<<

12 Twenty-Five Years of Global Imbalances

MAURICE OBSTFELD

The modern floating era that began in 1973 falls into two stages. The first, which ended in the mid-1990s, was a period of adjustment to the new international monetary regime. Financial markets underwent lib- eralization, internationally as well as domestically, and international trade expanded, while central bankers learned how to manage inflation in a world of national fiat currencies. The period’s end is marked by the foundation of the World Trade Organization (WTO) and the 1994–95 Mexican crisis, which Michel Camdessus, the managing director of the International Mon- etary Fund (IMF) at the time, labeled “the first 21st century crisis.” The second 21st century crisis arrived even before the 21st century did, in the form of the 1997–98 Asian crisis. The Asian crisis was notable in that several of its victims succumbed despite the absence of garden-variety macroeconomic imbalances—such as big public deficits—that IMF econo- mists and others viewed as red flags. This facet of the crisis certainly influ- enced academic thinking (witness the celebrated Kaminsky and Reinhart 1999 analysis of twin banking and currency crises), but it also pointed to the dawn of a new, second stage of the post-1973 era.

Maurice Obstfeld is director of the Research Department at the International Monetary Fund. This chapter is based on remarks made at the conference on “Prospects and Challenges for Sustained Growth in Asia” orga- nized by the Bank of Korea, the Korean Ministry of Strategy and Finance, the International Monetary Fund, and the Peterson Institute for International in Seoul on September 7–8, 2017. The author is grate- ful for suggestions and assistance from Gustavo Adler, Eugenio Cerutti, Luis Cubeddu, Thomas Helbling, and Haonan Zhou. The views expressed in this chapter are those of the author and do not necessarily represent the views of the IMF, its Executive Board, or its management. All errors and interpretations are the author’s alone.

269 That stage, covering roughly the last 25 years, is characterized by hyper- financialization, greater exchange rate flexibility on the part of many emerg- ing-market economies, and a decisive shift of Asian growth leadership from Japan to China, especially after China’s accession to the WTO. Subrama- nian and Kessler (2013) characterize developments in international trade, including rapidly expanding global value chains, as “hyperglobalization.” The forces unleashed after the mid-1990s led to the global financial crisis of 2008–09, a crisis with long-lived repercussions that are still being felt. One notable feature of the second period of floating was a significant widening of global current account imbalances, which roughly tripled in the decade after 1995 and remained higher, albeit at lower levels than the peak they reached before the global financial crisis (figure 12.1). That global imbalances had the potential to widen is not surprising, given financial market development, including further financial opening, after the mid- 1990s. Controversy remains, however, over both the causes of these imbal- ances and their potential causal role in the global financial crisis. On one side is the view, expressed by US Treasury Secretary Henry Paulson as he was leaving office in 2009, that global imbalances originating in the emerging markets were the root cause of the global crisis.1 Others (such as Obstfeld and Rogoff 2009) have argued that this view deflects too much blame from other critical factors. The debate raises at least four questions, which this chapter tries to answer: n Why did global imbalances expand after the mid-1990s? n What circumstances and concomitant factors provide clues about the origins of the global financial crisis? n If one accepts that a monocausal story about the global financial crisis based on global imbalances is inaccurate, how should one view the potential threats from excessive global imbalances today? n What policy implications follow?

Rise of Global Imbalances A prominent feature of the expansion of global imbalances after the mid- 1990s was the growing US deficit (see figure 12.1). In a justly famous speech, Bernanke (2005) argued for “locating the principal causes of the US current account deficit outside the country’s borders.” In his telling, in

1. See Krishna Guha, “Paulson says crisis sown by imbalance,” Financial Times, January 1, 2009, www.ft.com/content/ff671f66-d838-11dd-bcc0-000077b07658.

