A Primer on Cointegration with an Application to Money and Income

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

A Primer on Cointegration with an Application to Money and Income 58 I U David A. Dickey, Dennis W. Jansen and Daniel L. Thornton I David A. Dickey is a professor of statistics at North Carolina State University. Dennis W Jansen is an associate professor of economics at Texas A&M University and Daniel T Thornton is I an assistant vice president at the Federal Bank of St. Louis. The authors would like to thank Mark Watson, Tom Fomby and David Small for helpful comments on an earlier draft of this article. Lora Holman and Kevin L. Kliesen provided research assistance. I I A Primer On Cointegration I with an Application to Money I and Income I 1 I OR SOME TIME NOW, macroeconomists stems from a common prediction of macroeco- have been aware that many macroeconomic nomic theory that there should be a stable long- time series are not stationary in their levels and run relationship among the levels of certain eco- that many time series are most adequately nomic variables. That is, theory often suggests represented by first differences.’ In the parlance that some set of variables cannot wander too of time-series analysis, such variables are said to far away from each other. If individual time be integrated of order one and are denoted 1(1). series are integrated of order one, however, The level of such variables can become arbitrari- they may be “cointegrated.” Cointegration means ly large or small so there is no tendency for that one or more linear combinations of these them to revert to their mean level. Indeed, variables is stationary even though individually neither the mean nor the variance is a mean- they are not. If these variables are cointegrated, ingful concept for such variables. they cannot move too far” away from each Nonstationarity gives rise to several economet- other. In contrast, a lack of cointegration sug- ric problems.2 One of the most troublesome gests that such variables have no long-run link; 1 2lt can give rise to the possibility of a spurious relationship That is, formal statistical tests often cannot reject the null among the levels of the economic variables. Also, the hypothesis of a unit root. The results of these tests, parameter estimates from a regression of one such however, are sensitive to how the tests are performed— variable on others are inconsistent unless the variables are that is, whether the tests assume a non-zero mean or a cointegrated. time trend, whether an MA or AR data generating pro- cesses is assumed [Schwert (1987)) and whether the test is performed using classical or Bayesian statistical in- ference (Sims (1988), and Sims and Uhlig (1988)). These sensitivities are partly due to the lack of power these tests II have against an alternative hypothesis of a stationary but large root. FEDERAL RESERVE SANK OF ST. LOWS I I~- 59 in principle, they can %vander arbitrarily far When ~= 1, these deviations are permanent. In away from each other.-’ this case, y, is said to follow a random walk— I it can wander arbitrarily far from any given This article illustrates the salient features of 4 cointegration and tests for cointegration. The constant if enough time passes. In fact, when discussion, initially motivated by the simple ex- = 1 the variance of y, approaches infinity as I ample of Irving Fisher’s “equation of exchange,” increases and the mean of y,, y, is not defined. draws an analogy between cointegration and Alternatively, when ~[< 1, the series is said to unit roots on the one hand and tests for cointe- be mean reverting and the variance of y, is F gration among multiple time series and the usual finite. tests for unit roots in univariate time-series Although there is a similarity between tests analysis on the other. The article then addresses for cointegration and tests for unit roots, as we I the broader question of the economic inter- shall see below, they are not identical. Tests for pretation of cointegration by contrasting it with unit roots are performed on univariate time the usual linear, dynamic, simultaneous equa- series. In contrast, cointegration deals with the tion model which is frequently used in relationship among a group of variables, where I macroeconomics. (unconditionally) each has a unit root. The article goes on to compare three recently To be specific, consider Irving Fisher’s impor- proposed tests for cointegration and outlines the 7 tant equation of exchange, M\ = Pq, where Mis Ii procedures for applying these tests. An applica- a measure of nominal money, V is the velocity tion of these tests to U.S. time-series data using of money, Pisthe overall level of prices and q alternative monetary aggregates, income and in- is real output)’ This equation can be rewritten II terest rates suggests that there is a stable long- in natural logarithms as: run relationship among real output, interest rates and several monetary aggregates, including (2) lnM + mV — lnP — lnq = 0. the monetary base. In this form, the equation of exchange is an II identity. The theory of the demand for money, TESTING FOR COINTEGRATION: however, converts this identity into an equation by making velocity a function of a number of I f A GENERAL FRAMEWORK economic variables; both the form of the func- Because of the close correspondence between tion and its arguments change from one for cointegration and standard tests for theoretical specification to another. In the theory I testsunit roots, it is useful to begin the discussion by of money demand, V is unobservable and in ap- considering the univariate time-series model plied work it is proxied with some function of economic variables, V’, mV’ =lnV+E, where E denotes a random error associated with the use (i)y,—ji = Q(y,~ —jA) + II where y, denotes1 some univariate time series, p of the proxy for V.’ The proxy is a function of is the series’ mean and e, is a random error one or more observed variables, other than in- with an expected value of zero and a constant, come and prices, that are hypothesized to deter- ‘I finite variance. The coefficient Q measures the mine the demand for money. Hence, equation 2 degree of persistence of deviations of y, from j.i. is replaced with -‘At the present time, tests for cointegration deal only with pie, money holders might have a money illusion or money looking for stable linear relationships among economic demand might not be homogenous of degree one in real income. ‘For the classic discussion of velocity and a long list of its variables.relationshiptheredoes notis nonecessarilyConsequently,stable, amonglong-run,themeanvariables,a failurethat linearthereittorelationshiponly findis nosuggestscointegrationstable, amongthat long-run potential determinants, see Friedman (1956). Empirical proxies for velocity often contain one or more of these them. determinants. 4 Thatany startingis, for any valuenumbersY, thereC is>-a0time, and T,0 -<suchp <that,1 andfor forall generating>- 1, Pr(flYjY, >-isC)stationary> p. Whenin thatj~it<Idoesthe notprocesswander too far ‘Thefindfromacointegratingconstantits mean,C vectori.e.,> 0 forsuchcouldanythatgivenbePrdifferent(~Y,.-~4probabilityfromC) <p thep.we can hypothesized one for other reasons as well. For exam- I MARCH/APRlL 1991 I 60 I a (2’) lnM + lnV’ — lnP — lnq = E. In multiple comparison tests, an experimenter If the proxy is good, the expected value of E is usually concerned with, say, comparing the should be zero. Furthermore, E should be sta- highest and lowest sample means among several. I tionary, so that, V’ might deviate from its true He wants to find the pair of sample means with value in the short-run, but should converge to it the largest difference to see whether the dif- in the long-run. Failure to find a stationary rela- ference is statistically significant. When the I tionship among these variables—that is, to find means to be compared are chosen ahead of that they are not cointegrated—implies either time, tests for a significant difference between that V’ is a poor proxy for V or that the long- the means can be done using the usual t- I run demand for money does not exist in any statistics. If, however, the means to be com- meaningful sense. pared are chosen simply because they are the largest and smallest from a sample of, say, five In essence, the Fisher relationship embodies a means, the rejection rate under the null I long-run relationship among money, prices, out- hypothesis will be much higher than that im- put and velocity. In particular, it hypothesizes plied by the percentile of the t-distribution. In that the cointegrating vector (1,1,—i,— 1) exists. order to control for the experimentwise error I This vector combines the four series into a rate, as it is called, tables of distributions of univariate series, E. Given this assumption, a highest mean minus lowest mean (standardized) test for cointegration can be performed by ap- have been computed for the case of no true dif- plying any conventional unit x-oot test to E. ferences in the population means. These “tables Using conventional unit root tests to test for of the studentized range” are then used to test cointegration [such as tests prepared by Dickey for significant differences between the highest 7 and Fuller (1979) and Phillips (1987)], however, and lowest means. II requires prior knowledge of the cointegrating vector. And most often, this vector is unknown. The price paid for controlling the experiment- wise error rate is a loss in power. That is, the Therefore, some linear combination of these 11 variables, for example, difference between the means must be much larger than in the case of the standard t-test (3) b,lnM + b,lnv’ + b,lnP + b,lnq, before it can be declared significant at some is hypothesized to be stationary, where the predetermined significance level.
Recommended publications
  • Research Proposal
    Effects of Contract Farming on Productivity and Income of Farmers in Production of Tea in Phu Tho Province, Vietnam Anh Tru Nguyen MSc (University of the Philippines Los Baños) A thesis submitted in fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Management Newcastle Business School Faculty of Business and Law The University of Newcastle Australia February 2019 Statement of Originality I hereby certify that the work embodied in the thesis is my own work, conducted under normal supervision. The thesis contains no material which has been accepted, or is being examined, for the award of any other degree or diploma in any university or other tertiary institution and, to the best of my knowledge and belief, contains no material previously published or written by another person, except where due reference has been made. I give consent to the final version of my thesis being made available worldwide when deposited in the University’s Digital Repository, subject to the provisions of the Copyright Act 1968 and any approved embargo. Anh Tru Nguyen Date: 19/02/2019 i Acknowledgement of Authorship I hereby certify that the work embodied in this thesis contains a published paper work of which I am a joint author. I have included as part of the thesis a written statement, endorsed by my supervisor, attesting to my contribution to the joint publication work. Anh Tru Nguyen Date: 19/02/2019 ii Publications This thesis comprises the following published article and conference papers. I warrant that I have obtained, where necessary, permission from the copyright owners to use any third party copyright material reproduced in the thesis, or to use any of my own published work in which the copyright is held by another party.
