Cost Push and Demand Pull Inflation

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Cost Push and Demand Pull Inflation Cost push and demand pull inflation This revision note considers two of the main causes of inflation – namely cost-push and demand- pull factors. It is designed for AS economists preparing for Unit 2 but is also useful revision for students revising for unit 6. Inflation is a sustained increase in the general price level leading to a fall in the purchasing power of money. Inflationary pressures can come from domestic and external sources and from both the supply and demand side of the economy. Cost push inflation Inflation LRAS P2 P1 SRAS2 SRAS1 AD1 Y2 Y1 Yfc Real National Income Cost-push inflation occurs when businesses respond to rising costs, by increasing their prices to protect profit margins. There are many reasons why costs might rise: 1. Component costs: e.g. an increase in the prices of raw materials and components. This might be because of a rise in global commodity prices such as oil, gas copper and agricultural products used in food processing – a good recent example is the surge in the world price of wheat. 2. Rising labour costs - caused by wage increases that exceed improvements in productivity. Wage and salary costs often rise when unemployment is low (creating labour shortages) and when people expect inflation so they bid for higher pay in order to protect their real incomes. 3. Higher indirect taxes imposed by the government – for example a rise in the duty on alcohol, cigarettes and petrol/diesel or a rise in the standard rate of Value Added Tax. Depending on the price elasticity of demand and supply, suppliers may pass on the burden of the tax onto consumers. 4. A fall in the exchange rate – this can cause cost push inflation because it normally leads to an increase in the prices of imported products. For example during 2007-08 the pound fell heavily against the Euro leading to a jump in the prices of imported materials from Euro Zone countries. Cost-push inflation can be illustrated by an inward shift of the short run aggregate supply curve. The fall in SRAS causes a contraction of GDP together with a rise in the level of prices. One of the risks of cost-push inflation is that it can lead to stagflation. Important note: Many of the causes of cost-push inflation come from external economic shocks – e.g. unexpected volatility in the prices of internationally traded commodities and large-scale movements in variables such as the exchange rate. A country can also import cost-push inflation from another country that is suffering from rising inflation of its own. Demand pull inflation Demand pull inflation occurs when aggregate demand and output is growing at an unsustainable rate leading to increased pressure on scarce resources and a positive output gap. When there is excess demand in the economy, producers are able to raise prices and achieve bigger profit margins because they know that demand is running ahead of supply. Typically, demand-pull inflation becomes a threat when an economy has experienced a strong boom with GDP rising faster than the long run trend growth of potential GDP. The last time this happened to any great extent in the UK economy was in the late 1980s. Demand pull inflation can be shown in a diagram such as the one below. Inflation LRAS P2 P1 AD2 SRAS AD1 Y1 Y2Y fc Real National Income Possible causes of demand pull inflation 1. A depreciation of the exchange rate which makes exports more competitive in overseas markets leading to an injection of fresh demand into the circular flow and a rise in national and demand for factor resources – there may also be a positive multiplier effect on the level of demand and output arising from the initial boost to export sales. 2. Higher demand from a government (fiscal) stimulus e.g. via a reduction in direct or indirect taxation or higher government spending and borrowing. If direct taxes are reduced, consumers will have more disposable income causing demand to rise. Higher government spending and increased borrowing feeds through directly into extra demand in the circular flow. 3. Monetary stimulus to the economy: A fall in interest rates may stimulate too much demand – for example in raising demand for loans or in causing rise in house price inflation. 4. Faster economic growth in other countries – providing a boost to UK exports overseas. 