Externalities a Downriver Externality the Social Optimum First Order

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Externalities a Downriver Externality the Social Optimum First Order Externalities A Downriver Externality • An externality occurs whenever the activities of • Consider the firms on the river example. one economic agent affect the activities of another Both firms use only labor as an input. agent in ways that are not taken into account by the operation of the market. – The upriver firm produces Y with a production •Examples: function of Y = g(LY). – One firm produces down river from another firm. The – The downriver firm produces X. Its production first firm pollutes the river and prevents the second is affected by the upriver firm’s production: from producing. X = f(L ; Y), where: – Doctor works next door to a noisy factory. X ∂X – I care what my daughter eats. < 0 ∂Y First Order Condition at the The Social Optimum Social Optimum • Suppose there is a fixed amount of labor L in the • The first order conditions are: economy. æ ö ∂V ç ∂X ∂X ∂Y ÷ • Suppose prices for X and Y are Px and Py. = P − − λ = 0 ∂L x ç ∂L ∂Y ∂L ÷ æ ∂ ∂ ∂ ö ∂ x è x y ø ç X X Y ÷ Y • The total value of output is PxX + PyY. P − = P x ç ∂ ∂ ∂ ÷ y ∂ ∂V ∂Y è Lx Y Ly ø Ly • At the social optimum, labor is allocated to the two = P − λ = 0 ∂ y ∂ firms such that the total value of output in the Ly Ly economy is maximized: This “extra” term max ()+ () ∂V Px X Lx ;Y PyY Ly = L − L − L = 0 arises because of the Lx , Ly ∂λ x y + = externality. s.t. Lx Ly L The Market Will Not Lead to the Can the Market be Fixed? Social Optimum • In a competitive market, price taking maximize profits: • Pigouvian taxes π π – x = PxX - wLx and y =PyY – wLy – Impose a tax (t) on the production of Y such • The first order conditions in a competitive market are: that it chooses to cut back production to the ∂π ∂ ∂Y ∂X socially optimal level. x X = = P − w = 0 Py Px ∂ x ∂ ∂L ∂L π Lx Lx y x – Y’s profits after the tax are y =(Py-t)Y – wLy ∂π ∂π y ∂Y This is not the same f.o.c. as – Y’s new f.o.c. is: ∂Y = P − w = 0 y = ()P − t − w = 0 ∂ y ∂ the social optimum. Firm Y ∂ y ∂ Ly Ly L L ignores the externality it y y ∂ = − X imposesonXandproduces – For the socially optimal amount: t Px ∂Y too much. 1 Can the Market be Fixed? (II) Does the Market Need Fixing? • The firms can merge. • Suppose that firm X owned the river. Then it – If X and Y merge, the new super firm will maximize could charge the firm Y for the externality it joint profits: π = P Y + P X – w(L + L ) y x x y imposes and the socially efficient outcome would – The first order conditions for the super firm are: result. æ ö æ ∂ ∂ ∂ ö ∂ ∂π ç ∂X ∂X ∂Y ÷ ç X − X Y ÷ = Y • Suppose that firm Y owned the river. The socially = P − − w = 0 Px ç ÷ Py ∂ x ç ∂ ∂ ∂ ÷ ∂L ∂Y ∂L ∂L Lx è Lx Y Ly ø è x y ø y efficient would still occur! ∂π ∂Y This is exactly the f.o.c. for • Why? If it was socially efficient for X to have Y = P − w = 0 ∂L y ∂L the social optimum. By reduce its output, it would pay Y not to produce. y y merging, the externality has been “internalized” The Beneficent Effects of The Coase Theorem Assigning Property Rights • Coase Theorem: In the absence of transaction • The assignment and enforcement of a property costs, the socially efficient outcome will occur, right moves an externality (utility or productivity regardless of the assignment of property rights. interactions not dealt with by the market) into the • Externalities are not caused by one party—they market. are caused by the simultaneous actions of two or • It is the lack of (or poor) assignment of property more parties. rights that causes the externality and leads – For the downriver externality, you need two things: a ultimately to inefficient market outcomes. firm Y that pollutes a river and a firm X that locates – Markets are necessarily incomplete if property rights downriver. are not assigned. Coase Theorem Example M. Welby and W. Wonka • A doctor (M. Welby, MD) operates next door to a • Suppose that Dr. Welby has a right to peace and noisy candy manufacturer (W. Wonka). quiet. – The value of the doctor’s output is $100. – The efficient outcome happens and Mr. Wonka closes shop. (sorry Charlie!). – The value of the candy firm’s output is $50. • Suppose instead that Mr. Wonka convinces the • Dr. Welby cannot operate at all if the candy city council to decree that he has a right to make machines are running. noise. • The socially efficient outcome is that Mr. Wonka – Dr. Welby will pay Mr. Wonka at least $50 to shut shut down. down. – The efficient outcome still happens—no candy is produced. 