II Facts on Existing Public Debt Structures

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

II Facts on Existing Public Debt Structures II Facts on Existing Public Debt Structures ublic debt in emerging market countries differs P in several respects from that in advanced Figure 1. Advanced Economies and Emerg- economies. First, average debt levels were tradition- ing Market Countries: Public Debt Stocks ally equivalent to a lower share of GDP in emerging and Debt Composition market countries than they were in advanced (In percent of GDP) economies; the gap has closed in recent years, partly as a result of reductions in the debt of advanced economies (Figure 1). Second, reliance on externally 85 Domestic and Foreign Debt Issued issued debt has been far greater in emerging market by Emerging Market Countries countries than in advanced economies. Third, while 75 the structure of external debt of emerging market Advanced economies3 countries is similar to that of advanced economies, 65 the structure of their domestic debt—in terms of ma- All emerging turity, currency composition, and the prevalence of markets2 1 55 indexed debt—is very different. Large emerging The remainder of the section reviews such differ- markets1 ences in greater detail, first, by considering external 45 1992 94 96 98 2000 02 and domestic debt separately and, second, by offer- ing a consolidated view. 100 Composition of Total Debt: Domestic Unweighted Average, 1992–2002 External 80 Public Debt in Emerging Market 60 Countries Versus Advanced Economies 40 Structure of International Debt The international sovereign debt of emerging mar- 20 ket countries consists mainly of medium-term and 0 long-term fixed-interest-rate bonds denominated in 1 All 2 Asia foreign currency. Bank loans used to be the main G-7 Large Latin Middle Transition America Emerging Emerging East Africaand form of financing during the 1970s and 1980s. A Markets Markets Economies stock conversion of loans into bonds took place through the Brady deals; this helps explain the drop Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook (September 2003); and IMF in loans, and rise in bonds, in the early 1990s (Figure staff estimates. 1Argentina, Brazil, Chile, China, Hungary, India, Indonesia, Israel, 2, first panel). When developing countries re-entered Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Philippines, Poland, Russia, South Africa, international credit markets in the 1990s, they did so Thailand,Turkey, and Venezuela. 2Countries listed in footnote 1 above plus Bulgaria, Colombia, mainly through bond issues (Figure 2, second Costa Rica, Côte d’Ivoire, Croatia, Ecuador, Egypt, Jordan, Lebanon, panel). The prevalence of bond financing is not Morocco, Nigeria, Pakistan, Panama, Peru, Ukraine, and Uruguay. unique to emerging market countries: its relative im- 3Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Netherlands, New Zealand, portance has grown even more sharply in advanced Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, United Kingdom, and United States. Note: The authors of this section are Marcos Chamon, Olivier Jeanne, and Jeromin Zettelmeyer. 1In this paper, “external” (or “international”) and “domestic” refer to the jurisdiction where the debt is issued. 7 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution II FACTS ON EXISTING PUBLIC DEBT STRUCTURES Figure 2. Structure of External Public Debt Figure 3. Emerging Market Countries: in Emerging Market Countries Fixed- Versus Floating-Rate Sovereign (In billions of U.S. dollars) Bond Issues (In billions of U.S. dollars) 350 Stocks of Privately Held Debt 300 100 Bonds 250 Fixed interest rate 80 200 Loans 150 60 100 50 40 0 1980 84 88 92 96 2000 Floating interest rate 20 120 New Issues 100 0 Bonds 1980 82 84 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 2000 02 80 Source: Capital Data, Bondware and Loanware. 60 40 Loans 20 advanced economies. The share of the EMBIG con- 0 1980 84 88 92 96 2000 03 sisting of debt with remaining maturities over 20 years declined from 40 percent in the mid-1990s to Sources:World Bank, Global Development Finance (2003); Capital about 20 percent by the end of 1999, and has stabi- Data, Bondware and Loanware. lized since then (Figure 4, top panel). The decline stems from two factors. First, the 30-year bonds is- sued through the Brady deals are gradually becom- ing less important in the stock of emerging market countries’ debt as new debt is issued. Second, ex- economies, where virtually all international borrow- cluding the Brady bonds, the average maturity of ing is through bonds. new emerging market countries’ bond and loan is- Most internationally issued public debt carries a sues is significantly lower than for advanced fixed interest rate—for both advanced economies and economies, and has declined substantially over the emerging market countries. Much of the emerging past two decades (Figure 4, bottom panel).2 market debt issued in the 1970s and 1980s had a Most sovereign debt issued internationally by both floating rate. Certain types of Brady bonds also had a emerging market countries