Classical Reflections on the Deficit

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Load more

IF cs.~; cd c!>:; W«(isH lJ« ~; ~~) (~Jl'\V/ ~ ill) iii\, It\\lf~ C(J) tt ~:b«\\m\ IF'w (i\\m\Cc';li~0(C::C0) October 14, 1983 Classical Reflections On The Deficit The primary long-term effect ofdeficits is to Reserve System, which although formally reduce the rate ofcapital formation. Gov­ independent ofthe executive branch, can be ernment borrowing crowds alit private treated for our purposes as part of the gov­ borrowing and causes a lower rate ofinvest­ ernment. When the Federal Reserve buys ment. The lower rate ofcapital formation Treasury debt, itpays with an increase in the hurts productivity, decreases growth, limits monetary base which will be held either as the rise in real incomes and weakens our reserves of depository financial institutions international competitiveness. (Martin or as currency in the hands of the public. Feldstein, Chairman of the President's This transaction is sometimes called "mone­ Council of Economic Advisers in the Wall tizing the debt," and it leaves the public Streetjournal,)uly 15, 1983.) holding more non-interest bearing govern­ ment liabilities in the form of money and Everybody's jumping to the conclusion that fewer interest-bearing liabilities in the form Icrowding out] is going to happen in 30 ofTreasury securities. days ... it's not going to happen in three months. (Secretary of the Treasury, Donald Government's expenditure is constrained to T. Regan, quoted in the Washington Post, equal the sum of taxes plus the sales of debt August 23, 1983.) to the public (including banks) plus the creation of monetary base by the Federal With the prospect of large federal govern­ Reserve. Since deficits are the excess of ment deficits during this year and perhaps government expenditure over taxes, the for several years to come, the question as to budget constraint may also be expressed as: what their effects will be is in the forefront of deficits must equal the sales of debt to the discussions ofeconomic policy. Reasonable public plus the creation ofmonetary base by people evidently differ on the answer. the Federal Reserve. Unfortunately, it is not always clear from their pronouncements what the basisof their Ricardian equivalence judgments is. Close examination shows that The current policy debate centers on what may lie atthe heart oftheir differences whether or not different compositions of are some fundamental conceptual issues in government finance result in crowding out. economic theory-in particular, whether In particular, does issuing more debt and taxation and government borrowing are lowering taxes raise real interest rates and economically equivalent forms of govern­ crowd out private investment? Ricardo gave ment finance, and whether it makes a differ­ an early analysis of the problem in his ence if government debt takes the form of Principles of Political Economy and interest-bearing bonds or non-interest-bear­ Taxation (1821). ing currency and bank reserves. This Letter builds on a discussion by the nineteenth He argued that if taxpayers fu lIy understood century English classical economist David that government borrowing only postpones Ricardo to help clarify these issues. the payment o!.taxes, it wou Id not matter at all howdeficits were financed. If the govern­ Government's budget constraint ment chose to finance a given expenditure All federal expenditures must be paid for, through taxes, each taxpayer could borrow but there is a choice of sources for the enough to pay his taxes (i.e., sell a bond) and needed funds. The Treasury can raise taxes, then would immediately have to pay only or it can go into debt. Its debt may either be the interest and some portion of the princi­ held by the public at large or by the Federal pal on the loan. If the government financed 1 Opinion~ expressed in Ihis newsletter do not necessarilv reflect the vie\vs 01 the manag(~ment of the reelera! Reserve' Bank of San francisco, or of the Board of Covernors of the Federal Reserve Systern. the same deficit by selling its own bonds to taxpayers would save enough to pay only the public, the taxpayers would be taxed to the taxes that cover the interest on the debt pay the interest and the currently maturing and forget about the need to repay the prin­ principal on the government bonds. In either cipal in the future. Debt finance would then case, the taxpayer might pay the taxes with­ appear to be more stimulative than tax out borrowing the money, but if he treated finance when the economy is operating at the amount paid as a loan to himself, he less than full employment. would find that the portion of his income available for consumption would be no less If Ricardo's theoretical argument held in than ifhe had actually borrowed the money. practice, different splits between taxes and Ricardo argued, in effect, that the composi­ debt finance would not affect spendable tion of government finance for the same incomes. Private saving would always level ofexpenditure made no difference adjust to the amount needed to service the since taxpayers can make exactly compen­ debt, and interest rates would not be sating adjustments in their own portfolios. affected. On the other hand, if Ricardo's practical judgment were correct, taxpayers Ricardo's argument for the equ ivalence of would feel richer when government expen­ debt and taxation rests on at least two im­ diture is financed by debt rather than by plicit assumptions. The first is that taxpayers taxes. They would want to spend more, but are economically similar. If this assumption since they would not actually be richer, they were relaxed, then taxpayers' after-tax in­ could only spend more by saving less. To comes would be affected by the method of induce them to save enough to cover the government finance. Suppose, for example, debt, the interest rate on government bonds that some people are seen by lenders to be a would have to rise. Higher interest rates greater risk than others and are, therefore, would then discourage private investment. charged a higher rate of interest. Lowering Thus, when there is debt illusion, the more taxes and issu ing an equal amount of debt the method of government finance opts for means that high-risk borrowers have more debtover taxes, the lowerwould be the level cash in hand and pay it back through taxes at of fJrivate investment and the higher the a lower rate than they would pay ifthey had level of private consumption. borrowed it privately. Debt finance would thus affect their incomes. In the same way, The burden of debt if the people who buy most of the bonds Despite showing that debt and taxes could differed from those who pay most of the beequivalent, Ricardo believed that govem­ taxes, substituting debt for taxes would ment should favor taxes over debt even if affect incomes. The second assumption is there were no debt-illusion. His reason was that taxes are not distorting, that they do not that present taxes are immediate and hard to alter the optimal allocation of resources. If escape, but a large debt implying high future this assumption were relaxed, for example, taxes would encourage emigration to avoid if taxes were levied only on consumption paying future taxes. Ricardo's argument can (e.g., sales taxl, then lowering taxes and rais­ be reformu lated to show that the present ing debt would favor consumption at the generation can escape taxes by incurring expense of investment. debt that must be paid by generations that live long after the present one is dead and Ricardo recognized that his argument for the gone. It is said that "the past is another equivalence ofdebt finance and taxation country." The present generation, in effect, was a theoretical one that depended cru­ would emigrate to the past by shifting the cially on accurate anticipations offuture burden ofdebt onto its descendants. That taxes. He believed that, in practice, there burden can be measured by the degree to would be "debt-illusion" in the sense that which the capital stock is smaller because 2 previous generations invested less as a re­ orfixed rate ofreturn, these high rates would sponse to higher interest rates caused by the induce people to hold more government choice of debt financing. bonds and less money. Such a situation is equivalent to a rise in the velocity ofcircula­ This theoretical analysis raises two ques­ tion of money, which would support a tions: First, can the burden of debt actually higher rate of inflation. be shifted onto future generations? That is, are taxes and debt finance equivalent across In practice, we are not facing such a hyper­ generations? Second, is it desirable to shift expansion of government debt. Instead, we the burden ofdebt? The answer to the are facing a large increase in the ratio of second question depends on one's values, interest-bearing government debt to non­ but its importance depends on the answer to interest-bearing monetary base. In the the first question. long-run, since both are nominal liabilities of the government, it may make little differ­ Ricardo believed that the burden of govern­ ence which is used to finance the deficit. In ment debt can be shifted to other genera­ the short-run, however, the government can tions. His implicit assumption is that the sell more debt to the private sector only by debt must eventually be paid off by the tax­ offering a higher rate of return to increase its payers, but that it can be postponed by issu­ attractiveness. That this rise in interest rates ing more debt. If this were done continu­ will crowd-out private investment is the ously, no future generation would be taxed principal fear of those who oppose further to payoff the debt.
Recommended publications
  • Money Supply ECON 40364: Monetary Theory & Policy

