On the Desirability of a Regional Basket Currency Arrangement

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

On the Desirability of a Regional Basket Currency Arrangement 1%(5:25.,1*3$3(56(5,(6 217+('(6,5$%,/,7<2)$5(*,21$/ %$6.(7&855(1&<$55$1*(0(17 (LML2JDZD 7DNDWRVKL,WR :RUNLQJ3DSHU KWWSZZZQEHURUJSDSHUVZ 1$7,21$/%85($82)(&2120,&5(6($5&+ 0DVVD.KXVHWWV$YHQXH &DPEULGJH30$ 1RYHPEHU 7KLVSDSHUZDVSUHVHQWHGDWWKH&(3,,.,(3$'%,RQIHUHQH'HHPEHU7KHDXWKRUVDUH JUDWHIXOWR*DQJ<L.HQLKL2KQRDQGRWKHUSDUWLLSDQWVRIWKHUHIHUHQHDQGWRDQRQ\PRXVUHIHUHHIRU XVHIXODQGRQVWUXWLYHRPPHQWV9LHZVH[SUHVVHGKHUHDUHDXWKRUV¶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¶V KRLH RI WKH H[KDQJH UDWH UHJLPH 0RU ZHLJKWV LQ WKH EDVNHW1 LV GHSHQGHQWRQWKHQHLJKERULQJRXQWU\¶V7KHGROODUZHLJKWVLQWKHXUUHQ\EDVNHWVRIWKHWZR RXQWULHVDUHGHWHUPLQHGDVD1DVKHTXLOLEULXP,QJHQHUDO.WKHUHDUHPXOWLSOHHTXLOLEULD.DQGD ³RRUGLQDWLRQIDLOXUH´PD\UHVXOW (LML2JDZD 7DNDWRVKL,WR 'HSDUWPHQWRI&RPPHUH 'HSXW\9LH0LQLVWHURI,QWHUQDWLRQDO$IIDLUV +LWRWVXEDVKL8QLYHUVLW\ 0LQLVWU\RI)LQDQH .XQLWDKL.7RN\R ..DVXPLJDVHNL.&KL\RGD -DSDQ 7RN\R-DSDQ #VUYKLWXDMS DQG1%(5 WDNDWRVKLLWR#PRIJRMS 1. Introduction One of the lessons from the Asian Currency Crises is the danger of the de facto dollar peg adopted by the Asian economies that had extensive trade and investment relationship with countries other than the United States.1 When the yen appreciated vis-à-vis the US dollar, the Asian economies enjoyed the boom, or a bubble in some cases, due to increased exports. But, when the yen depreciated, the Asian economies tended to experience a recession, or a burst bubble. The experience of the Asian boom and bust in the 1990s, along with the yen-dollar exchange rate fluctuation, is a stark reminder of risk of the fixed exchange rate regime. An obvious solution for this problem is to increase flexibility of the exchange rate. If the baht had appreciated during the yen appreciation phase of the 1993-95, the extent of overheating in Thailand might have been limited; and if the baht had depreciated along with the yen in 1996-97, then the decline in exports could have been mitigated. This kind of exchange rate flexibility can be achieved by a flexible exchange rate regime which keeps the real effective exchange rate relatively stable. An obvious insight here is that an emerging market economy, which exports 3 to the United States and Japan, is well advised to consider managed exchange rate regimes, in order to avoid excessive volatility of the real effective exchange rate. 2 The questions to be considered include how to determine a reference rate as an appropriate real effective exchange rate and how much fluctuation is excessive. The optimality of the exchange rate regime is defined as the one that minimizes the fluctuation of the trade balances, when the yen-dollar exchange rate fluctuates. Ito, Ogawa, and Sasaki (1998) proposed how to calculate the optimal weights when the emerging market economy exports to Japan and the United States only. The optimal weights were calibrated with some assumptions on the demand elasticities and export shares. In this paper, we extend the Ito, Ogawa, and Sasaki model to include a neighboring emerging market as well as Japan and the United States. A typical Asian economy exports about one-third to the United States and one-third to Japan, and the rest to countries in the Asian region (and EU). Therefore, to simplify, we consider the case that country A (B, respectively) exports to the U.S., Japan, and country B (A, respectively). Therefore, the real effective exchange rate calculation includes the currency of neighboring country. What makes difficult and interesting in this model is 4 that the optimal weights may depend on what the neighboring country is adopting as weights. In the extreme case, if country A is adopting the dollar peg, country B should adopt the dollar peg; and if country B is adopting the dollar peg, then country A should adopt the dollar peg. Namely, the dollar peg is a Nash equilibrium. However, if country A is using a currency basket which mirrors the