5. Improved business confidence which prompts firms to raise prices and achieve better profit margins Demand pull inflation is most likely to occur when an economy is becoming stretched and is said to be danger of over-heating. This is often seen towards the end of a boom when output is expanding beyond the economy’s usual capacity to supply, the result being higher prices and also a larger trade deficit (imports act as a kind of safety valve to take away some of the excess AD). The Output Gap and Consumer Price Inflation Output Gap = Actual GDP - Potential GDP. CPI inflation - annual % change in prices 9 9 8 8 Excess demand in the economy 7 7 6 6 5 Excess supply in a recession 5 4 4 3 3 Inflation 2 2 Per cent Per 1 1 0 0 -1 -1 -2 -2 Output gap -3 -3 -4 -4 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 Source: Reuters EcoWin What should we look out for as evidence for cost-push and demand-pull inflation? Cost-push inflation 1. The rate at which wages and salaries are rising 2. Data on producer prices and input costs such as the prices of raw materials 3. Trends in international commodity prices 4. The effects of changes in indirect taxes on prices Demand-pull inflation 1. How fast is aggregate demand growing (and the component parts I.e. C+I+G+X-M) 2. Estimated size of the output gap 3. Profitability of businesses in different sectors of the economy 4. Growth of the money supply and credit / consumer borrowing 5. Trends in the values of assets such as property prices 6. Indicators of consumer and business confidence 7. Whether a firm’s prices are rising faster than their costs (tells you what is happening to profit margins) Economic Growth, Inflation and Oil Prices Input Costs and Manufacturing Producer Prices UK Real GDP Growth and CPI Inflation. annual percentage change, Brent Crude $s per barrel Annual percentage change, seasonally adjusted 110 110 22.0 22.0 100 100 90 90 20.0 20.0 80 80 el 18.0 18.0 r Brent Crude Oil Price $s r 70 70 Ba / 60 60 16.0 16.0 50 50 USD 40 40 14.0 14.0 30 30 20 20 12.0 12.0 10 10 10.0 10.0 9 9 Imported materials 8 Percent 8.0 8.0 7 7 6.0 6.0 Real GDP growth 6 5 5 4 4.0 4.0 3 3 2.0 2.0 Percent 2 1 1 Manufactured goods 0 0.0 0.0 -1 Consumer price inflation -1 -2.0 -2.0 -2 Imported foods -3 -3 -4.0 -4.0 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 Jan May Sep Jan May Sep Jan May Sep Jan May Sep Jan May Sep Jan 03 04 05 06 07 08 Source: Reuters EcoWin Source: Reuters EcoWin Check your understanding Online multiple choice test on inflation http://vle.tutor2u.net/mod/quiz/view.php?id=1476 .
Recommended publications
  • Microeconomics Exam Review Chapters 8 Through 12, 16, 17 and 19
    MICROECONOMICS EXAM REVIEW CHAPTERS 8 THROUGH 12, 16, 17 AND 19 Key Terms and Concepts to Know CHAPTER 8 - PERFECT COMPETITION I. An Introduction to Perfect Competition A. Perfectly Competitive Market Structure: • Has many buyers and sellers. • Sells a commodity or standardized product. • Has buyers and sellers who are fully informed. • Has firms and resources that are freely mobile. • Perfectly competitive firm is a price taker; one firm has no control over price. B. Demand Under Perfect Competition: Horizontal line at the market price II. Short-Run Profit Maximization A. Total Revenue Minus Total Cost: The firm maximizes economic profit by finding the quantity at which total revenue exceeds total cost by the greatest amount. B. Marginal Revenue Equals Marginal Cost in Equilibrium • Marginal Revenue: The change in total revenue from selling another unit of output: • MR = ΔTR/Δq • In perfect competition, marginal revenue equals market price. • Market price = Marginal revenue = Average revenue • The firm increases output as long as marginal revenue exceeds marginal cost. • Golden rule of profit maximization. The firm maximizes profit by producing where marginal cost equals marginal revenue. C. Economic Profit in Short-Run: Because the marginal revenue curve is horizontal at the market price, it is also the firm’s demand curve. The firm can sell any quantity at this price. III. Minimizing Short-Run Losses The short run is defined as a period too short to allow existing firms to leave the industry. The following is a summary of short-run behavior: A. Fixed Costs and Minimizing Losses: If a firm shuts down, it must still pay fixed costs.
