Revisiting Modern Portfolio Theory and Portfolio Construction

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Revisiting Modern Portfolio Theory and Portfolio Construction FEATURE | REvisiting ModeRn PoRtfolio THEORy and PoRtfolio CONSTRUCTION Revisiting Modern Portfolio Theory and Portfolio Construction By Bryce James ears ago, I was speaking at an invest- Figure 1: Standard Deviation Probabilities from the Mean Return ment industry conference when a Probability of Return at 1, 2, and 3 Standard Deviations Yman in the front row yelled out, “Is this just another rubber chicken pre- 5% 1σ sentation on asset allocation?” I responded 4% with, “Fasten your seatbelt!” and I’ll say it 3% again here, because this is not your generic 2% 2σ 2σ article on post-modern portfolio theory. 1% I’m going to challenge you to question what Probability Density 3σ 3σ 0% you think you know about asset allocation 0% 1% 2% 3% 4% 5% 6% 7% 8% 9% and ask you to keep an open mind to what –9% –8% –7% –6% –5% –4% –3% –2% –1% 10% –10% is possible. DJIA Daily Return 99.7% Probability of Return 95.4% Probability of Return 68.3% Probability of Return Birth of a New Technology Source: Internal calculation using Excel. Data from Thomson-Reuters Computer technology was born in the 1950s with the first commercial com- return, and linear correlation (ρ) for which academics named the efficient market puter—the UNIVAC 1—delivered in 1951, correlation. hypothesis (EMH). The person credited followed by the first hard disk in 1955, 3. Optimize the portfolio using a covari- with this integration of the EMH was Fortran computer language in 1957, and ance matrix to seek the optimal effi- Eugene Fama at the University of Chicago. the modem in 1958. This era also gave cient frontier, i.e., asset mix. birth to modern portfolio theory (MPT). Standardized risk metrics in finance took You know about Harry Markowitz and In a classic MPT model, which is based hold in the 1950s when top economists, what he accomplished. All asset allocation upon probability theory, many assumptions such as Maurice Kendall (London School of work henceforth is a manifestation of his are made. The core assumption was Economics), Paul Samuelson (MIT), Harry concepts, founded on the principles of founded on the work of Louis Bachelier Markowitz (University of Chicago), and diversification. Implementing MPT is to (Mandelbrot and Hudson 2004, 9), who in William Sharpe (University of Washington apply a process called mean-variance 1900 introduced a probability-based model and University of California, Los Angeles), optimization (MVO). following the random walk theory, which is observed that over the long term, changes named after the unpredictable path of a in security prices plotted on a histogram An MVO model is a three-step process for drunken man (Fox 2009, 40–41; Sornette chart (frequency distribution) resembled portfolio construction: 2002, 38). Bachelier postulated that the the shape of the symmetrical bell curve market is like a 50-50 coin toss and that (Gaussian distribution) (see figure 1). 1. Collect a large amount of historical most market moves are measurable. This Combining all these pieces gave birth to price data on each security in your led him to conclude that markets are effi- the “science of investing.” fund universe (typically 30 years of cient. He calculated that 68.3 percent of daily prices and dividends). the changes up and down are small, falling As MPT took hold in the early 1960s, folks 2. Calculate the risk and return of each within one standard deviation (1σ) from such as Jack Treynor and William Sharpe security and the correlation between the mean return; that 95.4 percent of the introduced the capital asset pricing model pairs of securities. In traditional MPT, changes fall within 2σ; and that 99.7 per- (CAPM), improving upon Markowitz’s this is performed using standard devia- cent fall within 3σ. Markowitz (1952, 1959) capital allocation line. Risk finally could tion (σ) for risk, mean return (μ) for fit snugly into this random walk theory, be measured, as ratios, in various ways JANUARY / FEBRUARY 2017 5 © 2017 Investment Management Consultants Association Inc. Reprinted with permission. All rights reserved. FEATURE | REvisiting ModeRn PoRtfolio THEORy and PoRtfolio CONSTRUCTION through the metrics created by Sharpe, Data bonds instead of non-callable bonds. In Treynor, and Sortino. Today, these theo- In 2005, a law firm representing a group of addition, they were using bond proxies ries, known for their risk metrics, stand as investors hired me as an expert witness. The when no long bond was issued (which is the foundation of investing. But as tech- clients, all retired, claimed their broker was most of the time) in calculating the long- nology has