export shares, adjusted for demand elasticities, then country B should adopt a (similar) currency basket; and if country B is using a currency basket, then country A should adopt a currency basket. This trade-weighted currency basket is also a Nash equilibrium. Although the paper is motivated by the recent Asian experiences, the application is not limited to Asia. Results obtained in this paper are relevant to any developing countries with a trading structure with export destinations including different currency areas. Which of the Nash equilibria is chosen depends on the inertia as well as rational calculation. If countries can coordinate, then they should choose the best among Nash equilibria. This process of choosing the optimal Nash equilibrium can be regarded as a regional currency arrangement. Coordination failure could occur if a country has some obstacles for coordination from 5 political or social obstacles against breaking inertia. What this paper shows is that coordinate managed float by the two countries would increase the stability in the trade balance fluctuations. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 explains the model. We assume that the Marshall-Lerner condition, which means that depreciation of the local currency will increase the net trade surpluses, is satisfied throughout the paper. Section 3 examines what the Marshall-Lerner condition implies in our oligopoly model with imported parts and It also examines in what situation the Marshall-Lerner condition is satisfied in the model. Section 4 defines and solves for an optimal currency regime. We introduce the exchange rate policy of the monetary authorities of the two countries in order to analyze interdependence and coordination failure between their exchange rate policies. 2. Model (1) Settings Our earlier work, Ito, Ogawa, and Sasaki (1998), considered the question of choosing optimal weights in the basket currency system for a country that exports goods to the United States and Japan. An Asian country was modeled 6 as a one-sector economy where a representative firm assembles parts imported from Japan and the United States into manufactured products. 3 The representative firm in one Asian country was assumed to compete with Japanese firms and/or U.S. firms in the Japanese and U.S. markets. We extend our earlier model to include another neighbor country in the model in order to analyze interactions of the exchange rate policies among Asian countries. We assume that a representative firm in country A imports parts from the United States and Japan and exports its products to markets in the United States, Japan, and country B as well as a domestic market.4 Also, a representative firm in country B imports parts from the United States and Japan and supplies its products to markets in the United States, Japan, and country A as well as a domestic market. We assume that prices of parts from the United States and Japan are given in terms of their production country’s currency. 5 Asian countries export their goods and services mainly to Japan, the United States, and neighboring Asian countries. For example, Thailand exports one-fourth to Japan, one-fifth to NIES (Korea, Singapore, Hong Kong, and Taiwan) and ASEAN-4 countries (Thailand, Philippines, Indonesia, and Malaysia), one-seventh to the United States. These three categories account for more than 7 60 percent. Similarly, Malaysia exports to 22 percent, 34 percent and 17 percent to Japan, to the United States, and to Asian countries, respectively. The sum of these three categories reaches 72 percent. The structure is similar in Indonesia and the Philippines. Table 1 shows the export shares by destination to Japan, the United States, Asian countries, and four European countries (Germany, France, UK, and Italy). Therefore, the assumptions of the model, Country A exports to Japan, the United States, and neighboring country B, are realistic. Each market in countries A and B is supposed to be a duopoly market where both country A and B firms compete with each other. Markets in the United States and Japan are under monopolistic competition. Country A and B firms compete with many domestic firms in each of the U.S. and Japanese markets. They supplies their products in the U.S. and Japanese monopolistically competitive markets given average prices of their domestic products made in the United States and Japan. We assume that prices of the products made in the U.S. and Japan are kept unchanged (exogenous to this model) for simplicity. Moreover, we assume that all firms in countries A and B have identical cost functions. Each firm maximizes its profits in terms of its own home currency. 