    [Show full text]
  • Marxist Economics: How Capitalism Works, and How It Doesn't
    MARXIST ECONOMICS: HOW CAPITALISM WORKS, ANO HOW IT DOESN'T 49 Another reason, however, was that he wanted to show how the appear- ance of "equal exchange" of commodities in the market camouflaged ~ , inequality and exploitation. At its most superficial level, capitalism can ' V be described as a system in which production of commodities for the market becomes the dominant form. The problem for most economic analyses is that they don't get beyond th?s level. C~apter Four Commodities, Marx argued, have a dual character, having both "use value" and "exchange value." Like all products of human labor, they have Marxist Economics: use values, that is, they possess some useful quality for the individual or society in question. The commodity could be something that could be directly consumed, like food, or it could be a tool, like a spear or a ham­ How Capitalism Works, mer. A commodity must be useful to some potential buyer-it must have use value-or it cannot be sold. Yet it also has an exchange value, that is, and How It Doesn't it can exchange for other commodities in particular proportions. Com­ modities, however, are clearly not exchanged according to their degree of usefulness. On a scale of survival, food is more important than cars, but or most people, economics is a mystery better left unsolved. Econo­ that's not how their relative prices are set. Nor is weight a measure. I can't mists are viewed alternatively as geniuses or snake oil salesmen. exchange a pound of wheat for a pound of silver.
    [Show full text]
  • Demand Composition and the Strength of Recoveries†
    Demand Composition and the Strength of Recoveriesy Martin Beraja Christian K. Wolf MIT & NBER MIT & NBER September 17, 2021 Abstract: We argue that recoveries from demand-driven recessions with ex- penditure cuts concentrated in services or non-durables will tend to be weaker than recoveries from recessions more biased towards durables. Intuitively, the smaller the bias towards more durable goods, the less the recovery is buffeted by pent-up demand. We show that, in a standard multi-sector business-cycle model, this prediction holds if and only if, following an aggregate demand shock to all categories of spending (e.g., a monetary shock), expenditure on more durable goods reverts back faster. This testable condition receives ample support in U.S. data. We then use (i) a semi-structural shift-share and (ii) a structural model to quantify this effect of varying demand composition on recovery dynamics, and find it to be large. We also discuss implications for optimal stabilization policy. Keywords: durables, services, demand recessions, pent-up demand, shift-share design, recov- ery dynamics, COVID-19. JEL codes: E32, E52 yEmail: [email protected] and [email protected]. We received helpful comments from George-Marios Angeletos, Gadi Barlevy, Florin Bilbiie, Ricardo Caballero, Lawrence Christiano, Martin Eichenbaum, Fran¸coisGourio, Basile Grassi, Erik Hurst, Greg Kaplan, Andrea Lanteri, Jennifer La'O, Alisdair McKay, Simon Mongey, Ernesto Pasten, Matt Rognlie, Alp Simsek, Ludwig Straub, Silvana Tenreyro, Nicholas Tra- chter, Gianluca Violante, Iv´anWerning, Johannes Wieland (our discussant), Tom Winberry, Nathan Zorzi and seminar participants at various venues, and we thank Isabel Di Tella for outstanding research assistance.
    [Show full text]
  • Chapter 9 Keynesian Models of Aggregate Demand
    Economics 314 Coursebook, 2010 Jeffrey Parker 9 KEYNESIAN MODELS OF AGGREGATE DEMAND Chapter 9 Contents A. Topics and Tools ............................................................................ 2 B. Comparative-Static Analysis of the Closed-Economy Basic Keynesian Model 3 Expenditure equilibrium and the IS curve ....................................................................... 4 Expenditures and the IS curve ....................................................................................... 5 Money demand and monetary policy.............................................................................. 7 The LM curve .............................................................................................................. 8 The MP curve .............................................................................................................. 9 Aggregate demand and aggregate supply ......................................................................... 9 C. Some Simple Aggregate-Supply Models ............................................... 10 Case 1: Nominal-wage stickiness .................................................................................. 11 Case 2: Inflation stickiness with competitive labor market ............................................... 12 Case 3: Inflation stickiness with labor-market imperfections ............................................ 13 Case 4: Sticky wages with imperfect competition ............................................................ 13 D. The Open Economy .......................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Introduction to Macroeconomics TOPIC 2: the Goods Market