and advanced economies floating rate, and the proportion of floating-rate is in foreign currency (Table 1). Only a handful of bonds was relatively high until the mid-1990s: in advanced economies issue a substantial share of 1994, about 40 percent of JPMorgan’s Emerging their international sovereign debt in their own cur- Markets Bond Index Global (EMBIG) carried a float- rency. This does not imply that governments in ing rate. As new bond issues began to take off in the emerging market countries and advanced economies mid-1990s and emerging markets moved from bank face the same constraints in the international debt loans to bond financing; they also moved from market. Indeed, some advanced economies issue floating-rate to fixed-rate instruments (Figure 3). local-currency debt in their home markets and attract Currently, floating-rate bonds make up less than 5 international investors to purchase it there. percent of the EMBIG. Most international sovereign debt of emerging market countries is issued at medium-term (5–10 2Certain types of short-term debt that have been widely cited as a source of fragility in some recent crises, such as the Mexican years) or longer-term maturities. However, the aver- Tesobonos in 1994 and the Russian GKOs in 1998, were issued age maturity of emerging market countries’ debt has domestically and, hence, were not international debt in the sense declined in recent years, and is now lower than for used here. 8 ©International Monetary Fund. Not for Redistribution Public Debt in Emerging Market Countries Versus Advanced Economies short-term fixed-rate, floating-rate (indexed to a do- Figure 4. Structure of Internationally Issued mestic rate), inflation-indexed, and foreign-currency. Debt: Maturity Composition Each of the first four categories represents more than one-half of total debt in at least one country. There is also significant heterogeneity within regions. In Asia, >20 years 10–20 years 5–10 years <5 years for example, some issuers (Indonesia and Malaysia) 160 do not make use of long-term local-currency debt Emerging Market Countries: whereas other issuers (India, Taiwan Province of Remaining Maturity Structure China) rely almost exclusively on this form of debt. 120 of the EMBIG1 (In percent) In Latin America, some countries (Venezuela) borrow mainly through interest-rate-indexed debt, whereas in 80 others (Chile) the majority of government debt is in- dexed to inflation. 40 A Consolidated View 0 1994 96 98 2000 02 Domestic and international debt markets are sub- stitute sources of finance and should be considered 14 jointly. International and domestic debt markets have Average Maturity at Issue become integrated, with residents and nonresidents of Sovereign Debt Issues 12 (In years) being active in both. For example, in both Argentina and Uruguay, more than half of the international Advanced economies 10 debt was held by residents. Conversely, foreign resi- dents held more than 80 percent of Mexican domes- 8 tically issued Tesobonos and Cetes before the 1994 crisis (IMF, 1995) and a large share of Russian 6 GKOs and OFZs issued before the 1998 crisis (about Emerging market countries 30 percent, according to IMF staff estimates). Sover- 4 eigns seem able to choose whether to tap interna- 1980 84 88 92 96 2000 02 tional debt markets or domestic debt markets. In ad- Sources: JPMorgan, Emerging Market Bond Index Global dition to market conditions, this choice depends on (EMBIG); Capital Data, Bondware and Loanware. two sets of considerations. First, domestic public 1Percentages in first three years do not add up to 100 because debt is likely to crowd out financing to the domestic of instruments with unknown remaining maturity. private sector, because some firms may be con- strained to the domestic credit market owing to high costs of borrowing abroad. Second, international in- vestors are less protected in domestic jurisdictions. Structure of Domestic Debt Obtaining an integrated picture of debt structure that includes both domestic and international debt is The composition of government debt issued on difficult owing to data limitations, especially for do- the domestic market is much more heterogeneous mestic debt. Since the 1994 Mexican crisis, the in- across countries than is the composition of debt is- ternational community has made an effort to im- sued internationally. While there are differences be- prove the availability of cross-country statistics.3 tween emerging market countries and advanced This effort has focused primarily on external debt, in economies, these are overwhelmed by differences spite of the important role played by domestic debt among emerging markets. On average, emerging in several recent emerging market crises (Mexico in market countries rely on long-term local-currency 1994; Russia in 1998; and Brazil in 1998). Neverthe- debt to a lesser extent than do advanced economies, less, it is possible to establish some basic stylized but there is substantial variation among emerging facts on total (domestic plus international) govern- markets: such debt is virtually absent in Latin Amer- ment debt.