significantly changed over the imprudent in managing their assets, creating term bond index. The net effect was an over- past half century, is it possible finance has losses exceeding 40 percent. The brokerage allocation to equities and an undervaluing been asleep? firm’s asset allocation software, based on an of bond returns. The net result, according to MVO model, recommended the usual 60/40 Ryan, created a massive performance dif- MPT assumes all information is priced into mix. However, the firm chose to use 18 years ference of 45.3 percent (from 1941–1991). the security and that yesterday’s price has of historical data rather than the 28 years Furthermore, investors would have experi- no influence on today’s price; each price recommended by the software vendor. As enced a standard deviation of 9.04 percent change is independent from the previous a result, the Monte Carlo simulations esti- using the Ibbotson Long Treasury portfolio move. The market, and each security, is mated a 16-percent return on equities into compared to 5.96 percent standard devia- fairly priced and moves are completely ran- the future instead of the 9-percent estimate tion with the actual Treasury composite; dom, with no regard for human emotion. (as of December 31, 1999) using the software a difference of 45.6 percent more risk Therefore, MPT assumes: (1) returns are vendor’s default 28-year time series. Yet this (Ryan 1992). normally distributed, (2) risk (σ) is accu- was not the main issue. The broker himself, rately captured using a normal distribution, using his own personal asset allocation soft- In a response to Ryan’s claims, Ibbotson (3) historical prices (mean-variance) can be ware, decided to load only three years’ worth colleagues Laurence B. Siegel and Scott L. used to predict future prices, (4) linear cor- of history (ending December 31, 1999) into Lummer (1993) wrote: relation accurately represents the relation- the asset allocation software. Recall that this ship between pairs of securities, (5) data was one of the best-performing periods for Today, however, only a very naïve investor acquired from data providers is accurate, the stock market, if not the best, in history. In would use our 20-year constant maturity and (6) markets are efficient, thus ignoring doing so, the broker’s MVO model forecasted series as a benchmark for evaluating a the behavioral science of fear and greed. a 27-percent return, which he presented to diversified bond portfolio. Mr. Ryan I’m here to tell you that all these assump- his retirement-age clients. As you know, the makes a valid point in suggesting an asset tions are false. Stock markets do not follow dotcom bubble soon burst and it took the allocator could be fooled by the Ibbotson random walks (see, e.g., Lo and MacKinlay S&P a decade to break even and 14 years data into underweighting in bonds. This 1988; Grossman and Stiglitz 1980; for the NASDAQ. The case was an easy win is a danger only if the asset allocator liter- Colander et al. 2009). for our side. Selection of time series is a form ally believes the disappointing historical of momentum. return on long-term bonds will be It’s so hard to let go of judgments and repeated. Again, this is a naïve view. The beliefs. It’s human nature to hang on to The time series is such a critical piece of expected return on a default-free bond is what’s familiar. In our business, it’s best to data, yet so overlooked. I argue that all its yield. This, not the historical return, stay safe by doing what everyone else does. models are momentum models, because should be used for asset allocation. We also stay safe by keeping things simple. any time you select a time series, you are If it’s not simple, clients’ eyes roll back in making an assumption and making a bet. Asset allocation models should be expec- their heads and you’ve lost the sale. This is To buy and hold is making a bet that past tational; they require expected returns as why even the newest financial technology— performance is indicative of future results, inputs. For bonds, the expected return is robo-advisors—rely upon the MPT/MVO contrary to our marketing disclaimers. observable in the market as a yield and math from 1952; it’s fast and easy. The first does not have to be extracted from his- person to expose the naked truth about the Back in the days of the UNIVAC 1, the tory. To use a historical average as the mathematics was Benoit Mandelbrot term GIGO (garbage in, garbage out) was expected return for bonds, as Mr. Ryan (1964). He criticized the use of normal dis- born. Financial companies have been built has done, is conceptually improper and tributions and warned that markets are around delivering quality data. I’m here to leads to poorly constructed portfolios. influenced by human behavior.
