobility of capital would be allowed.1 This step was unthink- able only a few years back; for decades analysts associated India with a strict policy of capital controls and restrictions. Indeed, in his criticism of the International Monetary Fund (IMF), Stiglitz (2002) argued that the fundamental reason why India and China had been spared from massive currency crises was that they did not allow free capital mobility. Stiglitz went even further and argued that the easing of controls on capital mobil- ity was at the center of most (if not all) of currency crises in the emerging markets during the last decade—Mexico 1994, East Asia 1997, Russia 1998, Brazil 1999, Turkey 2001, and Argentina 2002. Whether capital controls are beneficial for emerging countries continues to be a controversial issue among experts.
    [Show full text]