270 SUSTAINING ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ASIA 2017 2014 2011 2008 2005 2002 1999 1996 Other advanced economies Other EMDEs 1993 China Oil exporters IMF, World Economic Outlook . 1990 0 1.5 1.0 2.5 percent of world GDP Figure 12.1 Global current account balances and reserve purchases, 1990–2017 EMDEs = emerging-market and developing economies Note: “Oil exporters” follows WEO classification and includes Norway. Bars represent regional current account balances, the dotted line total reserve purchases. Source: 2.0 0.5 –1.5 –1.0 –2.0 –0.5

TWENTY-FIVE YEARS OF GLOBAL IMBALANCES 271 Figure 12.2 Real 10-year bond yield in advanced economies, 1990–2018

percent 8 United States 6 Japan 4 Euro area

2

0

–2 Asian crisis Global financial crisis

1990 1993 1996 1999 2002 2005 2008 2011 2014 2017

Sources: Consensus Forecasts; Haver Analytics. For the euro area, the period before 2003 is based on German data. a global capital market equilibrium, higher net saving by emerging-market and developing economies (EMDEs)—precautionary saving by Asian emerg- ing economies after their crisis, bigger surpluses of oil exporters as the price of oil rose—needed to be matched by bigger US deficits. What mechanism induced the United States to save less and invest more? Initially responsible was a run-up in equity prices. After they crashed, the main driver became a fall in real interest rates that, among other effects, fueled a housing price and residential investment boom. Real 10-year Treasury rates rose after the Asian crisis, returning to their long-term decline as recession set in during 2001 (figure 12.2). The pattern was similar for the short-term “natural” policy rates (r*), as calculated by Holston, Laubach, and Williams (2017) (see figure 12.3). Figure 12.4 is another way to visualize the dramatic widening of the US external deficit after the mid-1990s. Where are the counterpart widening surpluses? The top panel shows that deficits of non-oil-exporting EMDEs (including China) did start to rise as the Asian crisis erupted, but the extent of the increase was dwarfed by the rise in the US deficit. More important was the increase in oil exporters’ surpluses. In Asia (bottom panel), surpluses of East Asian economies other than China and Japan rose after the Asian crisis. China’s surplus began to rise later, in the mid-2000s, reaching about 0.6 percent of global GDP in 2008. There were multiple counterpart surpluses to the US deficit; one of the biggest came from oil exporters. Their surpluses were driven by steeply

272 SUSTAINING ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ASIA Figure 12.3 Natural rate of interest (r*) in advanced economies, 1990–2016

percent 4

3

2

1

0

–1 Asian crisis Global financial crisis

1990 1993 1996 1999 2002 2005 2008 2011 2014

United States United Kingdom Canada Euro area

Source: Holston, Laubach, and Williams (2017).

rising global oil prices, however (figure 12.5).2 As US real activity, financial conditions, and domestic oil production are critical determinants of con- ditions in the world oil market, it seems implausible that changes in oil prices emanated entirely from outside US borders to influence its current account. Instead, the US deficit reflected domestic as well as global forces— global forces coming from other advanced economies, not just EMDEs—all of which helped set the stage for the global financial crisis.

Background to the Global Financial Crisis Common factors drove oil prices, oil surpluses, and bigger current account deficits in several advanced economies. They included very loose global fi- nancial conditions, enabled by generally accommodative monetary policies, as well as financial deregulation and innovation, and a global reach for yield and safety that contributed to widespread housing market booms. One component of this constellation, though likely not the most im- portant one, was the accumulation of foreign reserves by EMDEs, which Bernanke (2005) noted (figure 12.1). During 1998–2008, intervention

2. In the early 2000s, measured world surpluses surged above world deficits; a substantial global discrepancy—a “missing deficit”—emerged. Missing deficits tend to be positively corre- lated with oil prices. The discrepancy could be related to some countries understating the cost of oil imports.