Recommended publications
  • Your Ultimate Guide to Debt Consolidation Table of Contents
    Your ultimate guide to debt consolidation Table of contents 1 What is debt consolidation? 2 The benefits of debt consolidation 3 Are you a good candidate for debt consolidation? 4 The best types of debt to consolidate 5 Types of debt consolidation loans 6 Conclusion What is debt consolidation? Before you decide whether debt consolidation is the right option for you, let’s cover the basics. Debt consolidation combines some or all of your debt into a single debt obligation. It’s beneficial if you have substantial debt or are paying high interest rates. Often, these types of debt include: Credit cards Medical bills Car payments Payday loans Here’s how it works First, you’ll use your debt consolidation loan to pay off this high-interest debt. Then, you’ll make fixed monthly payments toward a new loan — typically at a much lower interest rate. As a result, debt consolidation makes managing your finances easier and less stressful. The benefits of debt consolidation Consolidating debt offers plenty of benefits. While each person’s situation is unique, here are the most common benefits that can come from consolidating debt: A defined timeline 1 Unsecured debt often has no timeline for an eventual payoff, which can cause a lot of stress. One of the benefits of consolidating your debt is a structured timeline with a clear endpoint for when you’ll pay off your debt in full. A single monthly payment 2 Juggling multiple monthly payments is stressful. By combining your debt, you’re effectively paying off all your creditors, leaving you with one manageable monthly payment.
    [Show full text]
  • Dynamics of Secured and Unsecured Debt Over the Business Cycle
    Dynamics of Secured and Unsecured Debt Over the Business Cycle Paul Luk∗ Tianxiao Zheng y Abstract Firms have heterogeneous debt structure. High-credit-quality firms rely almost ex- clusively on unsecured debt and borrow with lower leverage ratios than low-credit-quality firms. In this paper, we develop a tractable macroeconomic model featuring debt heterogeneity. Unse- cured credit rests on the value that borrowers attach to a good credit track record. We argue that borrowers and lenders are more cautious in the unsecured debt market, so high-credit-quality firms have lower leverage ratios. Moreover, our model generates procyclical unsecured debt and acyclical secured debt, consistent with the US data. Our model with heterogeneous debt has a smaller amplification effect than a model featuring secured debt only. JEL Codes: E32, E44, G32 Key Words: Secured debt, unsecured debt, corporate debt structure, financial accelerator ∗Department of Economics, Hong Kong Baptist University, The Wing Lung Bank Building for Business Studies, 34 Renfrew Road, Kowloon Tong, Hong Kong, China. E-mail: [email protected] yShanghai Advanced Institute of Finance, Shanghai Jiao Tong University, 211 West Huaihai Road, Shanghai 200030, China. E-mail: [email protected] 1 1. Introduction Standard macro-finance models (such as Bernanke, Gertler and Gilchrist(1999), Carlstrom and Fuerst(1997), Gertler and Karadi(2011), Jermann and Quadrini(2012) and Meh and Moran (2010)) often assume that capital structure is uniform and that all firms borrow with identical debt contract and leverage. This is despite the fact that debt heterogeneity is a common feature of both theoretical research and the real world.