    Money Supply ECON 40364: Monetary Theory & Policy

    Money Supply ECON 40364: Monetary Theory & Policy Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2017 1 / 59 Readings I Mishkin Ch. 3 I Mishkin Ch. 14 I Mishkin Ch. 15, pg. 341-348 2 / 59 Money I Money is defined as anything that is accepted as payments for goods or services or in the repayment of debts I Money serves three functions: 1. Medium of exchange 2. Unit of account 3. Store of value I Any asset can serve as a store of value (e.g. house, land, stocks, bonds), but most assets do not perform the first two roles of money I Money is a stock concept { how much money you have (in your wallet, in the bank) at a given point in time. Income is a flow concept 3 / 59 Roles of Money I Medium of exchange role is the most important role of money: I Eliminates need for barter, reduces transactions costs associated with exchange, and allows for greater specialization I Unit of account is important (particularly in a diverse economy), though anything could serve as a unit of account I As a store of value, money tends to be crummy relative to other assets like stocks and houses, which offer some expected return over time I An advantage money has as a store of value is its liquidity I Liquidity refers to ease with which an asset can be converted into a medium of exchange (i.e. money) I Money is the most liquid asset because it is the medium of exchange I If you held all your wealth in housing, and you wanted to buy a car, you would have to sell (liquidate) the house, which may not be easy to do, may take a while, and may involve selling at a discount if you must do it quickly 4 / 59 Evolution of Money and Payments I Commodity money: money made up of precious metals or other commodities I Difficult to carry around, potentially difficult to divide, price may fluctuate if precious metal or commodity has consumption value independent of medium of exchange role I Paper currency: pieces of paper that are accepted as medium of exchange.
  • Sudden Stops and Currency Drops: a Historical Look

    Sudden Stops and Currency Drops: a Historical Look

    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by Research Papers in Economics This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: The Decline of Latin American Economies: Growth, Institutions, and Crises Volume Author/Editor: Sebastian Edwards, Gerardo Esquivel and Graciela Márquez, editors Volume Publisher: University of Chicago Press Volume ISBN: 0-226-18500-1 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/edwa04-1 Conference Date: December 2-4, 2004 Publication Date: July 2007 Title: Sudden Stops and Currency Drops: A Historical Look Author: Luis A. V. Catão URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c10658 7 Sudden Stops and Currency Drops A Historical Look Luis A. V. Catão 7.1 Introduction A prominent strand of international macroeconomics literature has re- cently devoted considerable attention to what has been dubbed “sudden stops”; that is, sharp reversals in aggregate foreign capital inflows. While there seems to be insufficient consensus on what triggers such reversals, two consequences have been amply documented—namely, exchange rate drops and downturns in economic activity, effectively constricting domes- tic consumption smoothing. This literature also notes, however, that not all countries respond similarly to sudden stops: whereas ensuing devaluations and output contractions are often dramatic among emerging markets, fi- nancially advanced countries tend to be far more impervious to those dis- ruptive effects.1 These stylized facts about sudden stops have been based entirely on post-1970 evidence. Yet, periodical sharp reversals in international capital flows are not new phenomena. Leaving aside the period between the 1930s Depression and the breakdown of the Bretton-Woods system in 1971 (when stringent controls on cross-border capital flows prevailed around Luis A.
  • Central Bank Interventions, Communication and Interest Rate Policy in Emerging European Economies

    Central Bank Interventions, Communication and Interest Rate Policy in Emerging European Economies