TWENTY-FIVE YEARS OF GLOBAL IMBALANCES 273 Figure 12.4 Current account balances, 1991–2017

a. World percent of world GDP 1.0

0.5

0

–0.5

–1.0 United States Other advanced –1.5 economies Oil exporters –2.0 Other EMDEs Asian crisis Global financial crisis

1991 1995 1999 2003 2007 2011 2015

b. East Asia percent of world GDP 1.0

0.6

0.2

–0.2 China Japan –0.6 Other East Asian advanced economies Other East Asian –1.0 EMDEs Asian crisis Global financial crisis

1991 1995 1999 2003 2007 2011 2015

EMDEs = emerging-market and developing economies Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook. tended to be associated with wider surpluses for countries purchasing foreign exchange. But the US housing bubble also drew fuel from European banks’ purchases of asset-backed securities, as Bernanke et al. (2011) and Bayoumi (2017) document. Perceiving low sovereign and no currency risk within a permissive regulatory environment, banks in , , and other European countries recycled global funding into peripheral econ- omies in the euro area, such as Spain, Ireland, Portugal, and Greece, financ- ing housing or sovereign debt bubbles and big external deficits (Hale and Obstfeld 2016). Similar dynamics played out in the Baltics.

274 SUSTAINING ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ASIA Figure 12.5 World oil price and oil exporters' current account, 1991–2017

current account balance Brent crude oil (percent of GDP) (dollars per barrel) 1.0 120 Oil exporters’ current 0.8 account 100 Brent crude oil price 0.6 (right axis) 80 0.4 60 0.2 40 0

–0.2 20

–0.4 0

1991 2011 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2013 2015 2017

Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook; Haver Analytics; IMF Sta‹ calculations.

A symptom of global financial ease during the 2000s, coupled with ongoing deregulation and innovation, was an explosion of two-way capital flows across borders. Figure 12.6 shows the pattern of gross international financing corresponding to the net international financing needs illustrated in figure 12.1. Starting in the mid-1990s, gross flows began to expand mark- edly, reaching unprecedented proportions on the eve of the global financial crisis. Tellingly, the vertical axis scale needed to chart gross flows in figure 12.6 is a full order of magnitude greater than the scale needed in figure 12.1: The bare minimum capital flows needed to finance current account imbal- ances would have been only a tenth of the flows that actually took place. In theory, gross two-way flows fulfill economic functions beyond the fi- nancing of current account imbalances, notably, asset swaps that enable in- ternational portfolio diversification and risk sharing. No known economic or financial model can easily rationalize gross flows that were persistently such a big share of global GDP in the run-up to the crisis, however. Much of the asset churning was likely driven by tax avoidance strategies or regulatory arbitrage, exemplified by the surge in European purchases of US mortgage-related assets (see, e.g., Acharya and Schnabl 2010). These developments were a symptom of the financial distortions that ultimately helped power the US current account deficit. Following their sharp expansion starting in the mid-1990s, gross ex- ternal positions leveled off after the finanical crisis, at least in the aggre- gate (see figure 12.7). An increasing fraction of gross external positions now seems to represent foreign direct investment (FDI), although as Lane and

TWENTY-FIVE YEARS OF GLOBAL IMBALANCES 275 2017 2014 2011 2008 2005 2002 Portfolio investment outflow FDI inflow FDI outflow 1999 1996 1993 Other investment inflow Other investment outflow Portfolio investment inflow 1990 5 0 15 10 –5 25 percent of world GDP FDI = foreign direct investment Source: IMF, Statistics . Figure 12.6 Global gross financial flows, 1990–2017 20 –15 –10 –25 –20

276 SUSTAINING ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ASIA 2016 2014 2012 2010 2008 2006 2004 2002 2000 1998 1996 1994 1992 Portfolio equity FDI Other investment Portfolio debt 1990 0 50 150 100 250 percent of world GDP Figure 12.7 Global investment liabilities stock, 1990–2016 FDI = foreign direct investment Source: IMF, International Investment Position, World Economic Outlook . 200

TWENTY-FIVE YEARS OF GLOBAL IMBALANCES 277 Miles-Ferretti (2018) document, much of this so-called FDI reflects not risk sharing or greenfield investment but claims on offshore financial centers, driven by tax minimization strategies.