    [Show full text]
  • How Does Access to the Unsecured Debt Market Affect Investment? Kizkitza Biguri†
    ADEMU WORKING PAPER SERIES How does access to the unsecured debt market affect investment? Kizkitza Biguri† September 2016 WP 2016/041 www.ademu-project.eu/publications/working-papers Abstract This paper examines the relation between debt structure and investment, by exploiting differences in secured and unsecured debt holdings. In order to address endogeneity concerns, I exploit two sources of exogenous variation for identification. From the firms' side, the Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2003 represents a negative shock to firms' creditworthiness. From the credit market's perspective, the asset-backed commercial paper market collapse of 2007 caused a temporary shortage of unsecured commercial paper. Each of these shocks to debt structure is analyzed combining a difference-in-differences approach with an instrumental variable estimation (Waldinger (2010)), which allows studying i) substitution patterns among debt types and ii) the impact on investment. Results show that greater access to unsecured debt leads to larger investment. When firms face more restricted access to the unsecured debt market, they substitute toward secured debt, and reduce investment. The reason behind this result is that unsecured debt is more cost-effective in terms of spreads and covenants. These findings suggest that collateral is not key to finance investment, as instead has often been claimed in the literature. Creditworthiness rather than collateral is key to access unsecured debt. Additionally, I shed light on how access to the unsecured debt market relates to the balance sheet and credit channels of monetary policy. _________________________ † BI Norwegian Business School. Email: [email protected] Keywords: Unsecured debt, debt structure, financial constraints, investment, collateral.
    [Show full text]
  • Debt Securities Product Overview Brochure
    Debt Product Overview We make home possible. In 1970, Congress chartered Freddie Mac to fulfill a public mission — to stabilize the nation’s mortgage markets and expand opportunities for homeownership and affordable rental housing. Since then, we’ve financed homes for more than 50 million American homebuyers. Freddie Mac doesn’t make mortgage loans directly to homebuyers. Instead, we make it possible for primary market mortgage lenders — such as commercial banks, mortgage companies and savings institutions — to make mortgage loans to homebuyers by creating a constant flow of funds that lenders can use to finance mortgages. Investors play an important role in this process. Investing in the U.S. Housing Market When a homebuyer obtains a mortgage loan from a primary market mortgage lender, the lender may sell that loan in the secondary mortgage market. The lender then uses the proceeds of that sale to make new loans to other homebuyers. As a leader in the secondary mortgage market, Freddie Mac is one of the largest buyers of mortgage loans in the United States. We purchase mortgages that meet our underwriting and product standards, then bundle them into mortgage-backed securities that can be sold to investors around the world. We then use the proceeds to purchase additional mortgages from primary market mortgage lenders. This provides a continuous flow of funds to primary market mortgage lenders, enabling them to originate new mortgage loans and, ultimately, to make the lending process faster, more convenient and more affordable for homebuyers. At times, Freddie Mac also purchases mortgage loans and mortgage- related securities for our investment portfolio, which enables us to fulfill our housing mission.
    [Show full text]
  • Covered Bonds As a Source of Funding for Banks' Mortgage Portfolios
    COVERED BONDS AS A SOUrcE OF Funding FOR BaNKS’ MORTGAge PORTFOLIOS BANK OF CANADA • FinANCIAL SYSTEM REView • JUNE 2018 37 Covered Bonds as a Source of Funding for Banks’ Mortgage Portfolios Toni Ahnert Covered bonds funded only about 3 per cent of the assets of the largest banks and 9 per cent of Canadian mortgages in 2017. Instead, banks have been relying primarily on relatively cheap government-guaranteed mortgage funding options. An increasing portion of mortgages are uninsured and not eligible for government-guaranteed funding, creating the need for alternative funding sources. Covered bonds may fill part of this need, helping to generate a diversified and stable funding mix for mortgages. Overcollateralization requirements and dynamic replenishment of the col- lateral pool can increase risks to unsecured creditors. This could add to the fragility of a bank in the face of negative shocks, with potential spill- overs to other parts of the financial system. Several policy tools are available to help balance the costs and benefits of covered bonds. These include simple issuance caps and adjustments to the pricing of deposit insurance premiums, as well as other types of prudential regulation. Introduction Banks’ choices for funding mortgages and other business activities have an important effect on how efficiently they provide banking services and how effectively they manage risks to their own business and to the financial system. Canadian banks typically use a broad array of funding sources, including equity, deposits and wholesale funding instruments (Chart 1).1 The terms of funding sources differ, ranging from short-term deposits and money market instruments to longer-term funding, including covered bonds and 5- and 10-year debentures.