    [Show full text]
  • The Johansen Tests for Cointegration
    The Johansen Tests for Cointegration Gerald P. Dwyer April 2015 Time series can be cointegrated in various ways, with details such as trends assuming some importance because asymptotic distributions depend on the presence or lack of such terms. I will focus on the simple case of one unit root in each of the variables with no constant terms or other deterministic terms. These notes are a quick summary of some results without derivations. Cointegration and Eigenvalues The Johansen test can be seen as a multivariate generalization of the augmented Dickey- Fuller test. The generalization is the examination of linear combinations of variables for unit roots. The Johansen test and estimation strategy { maximum likelihood { makes it possible to estimate all cointegrating vectors when there are more than two variables.1 If there are three variables each with unit roots, there are at most two cointegrating vectors. More generally, if there are n variables which all have unit roots, there are at most n − 1 cointegrating vectors. The Johansen test provides estimates of all cointegrating vectors. Just as for the Dickey-Fuller test, the existence of unit roots implies that standard asymptotic distributions do not apply. Slight digression for an assertion: If there are n variables and there are n cointegrating vectors, then the variables do not have unit roots. Why? Because the cointegrating vectors 1Results generally go through for quasi-maximum likelihood estimation. 1 can be written as scalar multiples of each of the variables alone, which implies
    [Show full text]
  • Testing for Cointegration When Some of The
    EconometricTheory, 11, 1995, 984-1014. Printed in the United States of America. TESTINGFOR COINTEGRATION WHEN SOME OF THE COINTEGRATINGVECTORS ARE PRESPECIFIED MICHAELT.K. HORVATH Stanford University MARKW. WATSON Princeton University Manyeconomic models imply that ratios, simpledifferences, or "spreads"of variablesare I(O).In these models, cointegratingvectors are composedof l's, O's,and - l's and containno unknownparameters. In this paper,we develop tests for cointegrationthat can be appliedwhen some of the cointegratingvec- tors are prespecifiedunder the null or underthe alternativehypotheses. These tests are constructedin a vectorerror correction model and are motivatedas Waldtests from a Gaussianversion of the model. Whenall of the cointegrat- ing vectorsare prespecifiedunder the alternative,the tests correspondto the standardWald tests for the inclusionof errorcorrection terms in the VAR. Modificationsof this basictest are developedwhen a subsetof the cointegrat- ing vectorscontain unknown parameters. The asymptoticnull distributionsof the statisticsare derived,critical values are determined,and the local power propertiesof the test are studied.Finally, the test is appliedto data on for- eign exchangefuture and spot pricesto test the stabilityof the forward-spot premium. 1. INTRODUCTION Economic models often imply that variables are cointegrated with simple and known cointegrating vectors. Examples include the neoclassical growth model, which implies that income, consumption, investment, and the capi- tal stock will grow in a balanced way, so that any stochastic growth in one of the series must be matched by corresponding growth in the others. Asset This paper has benefited from helpful comments by Neil Ericsson, Gordon Kemp, Andrew Levin, Soren Johansen, John McDermott, Pierre Perron, Peter Phillips, James Stock, and three referees.
    [Show full text]
  • A Cointegrated VAR and Granger Causality Analysis F
    CBN Journal of Applied Statistics Vol. 2 No.2 15 Foreign Private Investment and Economic Growth in Nigeria: A Cointegrated VAR and Granger causality analysis F. Z. Abdullahi1, S. Ladan1 and Haruna R. Bakari2 This research uses a cointegration VAR model to study the contemporaneous long-run dynamics of the impact of Foreign Private Investment (FPI), Interest Rate (INR) and Inflation rate (IFR) on Growth Domestic Products (GDP) in Nigeria for the period January 1970 to December 2009. The Unit Root Test suggests that all the variables are integrated of order 1. The VAR model was appropriately identified using AIC information criteria and the VECM model has exactly one cointegration relation. The study further investigates the causal relationship using the Granger causality analysis of VECM which indicates a uni-directional causality relationship between GDP and FDI at 5% which is in line with other studies. The result of Granger causality analysis also shows that some of the variables are Ganger causal of one another; the null hypothesis of non-Granger causality is rejected at 5% level of significance for these variables. Keywords: Cointegration, VAR, Granger Causality, FPI, Economic Growth JEL Classification: G32, G24 1.0 Introduction The use of Vector Autoregressive Models (VAR) and Vector Error Correction Models (VECM) for analyzing dynamic relationships among financial variables has become common in the literature, Granger (1981), Engle and Granger (1987), MacDonald and Power (1995) and Barnhill, et al. (2000). The popularity of these models has been associated with the realization that relationships among financial variables are so complex that traditional time-series models have failed to fully capture.