    CENTRAL BANK INTERVENTIONS, COMMUNICATION AND INTEREST RATE POLICY IN EMERGING EUROPEAN ECONOMIES BALÁZS ÉGERT CESIFO WORKING PAPER NO. 1869 CATEGORY 6: MONETARY POLICY AND INTERNATIONAL FINANCE DECEMBER 2006 An electronic version of the paper may be downloaded • from the SSRN website: www.SSRN.com • from the RePEc website: www.RePEc.org • from the CESifo website: www.CESifo-group.deT T CESifo Working Paper No. 1869 CENTRAL BANK INTERVENTIONS, COMMUNICATION AND INTEREST RATE POLICY IN EMERGING EUROPEAN ECONOMIES Abstract This paper analyses the effectiveness of foreign exchange interventions in Croatia, the Czech Republic, Hungary, Romania, Slovakia and Turkey using the event study approach. Interventions are found to be effective only in the short run when they ease appreciation pressures. Central bank communication and interest rate steps considerably enhance their effectiveness. The observed effect of interventions on the exchange rate corresponds to the declared objectives of the central banks of Croatia, the Czech Republic, Hungary and perhaps also Romania, whereas this is only partially true for Slovakia and Turkey. Finally, interventions are mostly sterilized in all countries except Croatia. Interventions are not much more effective in Croatia than in the other countries studied. This suggests that unsterilized interventions do not automatically influence the exchange rate. JEL Code: F31. Keywords: central bank intervention, foreign exchange intervention, verbal intervention, central bank communication, Central and Eastern Europe, Turkey. Balázs Égert Austrian National Bank Foreign Research Division Otto-Wagner-Platz 3 1090 Vienna Austria [email protected] I would like to thank Harald Grech and Zoltán Walko for useful discussion and two anonymous referees for very helpful comments and suggestions.
  • Deflation and Monetary Policy in a Historical Perspective: Remembering the Past Or Being Condemned to Repeat It?

    Deflation and Monetary Policy in a Historical Perspective: Remembering the Past Or Being Condemned to Repeat It?

    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES DEFLATION AND MONETARY POLICY IN A HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE: REMEMBERING THE PAST OR BEING CONDEMNED TO REPEAT IT? Michael D. Bordo Andrew Filardo Working Paper 10833 http://www.nber.org/papers/w10833 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 October 2004 This paper was prepared for the 40th Panel Meeting of Economic Policy in Amsterdam (October 2004). The authors would like to thank Jeff Amato, Palle Andersen, Claudio Borio, Gauti Eggertsson, Gabriele Galati, Craig Hakkio, David Lebow and Goetz von Peter, Patrick Minford, Fernando Restoy, Lars Svensson, participants at the 3rd Annual BIS Conference as well as seminar participants at the Bank of Canada and the International Monetary Fund for helpful discussions and comments. We also thank Les Skoczylas and Arturo Macias Fernandez for expert assistance. The views expressed are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Bank for International Settlements or the National Bureau of Economic Research. The views expressed herein are those of the author(s) and not necessarily those of the National Bureau of Economic Research. ©2004 by Michael D. Bordo and Andrew Filardo. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source. Deflation and Monetary Policy in a Historical Perspective: Remembering the Past or Being Condemned to Repeat It? Michael D. Bordo and Andrew Filardo NBER Working Paper No. 10833 October 2004 JEL No. E31, N10 ABSTRACT What does the historical record tell us about how to conduct monetary policy in a deflationary environment? We present a broad cross-country historical study of deflation over the past two centuries in order to shed light on current policy challenges.
  • Hyperinflation in Venezuela