    [Show full text]
  • The Global Securitized Debt Market Opportunities Often Reside in the Debris of Crisis
    Brandywine Global Investment Management, LLC Topical Insight | May 23, 2014 The Global Securitized Debt Market Opportunities Often Reside in the Debris of Crisis New issuance of private-label securitizations remains at nearly non-existent levels today despite more than five years of improving investor risk appetite since the Financial Crisis. While other spread- product markets reclaimed considerable new issuance momentum shortly after 2008, many investors today are still scarred from the miserable failures of private-label securitization during the housing crisis. Convolutedly packaged collateralized debt obligations (CDOs), backed by poorly underwritten subprime collateral, not only delivered steep price declines during the Financial Crisis, but market liquidity dried up quickly which impeded investors from exiting positions at reasonable valuations. Despite recent price gains in legacy securitized issues—those issued prior to 2008—neither the economics nor the tarnished reputation of securitization will justify a vigorous rebirth of the private- label new issue market anytime soon. As a result of the slowdown in new issuance and investors’ past trouble with these complex securities, many are choosing to fully avoid the legacy securitized market—eschewing exposure to both the private-label market and the more complex areas of the government-securitized market, called “agencies.” For that reason a large, under-owned, and under- followed collection of legacy securitized issues are available at attractive valuations. The legacy securitized market exhibits many of the inefficiencies that exemplify a distressed market. Those inefficiencies include all kinds of dislocations in the form of rating disparities, pricing anomalies, information asymmetry, ongoing regulatory uncertainties, unresolved legal settlements, abnormal servicer behavior, and an unclear future for housing finance.
    [Show full text]
  • Unsecured Debt and Reit Capital Structure*
    UNSECURED DEBT AND REIT CAPITAL STRUCTURE* Timothy J. Riddiough Massachusetts Institute of Technology Center for Real Estate, W31-310 Cambridge, AL4 021394307 (617)[email protected] April, 1998 * I am grateful to the Real Estate Research Institute for funding this project and to Fred Carr at Penobscott Group for providing much of the data. This research extends a series of earlier studies, done under my supervision, that were completed by master's students at the MIT Center for Real Estate. In particular, Josh Anderson, Josh Marston, Michael O'Connell, Ian Ponniah, and Mitchell Yuden deserve recognition for their fine research work. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY REAL ESTATE RESEARCH INSTITUTE "UNSECURED DEBT AND REIT CAPITAL STRUCTURE" Timothy J. Riddiough Massachusetts Institute of Technology Many REITs have recently touted the advantages of debt financing-in particular, the use of unsecured debt as an alternative to secured debt and equity financing. The primary argument for unsecured debt as a substitute for secured debt is that it increases operating flexibility due to the ability to "reshuffle the asset deck" at any time. An important implication of this argument is that use of unsecured debt is value increasing since it lowers the firm's weighted average cost of capital. This study questions the received wisdom by pointing out that unsecured debt is also flexibility reducing is several respects. Relative to use of secured debt, it decreases the firm's option value to defaulting on individual assets and bond covenants impose firm-wide restrictions on future operating and financing policy. If these flexibility costs are important to investors we might actually observe an increase in the firm's weighted average cost of capital when unsecured debt is first issued.