Recommended publications
  • Capturing Tail Risk in a Risk Budgeting Model
    DEGREE PROJECT IN MATHEMATICS, SECOND CYCLE, 30 CREDITS STOCKHOLM, SWEDEN 2020 Capturing Tail Risk in a Risk Budgeting Model FILIP LUNDIN MARKUS WAHLGREN KTH ROYAL INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY SCHOOL OF ENGINEERING SCIENCES Capturing Tail Risk in a Risk Budgeting Model FILIP LUNDIN MARKUS WAHLGREN Degree Projects in Financial Mathematics (30 ECTS credits) Master's Programme in Industrial Engineering and Management KTH Royal Institute of Technology year 2020 Supervisor at Nordnet AB: Gustaf Haag Supervisor at KTH: Anja Janssen Examiner at KTH: Anja Janssen TRITA-SCI-GRU 2020:050 MAT-E 2020:016 Royal Institute of Technology School of Engineering Sciences KTH SCI SE-100 44 Stockholm, Sweden URL: www.kth.se/sci Abstract Risk budgeting, in contrast to conventional portfolio management strategies, is all about distributing the risk between holdings in a portfolio. The risk in risk budgeting is traditionally measured in terms of volatility and a Gaussian distribution is commonly utilized for modeling return data. In this thesis, these conventions are challenged by introducing different risk measures, focusing on tail risk, and other probability distributions for modeling returns. Two models for forming risk budgeting portfolios that acknowledge tail risk were chosen. Both these models were based on CVaR as a risk measure, in line with what previous researchers have used. The first model modeled re- turns with their empirical distribution and the second with a Gaussian mixture model. The performance of these models was thereafter evaluated. Here, a diverse set of asset classes, several risk budgets, and risk targets were used to form portfolios. Based on the performance, measured in risk-adjusted returns, it was clear that the models that took tail risk into account in general had su- perior performance in relation to the standard model.
    [Show full text]
  • Optimal Life Extension Management of Offshore Wind Farms Based on the Modern Portfolio Theory
    Article Optimal Life Extension Management of Offshore Wind Farms Based on the Modern Portfolio Theory Baran Yeter and Yordan Garbatov * Centre for Marine Technology and Ocean Engineering (CENTEC), Instituto Superior Técnico, University of Lisbon, 1049-001 Lisbon, Portugal; [email protected] * Correspondence: [email protected] Abstract: The present study aims to develop a risk-based approach to finding optimal solutions for life extension management for offshore wind farms based on Markowitz’s modern portfolio theory, adapted from finance. The developed risk-based approach assumes that the offshore wind turbines (OWT) can be considered as cash-producing tangible assets providing a positive return from the initial investment (capital) with a given risk attaining the targeted (expected) return. In this regard, the present study performs a techno-economic life extension analysis within the scope of the multi-objective optimisation problem. The first objective is to maximise the return from the overall wind assets and the second objective is to minimise the risk associated with obtaining the return. In formulating the multi-dimensional optimisation problem, the life extension assessment considers the results of a detailed structural integrity analysis, a free-cash-flow analysis, the probability of project failure, and local and global economic constraints. Further, the risk is identified as the variance from the expected mean of return on investment. The risk–return diagram is utilised to classify the OWTs of different classes using an unsupervised machine learning algorithm. The optimal portfolios for the various required rates of return are recommended for different stages of life extension. Citation: Yeter, B.; Garbatov, Y.