8 Profits of each firm in countries A and B in terms of its own home currency A and B (πL (L $%) ) is calculated as LL<LLLLLLML π LLLL=+3G T ( 3 -L- I T + ( 3 86L86 J T +
Recommended publications
  • China's Currency Policy
    Updated May 24, 2019 China’s Currency Policy China’s policy of intervening in currency markets to control The yuan-dollar exchange rate has experienced volatility the value of its currency, the renminbi (RMB), against the over the past few years. On August 11, 2015, the Chinese U.S. dollar and other currencies has been of concern for central bank announced that the daily RMB central parity many in Congress over the past decade or so. Some rate would become more “market-oriented,” However, over Members charge that China “manipulates” its currency in the next three days, the RMB depreciated by 4.4% against order to make its exports significantly less expensive, and the dollar and it continued to decline against the dollar its imports more expensive, than would occur if the RMB throughout the rest of 2015 and into 2016. From August were a freely traded currency. Some argue that China’s 2015 to December 2016, the RMB fell by 8.8% against the “undervalued currency” has been a major contributor to the dollar. From January to December 2017, the RMB rose by large annual U.S. merchandise trade deficits with China 4.6% against the dollar. (which totaled $419 billion in 2018) and the decline in U.S. manufacturing jobs. Legislation aimed at addressing Since 2018, the RMB’s value against the dollar has “undervalued” or “misaligned” currencies has been generally trended downward. Many economists contend introduced in several congressional sessions. On May 23, that the RMB’s recent decline has largely been caused by 2019, the U.S.
    [Show full text]
  • The World Currency Basket (WCB) Stephen Jen & Fatih Yilmaz
    The World Currency Basket (WCB) Stephen Jen & Fatih Yilmaz November 30, 2012 Bottom line: The global economy and the financial markets have gone through dramatic changes in the last decade. Actions (e.g., globalization and the rise of cheap labour supply in EM) and reactions (e.g., low interest rate policies in the developed world in reaction to declining inflation rates in the 2000s) have culminated in the biggest global financial and economic crisis since the Great Depression. At the same time, longer-term structural changes (e.g., demographic shifts and changes in the geopolitical balance of hard power1) are taking place and will exert persistent pressures on financial prices, and especially currencies. Will the dollar remain the dominant global currency in the world? Will the Euro exist in 10 years’ time? Will Japan implode one day? Will China’s rise remain smooth? All of these are complex issues. In this note, we focus on one question: To preserve one’s wealth over time, what is the best long-term currency strategy? Keeping all the eggs in one basket, either in US dollars or in Euros, obviously does not make sense from a long-term perspective. Yet many funds are dollar-, euro-, or JPY-denominated and the portfolio managers only care about their returns in the denominated currency. Is this the right long-term strategy? If the answer is ‘no,’ what is the proper way to think about maintaining the long-term purchasing power of wealth? We introduce the concept of the World Currency Basket (WCB), whereby investors think not in terms of the dollar or the euro or the yen, but in WCB terms.