Risks from Excess Global Imbalances Twenty-first century crises have largely been balance sheet crises, driven more by predetermined vulnerabilities (currency and maturity risk) than by the risk that the flow of financing for the current account deficit dries up. The very large gross flows in figure 12.6 represent potentially fragile balance sheet positions that could threaten financial stability, with severe macroeconomic consequences. Why, then, worry about even outsized current account imbalances? One reason is that an excessive flow deficit may be one symptom of an under- lying buildup of stock vulnerabilities. Generally easy financial conditions (including lax or badly designed regulation) will tend to promote leverage, which in turn facilitates divergence between spending and income. The eventual adjustment process can be costlier when it follows bigger imbal- ances. Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2015), for example, show how countries with bigger current account deficits before the global financial crisis tended to suffer greater demand compression when the crisis struck. Another reason to worry about excess imbalances, especially if they are persistent, is that they could imply widening international disparities in net external wealth. Although the growth of gross external positions has leveled off for now, the net international investment positions of inter- national creditors and debtors have grown increasingly divergent (figure 12.8). Absent future changes in asset valuations, the IMF projects that this divergence trend will continue (IMF 2017). The tendency for debtors to go ever farther into debt (while credi- tors accumulate those debts as assets) has been a salient phenomenon, as figure 12.9 illustrates for the sample of countries covered in the IMF’s annual External Sector Reports. Since 2010 countries’ cumulative current account balances have been strongly positively correlated with initial net foreign assets. That propensity, however, leads to a sustainability problem. Eventually, debtor countries will have to reduce spending to reflect their intertemporal budget constraints; the longer the adjustment is postponed, the more likely it is that the process will be abrupt and disruptive, creating a global deflationary impulse unless creditor countries just as abruptly decide to spend more. Low real interest rates encourage debtors to continue borrowing and creditors to accumulate wealth more assiduously as they seek to ensure adequate resources for the future. Higher equilibrium interest rates could

278 SUSTAINING ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ASIA Figure 12.8 Net international investment positions, 2002–17

percent of world GDP 20

10

0

–10

–20

–30 2002 2005 2008 2011 2014 2017

Oil exporters United Kingdom Other surplus Deficit emerging-market economies Surplus advanced economies Advanced-economy commodity Japan exporters Germany/ Other deficit countries China East Asia (other) United States Discrepancy

Surplus advanced economies = Korea, Hong Kong, Singapore, Sweden, Switzerland, and Taiwan; Advanced-economy commodity exporters: , Canada, and New Zealand; Deficit emerging-market economies = Brazil, India, Indonesia, Mexico, South Africa, and Turkey; Oil exporters = World Economic Outlook definition plus Norway. Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook; IMF Sta‘ calculations.

TWENTY-FIVE YEARS OF GLOBAL IMBALANCES 279 create problems if they rise more than underlying economic growth rates. In integrated capital markets, real interest rates depend on global, not just national, growth. IMF projections of growth prospects for advanced economies are relatively subdued. As the External Sector Report (IMF 2017) points out, however, big deficits (and surpluses) have also increasingly become concentrated in precisely these slower-growing advanced debtors (and creditors). Down the road, therefore, higher real interest rates could spell trouble for some advanced debtors if the levels of those rates reflect primarily the better growth prospects in lower-income economies. A possible mitigating factor could be the effect identified by Gourinchas and Rey (2007) for the United States, according to which an unexpected fall in net exports triggers an unexpected capital gain on the net international investment position, thereby mitigating the negative effect of the net export innovation. When the World Economic Outlook examined the generality of this effect more than a decade ago (IMF 2005), it detected some evidence of the Gourinchas-Rey effect for advanced economies but not for EMDEs. The finding was unsurprising in view of the pervasive foreign currency denomi- nation of EMDEs’ foreign liabilities and the relatively early stage of their integration into world capital markets. Currency mismatch has declined since the early 2000s, however (Béné- trix, Lane, and Shambaugh 2015), and it appears that the Gourinchas-Rey effect now applies more broadly. This stabilizing force may owe more to do- mestic asset price developments than exchange rates. Whatever its source, estimates suggest that it provides only a partial offset to trade balance de- velopments (Adler and Garcia-Macia 2018). Figures 12.9 and 12.10 (which can be compared) illustrate how the Gourinchas-Rey effect has muted but not eliminated the divergent behavior of net international investment posi- tions. The tendency of current accounts to drive divergence in net foreign assets shown in figure 12.10 remains problematic. A third danger from big and persistent global imbalances, one that is currently prominent, is that they may spark trade warfare as deficit coun- tries vainly try to counter macroeconomic forces with import barriers. From the Asian crisis through the early 2010s, global current account surpluses were closely aligned with global foreign exchange purchases (figure 12.1). Indeed, several economies, notably in emerging East Asia, intervened to maintain their currencies at undervalued levels, as did some important oil exporters. Charges of currency manipulation and trade tensions resulted.3