    [Show full text]
  • An Overview of the Empirical Asset Pricing Approach By
    AN OVERVIEW OF THE EMPIRICAL ASSET PRICING APPROACH BY Dr. GBAGU EJIROGHENE EMMANUEL TABLE OF CONTENT Introduction 1 Historical Background of Asset Pricing Theory 2-3 Model and Theory of Asset Pricing 4 Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM): 4 Capital Asset Pricing Model Formula 4 Example of Capital Asset Pricing Model Application 5 Capital Asset Pricing Model Assumptions 6 Advantages associated with the use of the Capital Asset Pricing Model 7 Hitches of Capital Pricing Model (CAPM) 8 The Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT): 9 The Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT) Formula 10 Example of the Arbitrage Pricing Theory Application 10 Assumptions of the Arbitrage Pricing Theory 11 Advantages associated with the use of the Arbitrage Pricing Theory 12 Hitches associated with the use of the Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT) 13 Actualization 14 Conclusion 15 Reference 16 INTRODUCTION This paper takes a critical examination of what Asset Pricing is all about. It critically takes an overview of its historical background, the model and Theory-Capital Asset Pricing Model and Arbitrary Pricing Theory as well as those who introduced/propounded them. This paper critically examines how securities are priced, how their returns are calculated and the various approaches in calculating their returns. In this Paper, two approaches of asset Pricing namely Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) as well as the Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT) are examined looking at their assumptions, advantages, hitches as well as their practical computation using their formulae in their examination as well as their computation. This paper goes a step further to look at the importance Asset Pricing to Accountants, Financial Managers and other (the individual investor).
    [Show full text]
  • Tail Risk Premia and Return Predictability∗
    Tail Risk Premia and Return Predictability∗ Tim Bollerslev,y Viktor Todorov,z and Lai Xu x First Version: May 9, 2014 This Version: February 18, 2015 Abstract The variance risk premium, defined as the difference between the actual and risk- neutral expectations of the forward aggregate market variation, helps predict future market returns. Relying on new essentially model-free estimation procedure, we show that much of this predictability may be attributed to time variation in the part of the variance risk premium associated with the special compensation demanded by investors for bearing jump tail risk, consistent with idea that market fears play an important role in understanding the return predictability. Keywords: Variance risk premium; time-varying jump tails; market sentiment and fears; return predictability. JEL classification: C13, C14, G10, G12. ∗The research was supported by a grant from the NSF to the NBER, and CREATES funded by the Danish National Research Foundation (Bollerslev). We are grateful to an anonymous referee for her/his very useful comments. We would also like to thank Caio Almeida, Reinhard Ellwanger and seminar participants at NYU Stern, the 2013 SETA Meetings in Seoul, South Korea, the 2013 Workshop on Financial Econometrics in Natal, Brazil, and the 2014 SCOR/IDEI conference on Extreme Events and Uncertainty in Insurance and Finance in Paris, France for their helpful comments and suggestions. yDepartment of Economics, Duke University, Durham, NC 27708, and NBER and CREATES; e-mail: [email protected]. zDepartment of Finance, Kellogg School of Management, Northwestern University, Evanston, IL 60208; e-mail: [email protected]. xDepartment of Finance, Whitman School of Management, Syracuse University, Syracuse, NY 13244- 2450; e-mail: [email protected].