2 Transaction Costs Why Do Firms Exist? • Recall that one solution the the externality • The conclusion of the Coase Theorem problem is merger. depends crucially on low cost bargaining. • By merging, the combined Welby-Wonka – Suppose Dr. Welby had to pay a $50 for a operation’s optimal private choices would also be lawyer to help negotiate with the intractable socially optimal. Mr. Wonka. • The advantage of merging to form a firm is reduced transactions costs of bargaining. – In that case, the assignment of property rights – There is less need for Mr. Welby to hire a lawyer if would determine whether the socially optimal Wonka and Welby work for the same company. outcome happened. • In a sense, firms exist to “internalize” high transactions cost interactions. Public Goods Examples of Public Goods • Public goods are goods for which it is inherently Exclusive Nonexclusive difficult to assign property rights. Candy, BMW’s, Fishing ponds, – The classic example is national defense. Rival Houses Public parks • The defining characteristics of public goods are nonexclusivity and nonrivalry. Scrambled satellite National defense, – Nonexclusivity: It is very costly or impossible to Non- dish signals, Justice, Internet exclude those who have not paid from enjoying the good. Rival Bridges broadcasts, – Nonrivalry: The consumption of additional units Lighthouses involves zero social marginal costs of production. Question to ponder: Is education a public good? Is it exclusive? Is it rival? Market Provision of Public Goods Market Provision of Public Goods (II) • In private goods markets, we have seen that an • The social MRS is the total amount everyone efficient outcome requires that the PPF must be would give up of G to get an extra unit of P. tangent to the “society’s” utility curve (“social” – The social MRS is the sum of the individual MRS: MRS = RPT). n æ dG öi n SMRS (P for G) = åç− ÷ = å MRS i • Suppose there are two goods in the economy—a i=1 è dP ø i=1 private good (G) and a public good (P). • The social optimum (Pareto efficiency) requires • The marginal rate of substitution for any that the SMRS be equal to the rate of product individual i is: æ dG öi MU i transformation (RPT). i = ç− ÷ = P MRS (P for G) i è dP ø MUG 3 Market Provision of Public Goods (III) Government Provision of Public Goods • Public goods are often (though not always) • If a market provided P, however, each person provided by the government. would pick P and G to equate their own MRS to – A famous counterexample is lighthouses in Britain. the RPT of P for G. – Another is the 91 Freeway MU i RPT (P for G) = MRS i (P for G) = P < SMRS • In a sense, the government “internalizes” the MU i G externality by forcing everyone to contribute to • The amount of public good purchased would be funding the public good. less than optimal. • Whether or not a good is public often depends on • Each individual in the market ignores the positive the existence of exclusion technologies. externality caused by the purchase of more of the – e.g. without the development of the transponder box, the public good (“free rider” problem). private road provision is cumbersome (toll booths). Lindahl Taxes for Public Goods Lindahl Taxes—An Example • How much should the government tax each person to fund the public good? • Two people in an economy. Two goods: • In a Lindahl pricing equilibrium, the government – A private good (G)—price = pg imposes taxes on each individual in proportion to – A public good (P)—price = pp the benefit they derive from the public good. • The government charges taxes: – This information is hard to collect. – Everyone has an incentive to underreport how much –Pg * a1 to the first person, say Welby benefit they derive from the public good. –Pg * a2 to the second person, say Wonka • If willingness to pay information can be collected, –Wherea + a =1 the sum of all taxes collected exactly equals the 1 2 optimal amount of spending on the public good. Choosing The Right Taxes Lindahl Taxes and Private Choices Wonka’s demand for P Wonka • Welby chooses P and G such that his MRS equals the price 1 ratio he faces: a P 1 p = MRSWelby (P for G) Pg • Wonka chooses P and G such that his MRS equals the a1 a2 price ratio he faces: a P 2 p = MRSWonka (P for G) Pg • Producers maximize profits by setting RPT equal to the price ratio: 1 P Welby p = Welby’s demand for P RPT (P for G) Pg 4 Lindahl Taxes and the Social Optimum But Will the Government Get it Right? • At the Lindahl tax equilibrium, the socially • With Pigouvian taxes and the assignment of property optimal levels of the public and private goods will rights, the government has tools to internalize externalities be produced.