    [Show full text]
  • Sustaining the GCC Currency Pegs: the Need for Collaboration
    Policy Briefing February 2018 Sustaining the GCC Currency Pegs: The Need for Collaboration Luiz Pinto Sustaining the GCC Currency Pegs: The Need for Collaboration Luiz Pinto The Brookings Institution is a private non-profit organization. Its mission is to conduct high-quality, independent research and, based on that research, to provide innovative, practical recommendations for policymakers and the public. The conclusions and recommendations of any Brookings publication are solely those of its author(s), and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Institution, its management, or its other scholars. Brookings recognizes that the value it provides to any supporter is in its absolute commitment to quality, independence and impact. Activities supported by its donors reflect this commitment and the analysis and recommendations are not determined by any donation. Copyright © 2018 Brookings Institution BROOKINGS INSTITUTION 1775 Massachusetts Avenue, N.W. Washington, D.C. 20036 U.S.A. www.brookings.edu BROOKINGS DOHA CENTER Saha 43, Building 63, West Bay, Doha, Qatar www.brookings.edu/doha Sustaining the GCC Currency Pegs: The Need for Collaboration Luiz Pinto1 From June 2014 to January 2018, oil prices This policy briefing examines the fundamentals plummeted from $115 per barrel to $68 per of the GCC currency pegs and the capabilities barrel, a 41 percent decline. Prices reached of monetary authorities to sustain them over a low of $28 on January 19, 2016.2 As a time. It argues that, although fixed exchange result, the oil-exporting countries of the Gulf rate regimes are still optimal for all the GCC Cooperation Council (GCC) faced the longest states, the ability of policymakers to support period ever recorded of monthly consecutive the pegs varies markedly across the region.
    [Show full text]
  • The SDR—A Blueprint for Libra?
    Institute of Global Affairs The SDR —a blueprint for libra? Ousmène Jacques Mandeng Visiting Fellow, Institute of Global Affairs, London School of Economics and Political Science The SDR—a blueprint for libra? Ousmène Jacques Mandeng Visiting Fellow, Institute of Global Affairs, London School of Economics and Political Science First draft, 25 July 2019 Second draft, 27 August 2019 Facebook’s libra has reinvigorated the idea of a global currency and use of a currency basket for its valuation. The SDR shared similar ambitions and can serve as useful background to assess possible challenges and difficulties of designing an international currency. The SDR is not the outcome of a singular vision but rather the campaign of competing views among IMF member countries. It is about countries’ perspectives on the purposes of the SDR and its evolution from a basket to reflect inclusiveness and diversification reminiscent of the IMF membership to assuming properties to compete with the main reserve assets. Shifting country influences at the IMF may in the near future offer the possibility of a new direction for the SDR. The present paper provides a review, largely based on IMF Executive Board discussions, of the evolution of IMF views about objective and role of the SDR and traces the idea for the valuation basket of the SDR. Introduction Facebook’s libra coin has reignited interest in the idea of a supra-national currency and currency baskets.1 The idea is of course not new. The IMF Special Drawing Right (SDR) went furthest at international level.2 The rationale for an international currency is to minimise transaction costs in international exchanges and not depend on the monetary or exchange rate policy objectives of any single country.
    [Show full text]
  • Pegging to a Currency Basket
    Pegging to a currency basket The technical issues behind the choice, composition, and operation of a basket peg under a system of floating exchange rates Shinji Takagi JT ollowing the generalized floating of the these conditions, when a country decides not drawing right (SDR) and, later, the European world's major currencies in 1973, a number to float independently, it must also choose Currency Unit (ECU). of smaller countries began pegging the value the appropriate standard to which it wishes Although at least one country adopted an of their currencies to an average value, or to peg its currency. exchange rate system similar to a basket peg basket, of selected foreign currencies. At the When the world's major currencies began in the interwar years of floating exchange end of 1985, 43 member countries of the to float in early 1973, most small countries rates, the basket peg is a relatively new Fund maintained such basket peg arrange- initially continued to peg their currencies to mechanism that came into being in the wake ments. Taking into account countries that the single currency that they had previously of generalized floating after 1973. The exten- adopted and then abandoned a basket peg, used to intervene in the market to support sive use of the basket peg in recent years the total number of countries with such ar- the fixed value of their currencies (mainly, can be explained by the greater diversification rangements during 1973-85 was 63. the US dollar, French franc, and pound ster- in international trade that has increased the ling).