    Introduction to Macroeconomics TOPIC 2: The Goods Market Anna¨ıgMorin CBS - Department of Economics August 2013 Introduction to Macroeconomics TOPIC 2: Goods market, IS curve Goods market Road map: 1. Demand for goods 1.1. Components 1.1.1. Consumption 1.1.2. Investment 1.1.3. Government spending 2. Equilibrium in the goods market 3. Changes of the equilibrium Introduction to Macroeconomics TOPIC 2: Goods market, IS curve 1.1. Demand for goods - Components What are the main component of the demand for domestically produced goods? Consumption C: all goods and services purchased by consumers Investment I: purchase of new capital goods by firms or households (machines, buildings, houses..) (6= financial investment) Government spending G: all goods and services purchased by federal, state and local governments Exports X: all goods and services purchased by foreign agents - Imports M: demand for foreign goods and services should be subtracted from the 3 first elements Introduction to Macroeconomics TOPIC 2: Goods market, IS curve 1.1. Demand for goods - Components Demand for goods = Z ≡ C + I + G + X − M This equation is an identity. We have this relation by definition. Introduction to Macroeconomics TOPIC 2: Goods market, IS curve 1.1. Demand for goods - Components Assumption 1: we are in closed economy: X=M=0 (we will relax it later on) Demand for goods = Z ≡ C + I + G Introduction to Macroeconomics TOPIC 2: Goods market, IS curve 1.1.1. Demand for goods - Consumption Consumption: Consumption increases with the disposable income YD = Y − T Reasonable assumption: C = c0 + c1YD the parameter c0 represents what people would consume if their disposable income were equal to zero.
    [Show full text]
  • Inflation in Developing Asia: Demand-Pull Or Cost-Push?
    About the Paper Juthathip Jongwanich and Donghyun Park empirically examine the sources of inflation in developing Asia. They find that the region’s current inflation surge ECONOMICS AND RESEARCH DEPARTMENT is largely homegrown and due to excess aggregate demand and inflation expectations, rather than external commodity price shocks. This suggests that the region can and should use monetary policy decisively and preemptively to tame inflation before it becomes entrenched and harms long-term growth. About the Asian Development Bank ADB’s vision is an Asia and Pacific region free of poverty. Its mission is to help its developing member countries substantially reduce poverty and improve the quality of life of their people. Despite the region’s many successes, it remains home to two thirds of the world’s poor. Nearly 1.7 billion people in the region live on $2 or less ERD WORKING PAper SerIes NO. 121 a day. ADB is committed to reducing poverty through inclusive economic growth, environmentally sustainable growth, and regional integration. Based in Manila, ADB is owned by 67 members, including 48 from the region. Its main instruments for helping its developing member countries are policy dialogue, loans, equity investments, guarantees, grants, and technical assistance. In 2007, it approved $10.1 billion of loans, $673 million of grant projects, and technical assistance amounting to $243 million. Inflation in Developing Asia: Demand-Pull or Cost-Push? Juthathip Jongwanich and Donghyun Park September 2008 Asian Development Bank 6 ADB Avenue, Mandaluyong City 1550 Metro Manila, Philippines www.adb.org/economics ISSN: 1655-5252 Publication Stock No. Printed in the Philippines ERD Working Paper No.
    [Show full text]
  • Demand Flexibility
    O BO Y M UN AR N K T C C A I O N R DEMAND FLEXIBILITY I W N E A M THE KEY TO ENABLING A LOW-COST, LOW-CARBON GRID STIT U T R R O O FURTHER, FASTER, TOGETHER INSIGHT BRIEF February, 2018 IIIIIIIIII HIGHLIGHTS Cara Goldenberg • Wind and solar energy costs are at record lows and are forecast to keep falling, leading to New York, NY greater adoption, but the mismatch of weather-driven resources and electricity demand can [email protected] lead to lower revenues and higher risks of curtailment for renewable energy projects, potentially inhibiting new project investment. Mark Dyson • Using an hourly simulation of a future, highly-renewable Texas power system, we show how Boulder, CO using demand flexibility in eight common end-use loads to shift demand into periods of high [email protected] renewable availability can increase the value of renewable generation, raising revenues by 36% compared to a system with inflexible demand. Harry Masters • Flexible demand of this magnitude could reduce renewable curtailment by 40%, lower peak demand net of renewables by 24%, and lower the average magnitude of multihour ramps (e.g., the “duck curve”) by 56%. • Demand flexibility is cost-effective when compared with new gas-fired generation to balance renewables, avoiding approximately $1.9 billion of annual generator costs and 20% of total annual CO2 emissions in the modeled system. • Policymakers, grid operators, and utility program designers need to incorporate demand flexibility as a core asset at all levels of system planning to unlock this value.