    Hyperinflation in Venezuela

    POLICY BRIEF recovery can be possible without first stabilizing the explo- 19-13 Hyperinflation sive price level. Doing so will require changing the country’s fiscal and monetary regimes. in Venezuela: A Since late 2018, authorities have been trying to control the price spiral by cutting back on fiscal expenditures, contracting Stabilization domestic credit, and implementing new exchange rate poli- cies. As a result, inflation initially receded from its extreme Handbook levels, albeit to a very high and potentially unstable 30 percent a month. But independent estimates suggest that prices went Gonzalo Huertas out of control again in mid-July 2019, reaching weekly rates September 2019 of 10 percent, placing the economy back in hyperinflation territory. Instability was also reflected in the premium on Gonzalo Huertas was research analyst at the Peterson Institute foreign currency in the black market, which also increased for International Economics. He worked with C. Fred Bergsten in July after a period of relative calm in previous months. Senior Fellow Olivier Blanchard on macroeconomic theory This Policy Brief describes a feasible stabilization plan and policy. Before joining the Institute, Huertas worked as a researcher at Harvard University for President Emeritus and for Venezuela’s extreme inflation. It places the country’s Charles W. Eliot Professor Lawrence H. Summers, producing problems in context by outlining the economics behind work on fiscal policy, and for Minos A. Zombanakis Professor Carmen Reinhart, focusing on exchange rate interventions. hyperinflations: how they develop, how they disrupt the normal functioning of economies, and how other countries Author’s Note: I am grateful to Adam Posen, Olivier Blanchard, across history have designed policies to overcome them.
  • Inflation Vs. Deflation Which Is More Likely Part 2.Mp4

    Inflation Vs. Deflation Which Is More Likely Part 2.Mp4

    Inflation vs. deflation Which is more likely Part 2.mp4 Speaker1: As discussed last month, many economic experts believe that the US and other related countries like Canada are more likely to face deflation than inflation in the years to come. These experts point to the theory of debt deflation. When debts are excessive and people try to reduce their debts by selling assets, it puts downward pressure on prices and can result in deflation. Deflation is viewed by many economists as more harmful to the economy. Hi, I'm Michael Chugh. These low interest rates we see now on US 10 year bonds of around two percent prove that many savvy investors are betting that deflation is very possible. But we also hear other investors and economists worrying about the future high levels of inflation. Many say the unprecedented increase in monetary base in the US, which has increased almost fivefold from eight hundred forty three billion in August, two thousand eight to four trillion. Currently, the monetary base consists of all the notes in circulation and in bank vaults. It also includes the reserves that the banks have on deposit. The US Federal Reserve, the US Federal Reserve increased the monetary base mainly through its series of financial rescue programs in 2008 and then by its quantitative easing programs in 2009 through 2014. The monetary base is only a fraction of the money supply. The money supply, or M2, consists of all the notes in circulation plus all the money in bank accounts. Speaker1: The concern is that a large increase in monetary base can cause a big increase in money supply because of the multiplier effect.
  • The Monetary Transmission Mechanism

    The Monetary Transmission Mechanism

    No. 06‐1 The Monetary Transmission Mechanism Peter N. Ireland Abstract: The monetary transmission mechanism describes how policy‐induced changes in the nominal money stock or the short‐term nominal interest rate impact real variables such as aggregate output and employment. Specific channels of monetary transmission operate through the effects that monetary policy has on interest rates, exchange rates, equity and real estate prices, bank lending, and firm balance sheets. Recent research on the transmission mechanism seeks to understand how these channels work in the context of dynamic, stochastic, general equilibrium models. JEL Classifications: E52 Peter N. Ireland is Professor of Economics at Boston College, a visiting scholar at the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, and a research associate at the NBER. His email address and web site are [email protected] and http://www2.bc.edu/~irelandp, respectively. This paper was prepared for The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Second Edition, edited by Lawrence Blume and Steven Durlauf, Hampshire: Palgrave Macmillan, Ltd. This paper, which may be revised, is available on the web site of the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston at http://www.bos.frb.org/economic/wp/index.htm. The opinions, findings, and conclusions or recommendations expressed in this paper are solely those of the author and do not reflect official positions of the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, the Federal Reserve System, the National Bureau of Economic Research, or the National Science Foundation. I would like to thank Steven Durlauf and Jeffrey Fuhrer for extremely helpful comments and suggestions. Some of this work was completed while I was visiting the Research Department at the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston; I would like to thank the Bank and its staff for their hospitality and support.
  • Nber Working Paper Series Monetary Policy in a World