Recommended publications
  • Lindahl Tax, Income Tax, Commodity Tax, and Poll Tax, a Simulation
    20th International Congress on Modelling and Simulation, Adelaide, Australia, 1–6 December 2013 www.mssanz.org.au/modsim2013 Public Good Provision: Lindahl Tax, Income Tax, Commodity Tax, and Poll Tax, A Simulation T. Fukiharu School of Social Informatics, Aoyama Gakuin University Email: [email protected] Abstract: There are two traditions in the argument on taxation. On the one hand, the argument on taxation is constructed in such a way that which taxation is desirable in order to impose a tax, income tax, commodity tax or poll tax, without paying any attention on why the tax is necessary. In the partial equilibrium framework, the lump-sum tax, such as poll tax, is regarded as the best. On the other hand, it is also a tradition to assert that government imposes a tax in order to provide public goods. This paper integrates the above two traditions by constructing a primitive general equilibrium (GE) model which incorporates a public good, asking which taxation is desirable in order to impose tax, income tax, commodity tax, or poll tax to optimally provide the public good. Formally, in Part I, we start with utilizing the Lindahl mechanism to compute a Pareto-optimal public good level under a specification of the parameters on production and utility functions. The burden-sharing in this Lindahl mechanism may be regarded as a tax on the society members, while utilizing pseudo-market mechanism. We call it Lindahl tax. Next, we compute the rate of income tax in order to sustain the optimal public good level, and compare the Lindahl tax and income tax.
    [Show full text]
  • The Netherls
    Endogenous growth with public factors and heterogeneous human capital producers Thomas Ziesemer 93-022 .. ~ MERIT UNIVRSITY OF LIMURG P.O. BOX 616 6200 DM MASTRCHT THE NETHERLS MERIT, P.O. Box 616, 620 MD Maatricht (Netherlands) - telephone (31)43-83875- fax: (31)43-216518 ENDOGENOUS GROWTH WITH PUBLIC FACTORS AND HETEROGENEOUS * HUMAN CAPITAL PRODUCERS Thomas Ziesemer, University of Limburg, Faculty of Economics and Business Administration and Maatricht Economic Research Institute on Innovation and Technology (MERIT), P.O.Box 616, 6200 MD Maatricht, The Netherlands. Teleph: 31-43-883872, Telefax:31-43-216518, 'E-mail: T.Ziesemer~Algec.RuLimburg.NL In a growth model with no, one or multiple steady state(s) the following results are obtained for the stable steady states: If government revenues from a flat-rate income tax are spent on public factors and public factors are used for human capital production and human capital is used for the production of technical progress, then a higher rate of taxation will lead to a higher rate of technical progress. If human capital producing households have different abilities they wil have different desired (Lindahl) tax rates and a golden rule is no longer an acceptable welfare function. Therefore tax policy determines the rate of technical progress without a generally accepted welfare function. When the rate of time preference is larger than the rate of technical progress people with greater abilities want higher levels of public factors and taxes if indirect marginal utilty is inelastic with respect to net income. The outcome of this political decision wil determine the rate of technical progress.