    [Show full text]
  • Ethics and Market Design
    Ethics and Market Design Shengwu Li∗ July 25, 2017 1 Introduction [. ] just as there is a chemical engineering literature (and not just literature about theoretical and laboratory chemistry) and a medical literature (and not just a biology literature), economists need to develop a scientific literature concerned with practical problems of design. (Roth and Peranson, 1999) It is, in fact, arguable that economics has had two rather different origins [. ] concerned respectively with `ethics' on the one hand, and with what may be called `engineering' on the other. (Sen, 1987) The word \market" often refers to a set of agents who seek to transact with each other. In this sense, the stock market consists of individuals and corporations seeking to buy and sell stocks, and the market for medical residents consists of doctors and hospitals. However, the word \market" can also refer to the rule-governed institution that facilitates these transactions. In this sense, a stock market is a platform, such as the New York Stock Exchange, that enables participants to find willing trading partners according to a set of common rules.1 Similarly, the market for medical residents in the United States consists of a clearinghouse, the National Resident Matching Program, that matches doctors to hospitals using a centralized algorithm that accounts for the preferences of both sides (Roth and Peranson, 1999). An institution that facilitates transactions can be designed - the rules affect who trades, what is traded, and the terms of those trades. Market design takes an engineering approach to the problem: It seeks to construct rules that facilitate trade and lead to good outcomes.
    [Show full text]
  • The Political Economy of Capitalism
    07-037 The Political Economy of Capitalism Bruce R. Scott Copyright © 2006 by Bruce R. Scott Working papers are in draft form. This working paper is distributed for purposes of comment and discussion only. It may not be reproduced without permission of the copyright holder. Copies of working papers are available from the author. #07-037 Abstract Capitalism is often defined as an economic system where private actors are allowed to own and control the use of property in accord with their own interests, and where the invisible hand of the pricing mechanism coordinates supply and demand in markets in a way that is automatically in the best interests of society. Government, in this perspective, is often described as responsible for peace, justice, and tolerable taxes. This paper defines capitalism as a system of indirect governance for economic relationships, where all markets exist within institutional frameworks that are provided by political authorities, i.e. governments. In this second perspective capitalism is a three level system much like any organized sports. Markets occupy the first level, where the competition takes place; the institutional foundations that underpin those markets are the second; and the political authority that administers the system is the third. While markets do indeed coordinate supply and demand with the help of the invisible hand in a short term, quasi-static perspective, government coordinates the modernization of market frameworks in accord with changing circumstances, including changing perceptions of societal costs and benefits. In this broader perspective government has two distinct roles, one to administer the existing institutional frameworks, including the provision of infrastructure and the administration of laws and regulations, and the second to mobilize political power to bring about modernization of those frameworks as circumstances and/or societal priorities change.