    [Show full text]
  • The Optimal Currency Basket Under Vertical Trade
    The Optimal Currency Basket under Vertical Trade Juanyi Xu ∗ Hong Kong University of Science and Technology, Kowloon, Hong Kong May 2011 Abstract This paper explores the theory of optimal currency basket in a small open economy general equilibrium model with sticky prices. In contrast to existing literature, we focus on an economy with vertical trade, where the currencies in the basket may play different roles in invoicing trade flow. In a simple two-currency basket, one currency is used to invoice imported intermediate goods and is called \import currency", while the other currency is used to invoice exported finished goods and is called \export currency". We find that the optimal weights of the import currency and the export currency depends critically on the structure of vertical trade. Moreover, if a country decides to choose a single-currency peg, the choice of pegging currency also depends on how other competing economies respond to external exchange rate fluctuations. JEL classification: F3, F4 Keywords: Vertical trade, Import currency, Export currency, Currency basket peg, Welfare ∗ Department of Economics, Hong Kong University of Science and Technology, Clear Water Bay, Kowloon, Hong Kong. Email: [email protected]. Tel: +852 23587604; fax: +852 23582084. 1 Introduction The purpose of this study was to re-examine the theory of the optimal currency basket for small open economies in a vertical trade context. The literature on optimal currency baskets proliferated in the early 1980s. For example, see Behandari (1985), Flanders and Helpman (1979), Flanders and Tishler (1981), and Turnovsky (1982). The optimality of a currency basket in those studies was defined mainly in terms of trade balance stabilization or real income stabilization.
    [Show full text]
  • Artificial Currency Units: the Formation of Functional
    ESSAYS IN INTERNATIONAL FINANCE No. 114, April 1976 ARTIFICIAL CURRENCY UNITS: THE FORMATION OF FUNCTIONAL. CURRENCY AREAS JOSEPH ASCHHEIM AND Y. S. PARK INTERNATIONAL FINANCE SECTION DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS PRINCETON UNIVERSITY Princeton, New Jersey This is the one hundred and fourteenth number,in the series ESSAYS IN INTERNATIONAL FINANCE, published from time to time by the International Finance Section of the Department of Economics of Princeton University. Joseph Aschheim is Professor of Economics at The George Washington University. He has served as economic consultant to many governmental and international organi- zations and was Director of Research and Economic Ad- viser to the Governor of the Central Bank of Kenya in 1971-72. In addition to various journal articles, he is the author of Techniques of Monetary Control (1961) and co- author of Macroeconomics: Income and Monetary Theory (/969). 1'. S. Park is Senior Economist in the Treasurer's Department of the World Bank and Professorial Lecturer in International Finance at Georgetown University. Among his many publications are two books, The Eurobond Market (1974) and Oil Money and the World Economy (forthcom- ing), and Essay No. 100 in this series, The Link between Special Drawing Rights and Development Finance. The present essay represents the opinions of the authors and does not necessarily reflect the official views of the World Bank or of any organization with which either author has been affiliated. The Section sponsors the essays in this series but takes no further responsibility for the opinions expressed in them. The writers are free to develop their topics as they wish.