    [Show full text]
  • An Optimal Benefit-Based Corporate Income
    An optimal benefit-based corporate income tax Simon Naitram∗ June 2020 Abstract In this paper I explore the features of a benefit-based corporate income tax. Benefit-based taxation defines a firm’s fair share of tax as the returns to the public input. When the government is constrained to fund the public input through the use of a distortionary tax on the firm’s profit, the optimal benefit-based corporate income tax rate is a function of three estimable elasticities: the direct public input elasticity of profit, the indirect public input elasticity of profit, and the (net of) tax elasticity of profit. Using public capital as a measure of the public input, I calculate optimal benefit-based tax rates. Under plausible parameters, these optimal tax rates are quantitatively reasonable and are progressive. I show that benefit-based taxation delivers inter-nation equity. JEL: H21; H25; H32; H41 Keywords: benefit-based taxation; optimal corporate tax; public input 1 Introduction There is no consensus on the purpose of the corporate income tax. This lack of consensus on the purpose of the tax makes it almost impossible to agree on the design of the corporate tax system. Without guidelines on what we are trying to achieve, how do we assess any proposal for corporate tax reform? This concern is expressed most clearly by Weisbach(2015): \The basic point is that we cannot know what the optimal pattern of international capital income taxation should be without understanding the reasons for taxing capital income in the first place... To understand the design of firm-level taxation, however, we need to know why we are taxing firms.” ∗Adam Smith Business School, University of Glasgow and Department of Economics, University of the West Indies, Cave Hill, St Michael, Barbados.
    [Show full text]
  • Demand and Supply of Nature Conservation
    Faculty of Environmental Sciences Demand and Supply of Nature Conservation Dissertation for awarding the academic degree Doctor rerum silvaticarum (Dr. rer. silv.) Submitted by M. Sc. Carolin Werthschütz born on April 20th 1985 in Freital Reviewed by: Prof. Dr. habil. Peter Deegen, Technische Universität Dresden Prof. Dr. habil. Goddert von Oheimb, Technische Universität Dresden Prof. Dr. habil. Jan Schnellenbach, Brandenburg University of Technology Cottbus – Senftenberg Date of Submission: April 6th 2017; Tharandt Date of Defense: December 12th 2017; Tharandt Demand and Supply of Nature Conservation Declaration of Conformity Explanation of the doctoral candidate This is to certify that this copy is fully congruent with the original copy of the dissertation with the topic "Demand and Supply of Nature Conservation" Tharandt, April 6th 2017 Carolin Werthschütz II Demand and Supply of Nature Conservation Acknowledgement The success of scientific research – to generate new findings – depends on and is influenced by various external circumstances. I was in the lucky position to receive promoting support of different kind by many persons. I am highly grateful for the respectful and reliable supervision by Prof. Dr. habil. Peter Deegen. He gave me the necessary intellectual freedom to develop own thoughts. Many inspiring discussions and possibilities for an exchange of ideas accompanied our cooperation. During the last years I studied the economics of nature conservation, but the insights I have gained with the help of Peter Deegen go beyond the academic area. Scientific exchange is enriched when a research problem is discussed jointly by different academic disciplines. I would like to thank Prof. Dr. habil. Norbert Weber for the always benevolent discourse between economics and political science.