3. In the cases of oil exporters with exchange rate pegs (e.g., Saudi Arabia), causality clearly ran from the price of oil through the current account to reserve accumulation. In Asian econ- omies—notably China, with its capital control regime—intervention likely had some causal impact on the current account, to different degrees in different economies.

280 SUSTAINING ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ASIA Figure 12.9 Current account behavior has led net international investment positions to diverge change in international investment positions (2017–2010) excluding valuation changes, percent of GDP 100 NOR 80 CHE NLD 60 DNK DEU

40 SWEMYS KORRUS THA y = 0.4108x + 8.2883 R = 0.4173 HUN PHL ISR JPN 20 IRL AUT CHN

ESP ITA BEL CZE GTMFRA 0 PAK ARGFIN MEXIDN INDCHL PRT USA NZLPOL PER AUS BRACRICAN –20 ZAFCOL GBR MAR GRC TUR –40

–60 TUN

–80 –150 –100 –50 0 50 100 150 200 net international investment positions (2010, percent of GDP)

Note: Vertical axis measures cumulated nominal current accounts between 2010 and 2017, adjusted to reflect the path of nominal income growth. Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook; IMF Sta† calculations.

In more recent years, however, global imbalances owe little to foreign exchange intervention by EMDEs, as IMF (2017) observes and figure 12.1 shows. This change is consistent with the greater concentration of imbal- ances within the advanced economy group noted above. Although discus- sion of currency manipulation is much more muted than it was a few years ago, it can be expected to return to the fore if the US dollar strengthens in response to Federal Reserve tightening and procyclical fiscal expansion in the United States. Because of those US macroeconomic prospects, the IMF now projects a bigger US current account deficit in coming years, notwithstanding the US administration’s avowed aim of trimming deficits through trade policies. That tension will doubtless be a source of future trade frictions between the United States and the rest of the world. Those frictions may in turn take a toll on global economic growth.

TWENTY-FIVE YEARS OF GLOBAL IMBALANCES 281 Figure 12.10 Valuation effects have moderated but not eliminated the tendency for net international investment positions to diverge

change in net international investment positions (2017–2010) including valuation changes, percent of GDP 150 NOR

100

NLD DNK y = 0.1697x + 8.2267 50 HUN DEU R = 0.0666 KOR TUN CZE ZAF RUS ISR ESP ITA AUT PRT GRC POL BRA THA SWE NZL AUS IDN PHL ARG CHN MEX GBRMYS JPN CHE TUR PAK GTMINDFRACHL 0 PER MAR COL FIN BEL CRI USA

–50

–100 IRL

–150 –150 –100 –50 0 50 100 150 200 net international investment positions (2010, percent of GDP)

Source: IMF, World Economic Outlook; IMF Sta calculations.