    [Show full text]
  • The Currency-Plus-Commodity Basket: a Proposal for Exchange Rates in Oil-Exporting Countries to Accommodate Trade Shocks Automatically
    The Currency-Plus-Commodity Basket: A Proposal for Exchange Rates in Oil-Exporting Countries to Accommodate Trade Shocks Automatically Jeffrey A. Frankel CID Working Paper No. 333 December 2016. Revised March 2017 © Copyright 2017 Frankel, Jeffrey A.; and the President and Fellow of Harvard College Working Papers Center for International Development at Harvard University 1 1st draft, Dec. 31, 2016. Revised, March 19, 2017 The Currency-Plus-Commodity Basket: A Proposal for Exchange Rates in Oil-Exporting Countries to Accommodate Trade Shocks Automatically Jeffrey A. Frankel, James W. Harpel Professor of Capital Formation and Growth, Harvard Kennedy School, Harvard University This paper was written for Macroeconomic Institutions and Management in Resource-Rich Arab Economies (forthcoming, Oxford University Press). The author gratefully acknowledges support from the Economic Research Forum, Cairo, Egypt, and valuable research assistance from James Fallon. Abstract The paper proposes an exchange rate regime for oil-exporting countries. The goal is to achieve the best of both flexible and fixed exchange rates. The arrangement is designed to deliver monetary policy that counteracts rather than exacerbates the effects of swings in the oil market, while yet offering the day-to-day transparency and predictability of a currency peg. The proposal is to peg the national currency to a basket, but a basket that includes not only the currencies of major trading partners (in particular, the dollar and the euro), but also the export commodity (oil). The plan is called Currency-plus-Commodity Basket (CCB). The paper begins by fleshing out the need for an innovative arrangement that allows accommodation to trade shocks.
    [Show full text]
  • The G20's Role in the Reform of the International Monetary System
    Global Summitry Journal June 2013 The G20's Role in the Reform of the International Monetary System: Present Record, Potential, and Scenarios Yves Tiberghien Institute of Asian Research at the University of British Columbia, [email protected] Xu Hongcai China Center for International Economic Exchanges, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: Global Summitry Journal Part of the American Studies Commons, Australian Studies Commons, Banking and Finance Commons, Chinese Studies Commons, Economic History Commons, Economic Theory Commons, Ethics and Professional Responsibility Commons, Finance Commons, International Business Commons, International Economics Commons, International Law Commons, International Trade Commons, Political Economy Commons, Political History Commons, Politics Commons, and the Social History Commons Recommended Citation Tiberghien, Yves and Hongcai, Xu Available at: http://dx.doi.org/10.7871/2291-4110.1006 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Global Summitry Journal. It has been accepted for inclusion in Global Summitry Journal by an authorized administrator of Global Summitry Journal. For more information, please contact [email protected]. The G20's Role in the Reform of the International Monetary System: Present Record, Potential, and Scenarios Abstract With the acceleration of globalization, global markets have experienced an historic period of rapid expansion. The expansion of these markets has unleashed prosperity gains around the globe, most recently in large emerging market economies. However, it is now clear that this economic globalization has far outpaced the development of finance and monetary systems. The 2008 global financial crisis and the ensuing years of financial volatility have brought home the deficiencies in the architecture of governance undergirding global financial markets and the inherent instability of a global monetary system that relies on one currency.
    [Show full text]
  • Diversifying Reference Currency Basket and Decreasing Degree of Flexibility in Exchange Policy of China
    Japanese Journal of Monetary and Financial Economics Vol. 6, No. 1, pp. 1-18, 2018 Diversifying reference currency basket and decreasing degree of flexibility in exchange policy of China Pengfei Luo PhD Program, Graduate School of Commerce and Management, Hitotsubashi University E-mail: [email protected] ABSTRACT This study aims to determine the de facto foreign exchange rate regime of the renminbi (RMB) from 2005 to 2016. To address this problem, I employ the implicit currency basket model proposed by Frankel and Wei (1994) to estimate the components of RMB’s reference currency basket and the exchange rate flexibility model with a Markov-switching process to identify the possible regime switches. The main findings are as follows. First, the implicit currency basket model shows that the US dollar is still the anchor currency of RMB, with the highest weight in RMB’s reference basket, although it has decreased since August 2015. Second, the regime switches evaluated by examining exchange rate flexibility show that the regime differed over time. Indeed, the Chinese monetary authorities implemented heavy regulations on RMB flexibility under unstable external conditions such as the global financial crisis and period of RMB depreciation. Key words: foreign exchange rate regime, currency basket, renminbi, exchange rate flexibility JEL Classification: E58, F31 ©Japan Society of Monetary Economics 2018 1 Japanese Journal of Monetary and Financial Economics Vol. 6, No. 1, pp. 1-18, 2018 1. Introduction Clarifying the implemented renminbi (RMB hereafter) exchange rate regime is crucial because of the widespread “de facto vs. de jure” problem (Calvo & Reinhart, 2002; Frankel & Wei, 1994; Levy-Yeyati & Sturzenegger, 2005; Obstfeld & Rogoff, 1995), which is characterized by mone- tary authorities implementing different foreign exchange policies from what they officially claim to follow, particularly in emerging countries.