    [Show full text]
  • Subject ECONOMICS
    ____________________________________________________________________________________________________ Subject ECONOMICS Paper No and Title Paper No. 7: Theory of Public Finance Module No and Module No. 17: Voluntary Exchange Models Title Module Tag ECO_P7_M17 ECONOMICS Paper No. 7: Theory of Public Finance Module No. 17: Voluntary Exchange Models ____________________________________________________________________________________________________ TABLE OF CONTENTS 1. Learning Outcomes 2. Introduction 3. Benefit Theory / Voluntary Exchange Theory 3.1 Lindhal’s Model 3.1.1 Lindhal Equilibrium 3.1.2 Lindhal tax and Pareto optimality 3.1.3 Lindhal pricing 3.1.4 Mathematical representation 3.1.5 Limitations of Lindhal’s model 3.2 Bowen’s Model 3.2.1 Advantages and Limitations of Bowen’s model 3.3 Application of Benefit principle 4. Ability to Pay Approach 5. Summary ECONOMICS Paper No. 7: Theory of Public Finance Module No. 17: Voluntary Exchange Models ____________________________________________________________________________________________________ 1. Learning Outcomes After studying this module, you shall be able to Know about the Benefit theory / Voluntary exchange model. Learn the two approaches of Voluntary exchange model i.e. Lindhal and Bowen’s approach. Identify the advantages and limitations of these approaches. Analyse the feasibility of the two approaches. 2. Introduction Theory of Public goods provides a rationale for the allocation function of Public policy. Public goods exhibit the features of non-excludability and non-rivalry. In the provision of Public goods, private market fails to utilize resources efficiently. Public goods are also closely associated with the ‘free-rider’ problem, in which people do not pay for the good and may continue to access it which results in under-production, overconsumption and degraded goods and hence, government intervention is required.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 2 Federalism, Public Goods, and Taxes
    ch2.qxd 6/17/99 12:06 PM Page 11 Chapter 2 Federalism, Public Goods, and Taxes One element of modern representation consists of representatives re- sponding to their constituents’ preferences for goods and services (Jewell 1982; Pitkin 1967). Responding to constituents’ preferences is at best an uncertain undertaking. Citizens may not communicate their preferences well. There may be competing preferences from citizens within a legislative district. And citizens may be uncertain about their preferences or hold contradictory preferences (Jackson and Kingdon 1992). Pitkin (1967) has argued that representation is a process and posits an ongoing relationship between the representative and the represented. Representation involves responding to constituent demands for goods and services, not just in the narrow sense of pork-barrel projects but also in the broader sense of pro- viding goods and services in accord with citizens’ preferences and having governments impose tax systems citizens accept. An essential component of satisfying constituent preferences for government goods and services involves attaching appropriate pricing systems—taxes—to those services (see Levi 1987). Krehbiel (1991) and Jewell (1982) offer insight into how legislators use information to shape their decisions about how to extract tax revenues and allocate bene‹ts. Both scholars contend that legislators are more con- cerned with a broad-based allocation of tax burdens and resources than with particular bene‹ts for their districts. Jewell examines the positions of individual legislators and does not examine cases in which legislators must collectively decide on an alternative. The second unit of analysis in this work, the collective decisions of the legislature, enables the extension of Jewell’s work on state legislators to understand how individual positions translate into collective policy outcomes.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 8 PUBLIC GOODS
    Chapter 8 PUBLIC GOODS 1. Introduction In the last chapter we analyzed some examples of external effects, and discussed the calculation of appropriate taxes and subsidies to correct ex- ternality problems. In this chapter we carry the externality phenomenon to its logical extreme. We shall examine the theory of the production and consumption of goods whose character is essentially public, rather than private. What do we mean by a public good? Some goods have the property that when one person uses them, all people use them. That is, their use is nonexclusive; if the goods are available to one, they are available to all. There is no practical way for one person to use them alone. Goods that aren't like this, goods that are really private, or exclu- sively used by one person, are easy to think of: a glass of beer, a set of false teeth, a pair of socks, a hamburger. When A is using or consuming one of these things, then, necessarily, B isn't. Goods whose use is neces- sarily nonexclusive are less common, but there are many important ones: Radio and television broadcasts (unless scrambled) are nonexclusive. If A can get the TV signal and B lives nearby, then B can get the TV signal also. (Note that we are talking about the signal, not the TV set, which is a private good. Also note that we are not talking about cable TV, the access to which is again a private good.) There is no practical way to deliver radio waves to A without simultaneously delivering them to B.