    Nber Working Paper Series Monetary Policy in a World

    NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MONETARY POLICY IN A WORLD WITHOUT MONEY Michael Woodford Working Paper 7853 http://www.nber.org/papers/w7853 NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH 1050 Massachusetts Avenue Cambridge, MA 02138 August 2000 Prepared for a conference on "The Future of Monetary Policy", held at the World Bank on July 11, 2000. The paper was written during my tenure as Professorial Fellow in Monetary Economics at the Reserve Bank of New Zealand and Victoria University of Wellington, and I thank both institutions for their hospitality and assistance. I would also like to thank David Archer, Bany Bosworth, Roger Bowden, Andy Brookes, Kevin Clinton, Ben Friedman, Arthur Grimes, Bruce White, and Julian Wright for helpful discussions, Tim Hampton for providing me with New Zealand data, and Gauti Eggertsson for research assistance. Opinions expressed here should not be construed as those of The Reserve Bank of New Zealand or the National Bureau of Economic Research. 2000 by Michael Woodford. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, includingnotice, is given to the source. Monetary Policy in a World Without Money Michael Woodford NBER Working Paper No. 7853 August 2000 JEL No. E42, E52, E58 ABSTRACT This paper considers whether the development of "electronic money" poses any threat to the ability of central banks to control the value of their national currencies through conventional monetary policy. It argues that even if the demand for base money for use in facilitating transactions is largely or even completely eliminated, monetary policy should continue to be effective.
  • Sovereign Investor Models: Institutions and Policies for Managing Sovereign Wealth

    Sovereign Investor Models: Institutions and Policies for Managing Sovereign Wealth

    Sovereign investor models: Institutions and policies for managing sovereign wealth Khalid A. Alsweilem Angela Cummine Malan Rietveld Katherine Tweedie Sovereign investor models: Institutions and policies for managing sovereign wealth Khalid A. Alsweilem The Belfer Center for Science and International Affairs Harvard Kennedy School Angela Cummine British Academy Post-doctoral Fellow University of Oxford Malan Rietveld Investec Investment Institute & The Center for International Development Harvard Kennedy School Katherine Tweedie Investec Investment Institute A joint report by The Center for International Development Harvard Kennedy School The Belfer Center for Science and International Affairs Harvard Kennedy School Sovereign investor models Background and acknowledgements Background This research features the insights of experts from a number of the world’s leading universities, former policymakers, and investment professionals. The report is the result of collaboration between two centers at Harvard Kennedy School: the Belfer Center for Science and International Affairs and the Center for International Development (CID). Dr. Khalid Alsweilem, the former Chief Counselor and Director General of Investment at the Saudi Arabian Monetary Agency (SAMA), joined the Belfer Center as a Fellow in 2013 to conduct research on sovereign wealth funds, with a particular focus on the management of Saudi Arabia’s reserves and their links to the real economy. He is one of the longest serving and most successful sovereign investment practitioners, having held senior investment positions at SAMA for over two decades. Malan Rietveld and Angela Cummine are sovereign wealth fund experts and have conducted doctoral research on the topic at Columbia University and the University of Oxford, respectively. Katherine Tweedie has led the Investec Investment Institute’s collaboration with CID, supporting Professor Ricardo Hausmann and his team’s groundbreaking research on the role of productive knowledge as a primary driver of economic growth.
  • German Monetary History in the First Half of the Twentieth Century