    [Show full text]
  • The Launch of the Euro
    The Launch of the Euro Carol C. Bertaut and Murat F. Iyigun, of the Board’s 1. Comparison of the euro area and the United States Division of International Finance, prepared this Percent except as noted article. Tim Troha provided research assistance. Item Euro area United States Population (1997, millions) ............... 282 268 The introduction on January 1, 1999, of the euro— Nominal GDP (1998, trillions of dollars) . 6.6 8.5 the single currency adopted by eleven of the fifteen Inflation (June 1999, twelve-month percent change)1 .................... .9 2.0 countries of the European Union—marked the begin- Unemployment rate (July 1999) 2 ......... 10.3 4.3 Exports as a share of GDP (1998) ......... 33.7 11.3 ning of the final stage of Economic and Monetary Excluding intra-euro-area trade ......... 13.5 . Imports as a share of GDP (1998) ......... 31.5 13.0 Union and the start of a new era in Europe. This Excluding intra-euro-area trade ......... 12.1 . historic achievement was the culmination of a lengthy 1. Euro-area harmonized inflation is calculated from a weighted average of process that began in March 1957, when six Euro- harmonized consumer price indexes for individual countries. The harmonized pean nations—Belgium, France, Germany, Italy, Lux- indexes are constructed by standardizing some aspects of statistical practice and eliminating categories from national consumer price indexes, leaving indexes embourg, and the Netherlands—signed the Treaty of with basically identical coverage across countries. Rome, thereby founding the European Economic 2. Euro-area unemployment estimates are based on the results of the Euro- 1 pean Community Labour Force Survey.
    [Show full text]
  • Currency Boards and the Euro – an “International Role of the Euro” Perspective By
    This version: 9 April 2003 PRELIMINARY: NOT FOR QUOTATION Currency boards and the euro – An “international role of the euro” perspective by Arnaud Mehl and Adalbert Winkler* (European Central Bank) Abstract: This paper analyses the four countries that have adopted a euro-based currency board from an “international role of the euro” perspective. It investigates whether they have economic characteristics different from (1) countries with other exchange rate regimes involving the euro as an anchor currency and (2) countries with a US dollar-based currency board. To this end, the paper reviews the macroeconomic record of Bosnia and Herzegovina, Bulgaria, Estonia and Lithuania as well as their degree of trade, economic and institutional integration with the euro area. In both respects, countries with a euro-based currency board have achieved impressive results which, however, seem not to be significantly different from those achieved by other countries whose exchange rate policy is oriented towards the euro. Conversely, countries with a euro-based currency board are more integrated with the euro area than countries operating a US dollar-based currency board are with their anchor country, the US. In line with standard optimal currency area theory, this might suggest that the costs of foregoing the use of an independent monetary policy and the ability to counter asymmetric shocks through nominal exchange rate changes are somewhat mitigated in the case of euro-based currency boards. However, the general caveat applies that integration can only be seen as a necessary, albeit not sufficient, condition for the sustainability of a currency board. Keywords: currency board, international currency JEL classification number: E52, F31, F36 * The authors are grateful to Stefan Wredenborg and André Geis for invaluable research assistance and to Peter Backé, Christofer Burger, Oscar Calvo-Gonzalez, Michael Chui, Francesco Mazzaferro, Julie McKay, Georges Pineau, Ralph Sueppel and Christian Thimann for fruitful comments.
    [Show full text]