    [Show full text]
  • Glossary of Bond Terms
    Glossary of Bond Terms Accreted value- The current value of your zero-coupon municipal bond, taking into account interest that has been accumulating and automatically reinvested in the bond. Accrual bond- Often the last tranche in a CMO, the accrual bond or Z-tranche receives no cash payments for an extended period of time until the previous tranches are retired. While the other tranches are outstanding, the Z-tranche receives credit for periodic interest payments that increase its face value but are not paid out. When the other tranches are retired, the Z-tranche begins to receive cash payments that include both principal and continuing interest. Accrued interest- (1) The dollar amount of interest accrued on an issue, based on the stated interest rate on that issue, from its date to the date of delivery to the original purchaser. This is usually paid by the original purchaser to the issuer as part of the purchase price of the issue; (2) Interest deemed to be earned on a security but not yet paid to the investor. Active tranche- A CMO tranche that is currently paying principal payments to investors. Adjustable-rate mortgage (ARM)- A mortgage loan on which interest rates are adjusted at regular intervals according to predetermined criteria. An ARM's interest rate is tied to an objective, published interest rate index. Amortization- Liquidation of a debt through installment payments. Arbitrage- In the municipal market, the difference in interest earned on funds borrowed at a lower tax-exempt rate and interest on funds that are invested at a higher-yielding taxable rate.
    [Show full text]
  • Secured Credit Spreads and the Issuance of Secured Debt
    December 2020 Secured Credit Spreads and the Issuance of Secured Debt EFRAIM BENMELECH, NITISH KUMAR, and RAGHURAM RAJAN* ABSTRACT We show that after accounting for selection, credit spreads for secured debt issuances are lower than for unsecured debt issuances, especially when a firm’s credit quality deteriorates, the economy slows, or average credit spreads widen. Yet firms tend to be reluctant to issue secured debt when other forms of financing are available, as we demonstrate with an analysis of security issuance over time and in particular around the COVID-19 pandemic shock in the United States in early 2020. We find that for firms that are rated non-investment grade and that have few alternative sources of financing in difficult times, the likelihood of secured debt issuance is positively correlated with the spread between traded unsecured and secured bonds. It is not correlated for firms that are investment grade. This pattern of issue behavior is consistent with theories that see collateral as a form of insurance, to be used only in extremis. * Efraim Benmelech is with the Kellogg School of Management and NBER ([email protected]). Nitish Kumar is with the University of Florida ([email protected]). Raghuram Rajan is with the University of Chicago Booth School and NBER ([email protected]). The authors thank Dave Brown, Mark Flannery, Chris James, Gregor Matvos and Michael Schwert and seminar participants at the Kellogg School of Management and SMU Cox for very helpful comments and discussions. Sanhitha Jugulum and Manvendra Tiwari provided outstanding research assistance. Rajan thanks the Fama Miller Center, IGM, and the Stigler Center at the University of Chicago Booth School for research support.
    [Show full text]
  • Debt Investor Update Strong Result for H1/19 and Positive Outlook for FY 2019 Disclaimer
    Debt Investor Update Strong result for H1/19 and positive outlook for FY 2019 Disclaimer This presentation is not an offer or invitation to subscribe for or purchase any securities in any jurisdiction, including any jurisdiction of the United States. Securities may not be offered or sold in the United States absent registration or pursuant to an available exemption from registration under the U.S. Securities Act. Deutsche Pfandbriefbank AG does not intend to conduct a public offering of securities in the United States. No warranty is given as to the accuracy or completeness of the information in this presentation. You must make your own independent investigation and appraisal of the business and financial condition of Deutsche Pfandbriefbank AG and its direct and indirect subsidiaries and their securities. Nothing in this presentation shall form the basis of any contract or commitment whatsoever. This presentation may only be made available, distributed or passed on to persons in the United Kingdom in circumstances in which section 21(1) of the Financial Services and Markets Act 2000 does not apply. This presentation may only be made available, distributed or passed on to persons in Australia who qualify as 'wholesale clients' as defined in section 761G of the Australian Corporations Act. This presentation is furnished to you solely for your information. You may not reproduce it or redistribute to any other person. This presentation contains forward-looking statements based on calculations, estimates and assumptions made by the company’s top management and external advisors and are believed warranted. These statements may be identified by such words as ‘may’, ‘plans’, ‘expects’, ‘believes’ and similar expressions, or by their context and are made on the basis of current knowledge and assumptions.