Policy Implications This analysis yields four main implications for policy: n Excess global imbalances usually reflect global forces and multiple distortions in many countries, including diverse financial sector dis- tortions. Monocausal explanations rarely apply. Reducing global im- balances should therefore be a collective effort based on a shared appre- ciation of the roles individual countries need to play. To promote that objective, the IMF monitors external excess imbalances annually and makes its findings public through the External Sector Report. n Notwithstanding the need for collective action, excess surplus countries still face little that would force them to adjust (outside of the threat of protectionist responses). In contrast, most deficit countries face the risk that lenders will withdraw. The trend of diverging net international investment positions thus looks unsustainable. Its end is likely to origi- nate with external debtors. n That endgame could be messy. Gross capital flows far exceed the minimal needs of current account financing. These flows can give rise

282 SUSTAINING ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ASIA to balance sheet vulnerabilities, underlining the need for continuing international financial cooperation (within the Basel Committee, the Financial Stability Board, and other international forums) to address cross-border financial stability risks. Similar cooperation to address so- cially costly tax minimization strategies and money laundering is richly warranted. n Economic theory suggests that trade restrictions will do little to alter global current account imbalances, which are primarily macroeconom- ic phenomena. But protectionism can do great harm to global growth. Stronger multilateral dispute resolution within the rules-based system is the right way to deal with the range of policies that distort trade and tilt the playing field.

References Acharya, V., and P. Schnabl. 2010. Do Global Banks Spread Global Imbalances? Asset-Backed Commercial Paper During the Financial Crisis of 2007–09. IMF Economic Review 58, no. 1: 37–73. Adler, G., and D. Garcia-Macia. 2018. The Stabilizing Role of Net Foreign Asset Returns. IMF Work- ing Paper WP/18/79 (March). Washington: International Monetary Fund. Bayoumi, T. 2017. Unfinished Business: The Unexplored Causes of the Financial Crisis and the Lessons Yet to Be Learned. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Bénétrix, A., P. Lane, and J. Shambaugh. 2015. International Currency Exposures, Valuation Effects, and the Global Financial Crisis. Journal of 96, no. S1: S98– S109. Bernanke, B. 2005. The Global Saving Glut and the U.S. Current Account Deficit. Sandridge Lecture to the Virginia Association of Economists, Richmond, VA, March 10. Bernanke, B., C. Bertaut, L. DeMarco, and S. Kamin. 2011. International Capital Flows and the Returns to Safe Assets in the United States, 2003–2007. Financial Stability Review (Banque de France) 15: 13–26. Gourinchas, P.-O., and H. Rey. 2007. International Financial Adjustment. Journal of Political Economy 114, no. 4: 665–703. Hale, G., and M. Obstfeld. 2016. The Euro and the Geography of International Debt Flows. Journal of the European Economic Association 14, no. 1: 115–44. Holston, K., T. Laubach, and J. Williams. 2017. Measuring the Natural Rate of Interest: Inter- national Trends and Determinants. Journal of International Economics 108, no. S1: S59–S75. IMF (International Monetary Fund). 2005. Globalization and External Imbalances. In World Economic Outlook (April). Washington. IMF (International Monetary Fund). 2017. External Sector Report (July). Washington. Kaminsky, G., and C. Reinhart. 1999. The Twin Crises: The Causes of Banking and Balance- of-Payments Problems. American Economic Review 89, no. 3: 473–500. Lane, P. and G. Milesi-Ferretti. 2015. Global Imbalances and External Adjustment After the Crisis. In Global Liquidity, Spillovers to Emerging Markets and Policy Responses, ed. C. Raddatz, D. Saravia, and J. Ventura. Santiago: Central Bank of Chile. Lane, P., and G. Milesi-Ferretti. 2018. The External Wealth of Nations Revisited: International Financial Integration in the Aftermath of the Global Financial Crisis. IMF Economic Review 66, no. 1: 189–222.

TWENTY-FIVE YEARS OF GLOBAL IMBALANCES 283 Obstfeld, M., and K. Rogoff. 2009. Global Imbalances and the Financial Crisis: Products of Common Causes. In Asia and the Global Financial Crisis, ed. R. Glick and M. Spiegel, 131– 172. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco. Subramanian, Arvind, and Martin Kessler. 2013. The Hyperglobalization of Trade and Its Future. PIIE Working Paper 13-6 (July). Washington: Peterson Institute for International Eco- nomics.

284 SUSTAINING ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ASIA