    German Monetary History in the First Half of the Twentieth Century

    CORE Metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk Provided by Research Papers in Economics German Monetary History in the First Half of the Twentieth Century Robert L. Hetzel t the end of 1998, the German Bundesbank turned over the adminis- tration of monetary policy to the European Central Bank (ECB). In Athe years between World War I and 1998, the Bundesbank had come to embody the modern central bank. What history did Germany traverse to make possible the creation of such an institution? And how does that history help us define a modern central bank? Today, a central bank chooses one of two objectives. It may target either the exchange rate or domestic economic conditions, including the inflation rate. In either case, the central bank is the unique institution charged with controlling the chosen objective. Such control relies exclusively on the central bank’s management of its own balance sheet. In particular, the central bank controls its liabilities (the monetary base) through its asset acquisition.1 Conversely, a country with a modern central bank does not rely on govern- ment intervention in specific markets to achieve either price-level or exchange- rate objectives. If the central bank targets the exchange rate, the country does not rely on exchange controls, multiple exchange rates, tariffs, quotas, or other This history will be continued in a related article, to appear in a future issue of the Economic Quarterly. It will consider how Germany came to define stability of the mark in terms of its internal value (price level) rather than external value (exchange rate).
  • Government Wealth Funds and Monetary Policy

    Government Wealth Funds and Monetary Policy

    Government Wealth Funds and Monetary Policy By Sergey Sinelnikov-Murylev Dr. Sci. (Econ.), Professor, Rector of the Russian Foreign Trade Economy (e-mail: [email protected]) +7 (499) 143-1235 Pavel Trunin Cand. Sci. (Econ.), Leading Researcher, Center for Study of Central Banks’ Issues, Russian Presidential Academy of National Economy and Public Administration (e-mail: [email protected]) +7 (495) 629-8231 Moscow 2016 1 Abstract Both economic theory and economic practice reveal a high degree of interdependence between fiscal and monetary policies. This relationship is especially evident if the government accumulates a considerable amount of money in its accounts with the central bank. The article analyzes the impact of the formation and spending of the Reserve Fund and the National Wealth Fund on the monetary policy of the Bank of Russia. This effect is considered from the point of view of the current economic crisis and the need to spend resources accumulated in sovereign wealth funds. Key words: fiscal policy, monetary policy, sovereign wealth funds, forex interventions, international reserves. JEL classification: E43, E520, E620, E630 2 The creation, in 2004, of the Stabilization Fund, later to be reorganized into the Reserve Fund and the National Wealth Fund, was a major evolutionary landmark not only in the fiscal policy, but also in the monetary policy pursued by the Russian authorities. It should be reminded in this connection that for the greater part of the 2000s, right until the 2008 crisis, the Bank of Russia had maintained the ruble's exchange rate against major world currencies at a fixed level, resorting to substantial forex interventions in the foreign exchange market in order to sustain a positive balance of payments and prevent the ruble's strengthening in nominal terms.
  • An Alternative for the European Money Market

    An Alternative for the European Money Market

    An Alternative for the European Money Market Witold Rutkowski, Higher School of Economics and Arts in Skierniewice This paper concerns an alternative of monetary policy operational framework for the newly created European Central Bank (ECB). Composed of 12 central banks (many of them with an outstanding prestige) it must create the new quality as the emerging single central bank of the large monetary union. The most important question the Eurosystem should answer is what should be the targeted structure of the European money market? To detain its insider bank-based structure or to change it into market-based outsider structure? For an answer to such a question we should remember that the Eurosystem issues the currency that might challenge the dollar in the future what may increase a demand for the euro. In the wake of coming enlargement the Bank of England might play in such a market the special role. The first part concerns the most important feature of a central bank, which even such a particular central bank as the ECB should remember and to take into consideration while analysing the efficiency of its monetary operations. The second part concerns the comparisons with the Federal Reserve System and the third part concerns the prospective enlargement of the euro’s zone. JEL Classifications: F36, E58, G21, G10, D40, E43, E50. The main feature of central banking A central bank derives the power to determine specific interest rates from the fact that it is monopoly supplier of ‘high-powered’ money, which is also known as ‘base money’1. This principle and as well operating procedures are common for many central banks, however institutional details differ slightly from country to country.