    [Show full text]
  • Coercion and Social Welfare in Public Finance
    1 Coercion and Social Welfare in Public Finance Economic and Political Perspectives Editors: Jorge Martinez-Vazquez* and Stanley L. Winer** July 16, 2013 * Regents Professor, Andrew Young School of Policy Studies, Georgia State University, Atlanta ** Canada Research Chair Professor, School of Public Policy and Administration and Department of Economics, Carleton University, Ottawa 2 Dedication To Isaac, Jonah, Lily, Amelia, Oliver and Eleanor. Jorge Martinez-Vazquez To Navah and Zev. Stanley L. Winer 3 Table of Contents Dedication 1. Coercion, Welfare and the Study of Public Finance Jorge Martinez-Vazquez and Stanley L. Winer I Violence, Structured Anarchy and the State 2. The Constitution of Coercion: Wicksell, Violence and the Ordering of Society John J. Wallis 3. Proprietary Public Finance: On its Emergence and Evolution Out of Anarchy Stergios Skaperdas Discussion: A Spatial Model of State Coercion Leonard Dudley II Voluntary and Coercive Transactions in Welfare Analysis 4. Coercion, Taxation and Voluntary Association Roger D. Congleton 5. Kaldor-Hicks Coercion, Coasian Bargaining and the State Michael C. Munger Discussion: A Sociological Perspective on Coercion and Social Welfare Edgar Kiser III Coercion in Public Sector Economics: Theory and Application 6. Non-coercion, Efficiency and Incentive Compatibility in Public Goods John O. Ledyard 7. Social Welfare and Coercion in Public Finance Stanley L. Winer, George Tridimas and Walter Hettich Discussion: The Role of Coercion in Public Economic Theory Robin Boadway 8. Lindahl Fiscal Incidence and the Measurement of Coercion Saloua Sehili and Jorge Martinez-Vazquez Discussion: State- Local Incidence and the Tiebout Model George R. Zodrow 4 9. Fiscal Coercion in Federal Systems, with Special Attention to Highly Divided Societies Giorgio Brosio Discussion: On Coercion in Divided Societies Bernard Grofman IV Coercion in the Laboratory 10.
    [Show full text]
  • The Core of Neoclassical
    EC 742: Handout 2: An Overview of the essential geometry and mathematics of Neoclassical Public Economics I. An Introduction to the Microeconomics of Public Economics. Part II: On the Geometry of Neoclassical Public Economics A. The first half of this handout provides a condensed overview of the basic geometry of public finance with some extensions to the theory of I. Rationality as Net Benefit Maximizing Choice regulation and public choice. A. Nearly all economic models can be developed from a fairly simple model of rational decision making that assume that individuals maximize i. It is intended to be a review for students who have had undergraduate courses in public finance and regulation, and as a quick overview for those who have not. their (expected) private net benefits. a. We will draw upon this “tool bag” repeatedly during this course. i. Consumers maximize consumer surplus: the difference between what a thing is b. These tools provide much of the neoclassical foundation for public economics, worth to them and what they have to pay for it. both as it was being worked out in the first half of the twentieth century and as CS(Q) = TB(Q) - TC(Q) it was applied and extended in the second half. ii. Firms maximize their profit:, the difference in what they receive in revenue from selling a product and its cost of production: B. The second half of the handout reviews some of the core mathematical tools of public economics. = TR(Q) - TC(Q) i. Most of these results and approaches are taken for granted in published research.