    [Show full text]
  • Post-Modern Portfolio Theory Supports Diversification in an Investment Portfolio to Measure Investment's Performance
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Rasiah, Devinaga Article Post-modern portfolio theory supports diversification in an investment portfolio to measure investment's performance Journal of Finance and Investment Analysis Provided in Cooperation with: Scienpress Ltd, London Suggested Citation: Rasiah, Devinaga (2012) : Post-modern portfolio theory supports diversification in an investment portfolio to measure investment's performance, Journal of Finance and Investment Analysis, ISSN 2241-0996, International Scientific Press, Vol. 1, Iss. 1, pp. 69-91 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/58003 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend
    [Show full text]
  • Portfolio Management Under Transaction Costs
    Portfolio management under transaction costs: Model development and Swedish evidence Umeå School of Business Umeå University SE-901 87 Umeå Sweden Studies in Business Administration, Series B, No. 56. ISSN 0346-8291 ISBN 91-7305-986-2 Print & Media, Umeå University © 2005 Rickard Olsson All rights reserved. Except for the quotation of short passages for the purposes of criticism and review, no part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise, without the prior consent of the author. Portfolio management under transaction costs: Model development and Swedish evidence Rickard Olsson Master of Science Umeå Studies in Business Administration No. 56 Umeå School of Business Umeå University Abstract Portfolio performance evaluations indicate that managed stock portfolios on average underperform relevant benchmarks. Transaction costs arise inevitably when stocks are bought and sold, but the majority of the research on portfolio management does not consider such costs, let alone transaction costs including price impact costs. The conjecture of the thesis is that transaction cost control improves portfolio performance. The research questions addressed are: Do transaction costs matter in portfolio management? and Could transaction cost control improve portfolio performance? The questions are studied within the context of mean-variance (MV) and index fund management. The treatment of transaction costs includes price impact costs and is throughout based on the premises that the trading is uninformed, immediate, and conducted in an open electronic limit order book system. These premises characterize a considerable amount of all trading in stocks.
    [Show full text]
  • Comparative Analyses of Expected Shortfall and Value-At-Risk Under Market Stress1
    Comparative analyses of expected shortfall and value-at-risk under market stress1 Yasuhiro Yamai and Toshinao Yoshiba, Bank of Japan Abstract In this paper, we compare value-at-risk (VaR) and expected shortfall under market stress. Assuming that the multivariate extreme value distribution represents asset returns under market stress, we simulate asset returns with this distribution. With these simulated asset returns, we examine whether market stress affects the properties of VaR and expected shortfall. Our findings are as follows. First, VaR and expected shortfall may underestimate the risk of securities with fat-tailed properties and a high potential for large losses. Second, VaR and expected shortfall may both disregard the tail dependence of asset returns. Third, expected shortfall has less of a problem in disregarding the fat tails and the tail dependence than VaR does. 1. Introduction It is a well known fact that value-at-risk2 (VaR) models do not work under market stress. VaR models are usually based on normal asset returns and do not work under extreme price fluctuations. The case in point is the financial market crisis of autumn 1998. Concerning this crisis, CGFS (1999) notes that “a large majority of interviewees admitted that last autumn’s events were in the “tails” of distributions and that VaR models were useless for measuring and monitoring market risk”. Our question is this: Is this a problem of the estimation methods, or of VaR as a risk measure? The estimation methods used for standard VaR models have problems for measuring extreme price movements. They assume that the asset returns follow a normal distribution.
    [Show full text]
  • MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY: FOUNDATIONS, ANALYSIS, and NEW DEVELOPMENTS Table of Contents
    MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY: FOUNDATIONS, ANALYSIS, AND NEW DEVELOPMENTS Table of Contents Preface Chapter 1 Introduction (This chapter contains three Figures) 1.1 The Portfolio Management Process 1.2 The Security Analyst's Job 1.3 Portfolio Analysis 1.3A Basic Assumptions 1.3B Reconsidering The Assumptions 1.4 Portfolio Selection 1.5 Mathematics Segregated to Appendices 1.6 Topics To Be Discussed Appendix - Various Rates of Return A1.1 The Holding Period Return A1.2 After-Tax Returns A1.3 Continuously Compounded Return PART 1: PROBABILITY FOUNDATIONS Chapter 2 Assessing Risk (This chapter contains six Numerical Examples) 2.1 Mathematical Expectation 2.2 What is Risk? 2.3 Expected Return 2.4 Risk of a Security 2.5 Covariance of Returns 2.6 Correlation of Returns 2.7 Using Historical Returns 2.8 Data Input Requirements 2.9 Portfolio Weights 2.10 A Portfolio’s Expected Return 2.11 Portfolio Risk 2.12 Summary of Conventions and Formulas MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY - Table of Contents – Page 1 Chapter 3 Risk and Diversification: An Overview (This chapter contains ten Figures and three Tables of real numbers) 3.1 Reconsidering Risk 3.1A Symmetric Probability Distributions 3.1B Fundamental Security Analysis 3.2 Utility Theory 3.2A Numerical Example 3.2B Indifference Curves 3.3 Risk-Return Space 3.4 Diversification 3.4A Diversification Illustrated 3.4B Risky A + Risky B = Riskless Portfolio 3.4C Graphical Analysis 3.5 Conclusions PART 2: UTILITY FOUNDATIONS Chapter 4 Single-Period Utility Analysis (This chapter contains sixteen Figures, four Tables
    [Show full text]
  • 11Portfolio Concepts
    CHAPTER 11 PORTFOLIO CONCEPTS LEARNING OUTCOMES After completing this chapter, you will be able to do the following: Mean–Variance Analysis I Define mean–variance analysis and list its assumptions. I Explain the concept of an efficient portfolio. I Calculate the expected return and variance or standard deviation of return for a portfolio of two or three assets, given the assets’ expected returns, variances (or standard deviations), and correlation(s) or covariance(s). I Define the minimum-variance frontier, the global minimum-variance portfolio, and the efficient frontier. I Explain the usefulness of the efficient frontier for portfolio management. I Describe how the correlation between two assets affects the diversification benefits achieved when creating a portfolio of the two assets. I Describe how to solve for the minimum-variance frontier for a set of assets, given expected returns, covariances, and variances with and without a constraint against short sales. I Calculate the variance of an equally weighted portfolio of n stocks, given the average variance of returns and the average covariance between returns. I Describe the capital allocation line (CAL), explain its slope coefficient, and calculate the value of one of the variables in the capital allocation line given the values of the remaining variables. I Describe the capital market line (CML), explain the relationship between the CAL and the CML, and interpret implications of the CML for portfolio choice. I Describe the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) including its underlying assumptions, resulting conclusions, security market line, beta, and market risk premium. I Explain the choice between two portfolios given their mean returns and standard deviations, with and without borrowing and lending at the risk-free rate.
    [Show full text]
  • CAPITAL ALLOCATION March 22 2013
    THEORY OF CAPITAL ALLOCATION Isil Erel, Stewart C. Myers and James A. Read, Jr.* March 22, 2013 Abstract We demonstrate that firms should allocate capital to lines of business based on marginal default values. The marginal default value for a line of business is the derivative of the value of the firm’s option to default with respect to the scale of the line. Marginal default values give a unique allocation of capital that adds up exactly, regardless of the joint probability distribution of line-by-line returns. Capital allocations follow from the conditions for the firm’s optimal portfolio of businesses. The allocations are systematically different from allocations based on VaR or contribution VaR. We set out practical applications, including implications for regulatory capital standards. *Ohio State University, MIT Sloan School of Management, and The Brattle Group, Inc. We received helpful comments on earlier versions from Richard Derrig, Ken Froot, Hamid Mehran, Rene Stulz, and seminar participants at the University of Michigan, the NBER, the New York Federal Reserve Bank, Ohio State University and University College Dublin. CAPITAL ALLOCATION 1. Introduction This paper presents a general procedure for allocating capital. We focus on financial firms, but the procedure also works for non-financial firms that operate in a mix of safe and risky businesses. The efficient capital allocation for a line of business depends on its marginal default value, which is the derivative of the value of the firm’s option to default (its default put) with respect to a change in the scale of the business. Marginal default values are unique and add up exactly.