    [Show full text]
  • Microeconomics Definitions Microeconomics Is the Study of Individuals, Firms Or Markets
    Microeconomics Definitions microeconomics is the study of individuals, firms or markets. Macroeconomics is the study of a whole country's economy growth an increase in production or income over a period of time development an improvement in the quality of life for the majority of the population sustainable development development that doesn't leave future generations worse off positive something that can be objectively measured normative something that is subjective and has a value judgement ceteris paribus everything else remains equal (latin) land any raw material labour people paid to work capital something man-made used in production entrepreneur a person that combines the other resources in production rent the payment from land wage the payment for labour interest the payment from capital profit the payment to entrepreneurs utility a unit of happiness opportunity cost the difference between the best and next best alternatives free good one with no opportunity cost economic good one with an opportunity cost mixed economy one that combines the private and public sector public sector that owned by the government private sector that owned by private individuals planned economy one where what, how and for whom to produce is decided by the government market economy one where the free market decides what and how to produce transition economy one changing from planned to market economy market a place where buyers and sellers meet monopoly a market of one firm or dominated by one firm oligopoly a market dominated by a few firms monopolistic
    [Show full text]
  • The Economics of Demand Flexibility How “Flexiwatts” Create Quantifiable Value for Customers and the Grid
    M OUN KY T C A I O N R I N E STIT U T THE ECONOMICS OF DEMAND FLEXIBILITY HOW “FLEXIWATTS” CREATE QUANTIFIABLE VALUE FOR CUSTOMERS AND THE GRID 1820 FOLSOM STREET | BOULDER, CO 80302 | RMI.ORG PUBLISHED AUGUST 2015 COPYRIGHT ROCKY MOUNTAIN INSTITUTE. DOWNLOAD AT: WWW.RMI.ORG/ELECTRICITY_DEMAND_FLEXIBILITY AUTHORS ACKNOWLEDGMENTS Peter Bronski, Mark Dyson, Matt Lehrman, James Mandel, The authors thank the following individuals and Jesse Morris, Titiaan Palazzi, Sam Ramirez, Hervé Touati organizations for offering their insights and perspectives on this work: * Authors listed alphabetically. All authors from Rocky Mountain Institute unless otherwise noted. Pierre Bull, Natural Resources Defense Council Karen Crofton, Rocky Mountain Institute James Fine, Environmental Defense Fund CONTACTS Ellen Franconi, Rocky Mountain Institute William Greene, Nest Labs James Mandel ([email protected]) Leia Guccione, Rocky Mountain Institute Mark Dyson ([email protected]) Lena Hansen, Rocky Mountain Institute Ryan Hledik, The Brattle Group Marissa Hummon, Tendril SUGGESTED CITATION Ian Kelly, Rocky Mountain Institute Tom Key, Electric Power Research Institute Virginia Lacy, Rocky Mountain Institute Dyson, Mark, James Mandel, et al. The Economics of Jim Lazar, The Regulatory Assistance Project Demand Flexibility: How “flexiwatts” create quantifiable Amory Lovins, Rocky Mountain Institute value for customers and the grid. Rocky Mountain Institute, Farshad Samimi, Enphase Energy August 2015. <<http://www.rmi.org/electricity_demand_ Daniel Seif, The Butler Firm flexibility>> James Sherwood, Rocky Mountain Institute Owen Smith, Rocky Mountain Institute Eric Wanless, Rocky Mountain Institute Jon Wellinghoff, Stoel Rives Daniel Wetzel, Rocky Mountain Institute Hayes Zirnhelt, Rocky Mountain Institute Editorial Director: Peter Bronski Editor: Laurie Guevara-Stone Art Director: Romy Purshouse Designer: Mike Heighway Images courtesy of Thinkstock unless otherwise noted.
    [Show full text]
  • Capitalism Redefined Nick Hanauer, Remarks to the OECD, Paris, Oct 16, 2018
    Capitalism Redefined Nick Hanauer, remarks to the OECD, Paris, Oct 16, 2018 Thank you very much for having me here. My co-author Eric Beinhocker and I have been great admirers of the NAEC initiative from its beginnings. The questions NAEC are posing are essential ones, and the OECD’s willingness to challenge orthodoxy and stimulate new thinking is very heartening during these challenging times. The financial crash of 2008 and the cruelly unequal recovery that followed have sparked crises of faith in the three social technologies that define the modern world: democracy, science, and markets. And with human civilization rushing headlong toward a global climate catastrophe, the timing couldn’t be worse. Brexit, Trumpism, and other nationalist movements throughout the world are undermining the institutions and global cooperation necessary to address many global priorities including limiting greenhouse gas emissions, while in the United States, even the science of climate 1 change remains under assault. And while the financial markets may have recovered from their 2008 lows, market capitalism has not. The same policies and theories that crashed the global economy ten years ago are largely still in place. And while growth is back and unemployment is low across much of the Western world, a majority of households have not experienced those gains. A recent report by the U.S. Federal Reserve showed that the bottom 90 percent of the U.S. population are still poorer in real terms today than they were in 2007. Not just some or most, but all of the gains from the post-crash recovery have flowed to the top 10%.
    [Show full text]