    [Show full text]
  • EC 741: Handout 2: a Review of Core Geometric and Mathematical Tools for Public Economics I
    EC 741: Handout 2: A Review of core geometric and mathematical tools for Public Economics I. An Introduction and Review of the Microeconomics of Public ii. Firms maximize their profit:, the difference in what they receive in Economics. revenue from selling a product and its cost of production: A. This handout provides a condensed overview of the basic geometry of = TR(Q) - TC(Q) public finance with some extentions to the theory of regulation and public B. The change in benefits, costs, etc. with respect to quantity consumed or choice. produced is generally called Marginal benefit, or Marginal cost. B. It is intended to be a review for students who have had undergraduate i. DEF: Marginal "X" is the change in Total "X" caused by a one unit courses in public finance and regulation, and as a quick overview for change in quantity. It is the slope of the Total "X" curve. "X" {cost, those who have not. benefit, profit, product, utility, revenue, etc.} C. We will draw upon this “tool bag” repeatedly during this course, because ii. Important Geometric Property: Total "X" can be calculated from a Marginal these tools provide much of the neoclassical foundation for public "X" curve by finding the area under the Marginal l "X" curve over the economics, both as it was being worked out in the first half of the range of interest (often from 0 to some quantity Q). This property twentieth century and as it was being applied and extended in the second allows us to determine consumer surplus and/or profit from a diagram of half.
    [Show full text]
  • Externalities and Public Goods—In More Detail
    Externalities and CHAPTER NINETEEN Public Goods In Chapter 13 we looked briefly at a few problems that may interfere with the allocational efficiency of perfectly competitive markets. Here we will examine two of those problems—externalities and public goods—in more detail. This examination has two pur- poses. First, we wish to show clearly why the existence of externalities and public goods may distort the allocation of resources. In so doing it will be possible to illustrate some additional features of the type of information provided by competitive prices and some of the circumstances that may diminish the usefulness of that information. Our second rea- son for looking more closely at externalities and public goods is to suggest ways in which the allocational problems they pose might be mitigated. We will see that, at least in some cases, the efficiency of competitive market outcomes may be more robust than might have been anticipated. Defining Externalities Externalities occur because economic actors have effects on third parties that are not reflected in market transactions. Chemical makers spewing toxic fumes on their neigh- bors, jet planes waking up people, and motorists littering the highway are, from an eco- nomic point of view, all engaging in the same sort of activity: they are having a direct effect on the well-being of others that is outside market channels. Such activities might be contrasted to the direct effects of markets. When I choose to purchase a loaf of bread, for example, I (perhaps imperceptibly) increase the price of bread generally, and that may affect the well-being of other bread buyers.
    [Show full text]
  • Handbook of Public Finance General Editors: Juergen G
    Handbook of Public Finance General Editors: Juergen G. Backhaus University of Erfurt Richard E. Wagner George Mason University Contributors: Andy H. Barnett Charles B. Blankart Thomas E. Borcherding Rainald Borck Geoffrey Brennan Giuseppe Eusepi J. Stephen Ferris Fred E. Folvary Andrea Garzoni Heinz Grossekettler Walter Hettich Scott Hinds Randall G. Holcombe Jean-Michel Josselin Carla Marchese Alain Marciano William S. Peirce Nicholas Sanchez David Schap A. Allan Schmid Russell S. Sobel Stanley L. Winer Bruce Yandle Handbook of Public Finance Editors Jürgen G. Backhaus University of Erfurt and Richard E. Wagner George Mason University KLUWER ACADEMIC PUBLISHERS NEW YORK, BOSTON, DORDRECHT, LONDON, MOSCOW eBook ISBN: 1-4020-7864-1 Print ISBN: 1-4020-7863-3 ©2005 Springer Science + Business Media, Inc. Print ©2004 Kluwer Academic Publishers Boston All rights reserved No part of this eBook may be reproduced or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, recording, or otherwise, without written consent from the Publisher Created in the United States of America Visit Springer's eBookstore at: http://ebooks.kluweronline.com and the Springer Global Website Online at: http://www.springeronline.com Handbook of Public Finance Table of Contents 1. Jürgen G. Backhaus and Richard E. Wagner 1 Society, State, and Public Finance: Setting the Analytical Stage 2. Russell S. Sobel Welfare Economics and Public Finance 19 3. Geoffrey Brennan and Giuseppe Eusepi Fiscal Constitutionalism 53 4. Thomas E. Borcherding, J. Stephen Ferris, and Andrea Garzoni Growth in the Real Size of Government since 1970 77 5. Walter Hettich and Stanley L. Winer Rules, Politics, and the Normative Analysis of Taxation 109 6.
    [Show full text]