    [Show full text]
  • Testing the Validity of the Capital Asset Pricing Model in Turkey”
    T.C. İstanbul Üniversitesi Sosyal Bilimler Enstitüsü İngilizce İktisat Anabilim Dalı Yüksek Lisans Tezi Testing The Validity of The Capital Asset Pricing Model In Turkey Veysel Eraslan 2504080001 Tez Danışmanı Prof. Dr. Nihal Tuncer İstanbul 2011 “Testing The Validity of The Capital Asset Pricing Model In Turkey” Veysel ERASLAN ÖZ Finansal Varlıkları Fiyatlandırma Modeli yıllardan beri akademisyenlerin üzerinde çalıştığı en popüler konulardan biri olmuştur. Finansal Varlıkları Fiyatlandırma Modeli’nin farklı ekonomilerdeki geçerliliğini test etmek amacıyla birçok çalışma yapılmıştır. Bu çalışmalarda modeli destekleyen veya desteklemeyen farklı sonuçlar elde edilmiştir. Bu çalışmada, Finansal Varlıkları Fiyatlandırma Modeli’nin Sharpe- Lintner-Black versiyonu, Ocak 2006-Aralık 2010 zaman dilimi içerisinde İstanbul Menkul Kıymetler Borsası aylık kapanış verileri kullanılarak test edilmiştir. Çalışmanın amacı modelde risk ölçüsü olarak ifade edilen portföy betası ile portföy getirisi arasındaki ilişkinin belirtilen zaman dilimi içerisinde İstanbul Menkul Kıymetler Borsası’nda test edilmesidir. Çalışmada iki farklı yöntem kullanılmıştır. Bunlardan birincisi koşulsuz (geleneksel) analiz yöntemidir. Bu yöntemin temelini Fama ve French’in (1992) çalışması oluşturmaktadır. İkinci yöntem olarak ise Pettengill v.d. nin (1995) koşullu analiz tekniği kullanılmıştır. Yapılan analizler sonucunda Finansal Varlıkları Fiyatlandırma Modeli’nin İstanbul Menkul Kıymetler Borsası’nda geçerli olduğu bulgusuna ulaşılmış olup betanın bir risk ölçüsü olarak kullanılabilirliği desteklenmiştir. ABSTRACT The Capital Asset Pricing Model has been the most popular model among the academicians for many years. Lots of studies have been done in order to test the validity of the Capital Asset Pricing Model in different economies. Various results were obtained at the end of these studies. Some of these results were supportive while some of them were not.
    [Show full text]
  • Modeling Financial Sector Joint Tail Risk in the Euro Area
    Modeling financial sector joint tail risk in the euro area∗ Andr´eLucas,(a) Bernd Schwaab,(b) Xin Zhang(c) (a) VU University Amsterdam and Tinbergen Institute (b) European Central Bank, Financial Research Division (c) Sveriges Riksbank, Research Division First version: May 2013 This version: October 2014 ∗Author information: Andr´eLucas, VU University Amsterdam, De Boelelaan 1105, 1081 HV Amsterdam, The Netherlands, Email: [email protected]. Bernd Schwaab, European Central Bank, Kaiserstrasse 29, 60311 Frankfurt, Germany, Email: [email protected]. Xin Zhang, Research Division, Sveriges Riksbank, SE 103 37 Stockholm, Sweden, Email: [email protected]. We thank conference participants at the Banque de France & SoFiE conference on \Systemic risk and financial regulation", the Cleveland Fed & Office for Financial Research conference on \Financial stability analysis", the European Central Bank, the FEBS 2013 conference on \Financial regulation and systemic risk", LMU Munich, the 2014 SoFiE conference in Cambridge, the 2014 workshop on \The mathematics and economics of systemic risk" at UBC Vancouver, and the Tinbergen Institute Amsterdam. Andr´eLucas thanks the Dutch Science Foundation (NWO, grant VICI453-09-005) and the European Union Seventh Framework Programme (FP7-SSH/2007- 2013, grant agreement 320270 - SYRTO) for financial support. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and they do not necessarily reflect the views or policies of the European Central Bank or the Sveriges Riksbank. Modeling financial sector joint tail risk in the euro area Abstract We develop a novel high-dimensional non-Gaussian modeling framework to infer con- ditional and joint risk measures for many financial sector firms.
    [Show full text]