    [Show full text]
  • Asset-Backed Securities: Costs and Benefits of "Bankruptcy
    Asset-Backed Securities: Costs and Benefits of “Bankruptcy Remoteness”∗ Kenneth M. Ayotte† Stav Gaon‡ Columbia Business School Columbia Business School Abstract This paper focuses on a key property of asset-backed securities (ABS); namely, that ABS are designed to achieve “bankruptcy remoteness” of the securitized assets from the borrowing firm. This provides lenders with maximal protection from dilution in bankruptcy that is not available with other contracts, such as secured debt. ABS can have real effects in allowing firmstocommittomoreefficient investment decisions in bankruptcy. We show that securitization of replaceable assets, such as accounts receivable, prevents inefficient continuation in bankruptcy, but securitization of neces- sary assets can lead to inefficient liquidations. In these circumstances, secured debt and/or leases can be preferred. We provide empirical support for the importance of bankruptcy remoteness in ABS contracts using a controversial decision in the Chapter 11 bankruptcy of LTV Steel, in which a securitization contract was unexpectedly treated as a secured loan. Using adifference-in-differences approach, we find that ABS spreads for securitizers eligible for Chapter 11 increased significantly more than spreads for insured bank securitiz- ers, who are not Chapter 11-eligible, in the period following the LTV filing. The results demonstrate that the creditor protection provided by “bankruptcy remoteness” is indeed valuable and priced in financial markets. ∗We would like to thank Barry Adler, Sugato Bhattacharyya, Jean Boivin, Patrick Bolton, Margarida Catalao, Frank Edwards, Chris Mayer, Rick Mishkin, Ed Morrison, Francisco Perez-Gonzalez, Robert Ras- mussen, Suresh Sundaresan, Walter Torous, Laurent Vilanova, and seminar participants at the ESSFM Gerzensee, the Texas Finance Festival, Wharton Bankruptcy/Financial Distress Conference, Columbia Con- ference for Bankruptcy Judges, and Conference on Financial Innovation for thoughtful comments and sug- gestions.
    [Show full text]
  • Does Unsecured Debt Decrease Savings? Evidence from the Refund to Savings Initiative by Michal Grinstein-Weiss, Jane Oliphant, Blair D
    | MARCH 2015 | CSD RESEARCH BRIEF 15-16 | Does unsecured debt decrease savings? Evidence from the Refund to Savings Initiative By Michal Grinstein-Weiss, Jane Oliphant, Blair D. Russell, & Ray Boshara In the wake of the Great Recession, low- and moderate- complete the Household Financial Survey (HFS). They income (LMI) households continue to face significant completed the first wave of the HFS at the time of tax obstacles that prevent them from developing healthy filing and the second wave 6 months later. balance sheets.1 One proposed step toward enabling financial health in these households is to encourage With two waves of survey data from 8,484 LMI saving at tax time,2 when tax refunds bring many LMI households, the 2013 R2S Initiative provides insights households the year’s largest influx of cash. However, into the burden of debt owed by LMI Americans. The high debt may prevent many of these households from average age of survey respondents was approximately saving at tax time. This brief summarizes findings on 35 years, the average adjusted gross income among household debt and saving from the Refund to Savings respondents’ households was $17,520, and the average (R2S) Initiative, which provides detailed information on federal refund was $2,179. Sixty-one percent of HFS the financial lives of LMI households. respondents were female, 64% were single, 43% were college educated, and 20% were non-White. A third of respondents’ households included dependent children. Background Using data from the 2013 R2S, this brief reviews the The R2S Initiative seeks to enhance saving at tax results of an analysis of debt.
    [Show full text]