    [Show full text]
  • Conditional Heteroscedastic Cointegration Analysis with Structural Breaks a Study on the Chinese Stock Markets
    Conditional Heteroscedastic Cointegration Analysis with Structural Breaks A study on the Chinese stock markets Authors: Supervisor: Andrea P.G. Kratz Frederik Lundtofte Heli M.K. Raulamo VT 2011 Abstract A large number of studies have shown that macroeconomic variables can explain co- movements in stock market returns in developed markets. The purpose of this paper is to investigate whether this relation also holds in China’s two stock markets. By doing a heteroscedastic cointegration analysis, the long run relation is investigated. The results show that it is difficult to determine if a cointegrating relationship exists. This could be caused by conditional heteroscedasticity and possible structural break(s) apparent in the sample. Keywords: cointegration, conditional heteroscedasticity, structural break, China, global financial crisis Table of contents 1. Introduction ............................................................................................................................ 3 2. The Chinese stock market ...................................................................................................... 5 3. Previous research .................................................................................................................... 7 3.1. Stock market and macroeconomic variables ................................................................ 7 3.2. The Chinese market ..................................................................................................... 9 4. Theory .................................................................................................................................
    [Show full text]
  • Lecture 18 Cointegration
    RS – EC2 - Lecture 18 Lecture 18 Cointegration 1 Spurious Regression • Suppose yt and xt are I(1). We regress yt against xt. What happens? • The usual t-tests on regression coefficients can show statistically significant coefficients, even if in reality it is not so. • This the spurious regression problem (Granger and Newbold (1974)). • In a Spurious Regression the errors would be correlated and the standard t-statistic will be wrongly calculated because the variance of the errors is not consistently estimated. Note: This problem can also appear with I(0) series –see, Granger, Hyung and Jeon (1998). 1 RS – EC2 - Lecture 18 Spurious Regression - Examples Examples: (1) Egyptian infant mortality rate (Y), 1971-1990, annual data, on Gross aggregate income of American farmers (I) and Total Honduran money supply (M) ŷ = 179.9 - .2952 I - .0439 M, R2 = .918, DW = .4752, F = 95.17 (16.63) (-2.32) (-4.26) Corr = .8858, -.9113, -.9445 (2). US Export Index (Y), 1960-1990, annual data, on Australian males’ life expectancy (X) ŷ = -2943. + 45.7974 X, R2 = .916, DW = .3599, F = 315.2 (-16.70) (17.76) Corr = .9570 (3) Total Crime Rates in the US (Y), 1971-1991, annual data, on Life expectancy of South Africa (X) ŷ = -24569 + 628.9 X, R2 = .811, DW = .5061, F = 81.72 (-6.03) (9.04) Corr = .9008 Spurious Regression - Statistical Implications • Suppose yt and xt are unrelated I(1) variables. We run the regression: y t x t t • True value of β=0. The above is a spurious regression and et ∼ I(1).
    [Show full text]
  • Testing Linear Restrictions on Cointegration Vectors: Sizes and Powers of Wald Tests in Finite Samples
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Haug, Alfred A. Working Paper Testing linear restrictions on cointegration vectors: Sizes and powers of Wald tests in finite samples Technical Report, No. 1999,04 Provided in Cooperation with: Collaborative Research Center 'Reduction of Complexity in Multivariate Data Structures' (SFB 475), University of Dortmund Suggested Citation: Haug, Alfred A. (1999) : Testing linear restrictions on cointegration vectors: Sizes and powers of Wald tests in finite samples, Technical Report, No. 1999,04, Universität Dortmund, Sonderforschungsbereich 475 - Komplexitätsreduktion in Multivariaten Datenstrukturen, Dortmund This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/77134 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung
    [Show full text]
  • SUPPLEMENTARY APPENDIX a Time Series Model of Interest Rates
    SUPPLEMENTARY APPENDIX A Time Series Model of Interest Rates With the Effective Lower Bound⇤ Benjamin K. Johannsen† Elmar Mertens Federal Reserve Board Bank for International Settlements April 16, 2018 Abstract This appendix contains supplementary results as well as further descriptions of computa- tional procedures for our paper. Section I, describes the MCMC sampler used in estimating our model. Section II describes the computation of predictive densities. Section III reports ad- ditional estimates of trends and stochastic volatilities well as posterior moments of parameter estimates from our baseline model. Section IV reports estimates from an alternative version of our model, where the CBO unemployment rate gap is used as business cycle measure in- stead of the CBO output gap. Section V reports trend estimates derived from different variable orderings in the gap VAR of our model. Section VI compares the forecasting performance of our model to the performance of the no-change forecast from the random-walk model over a period that begins in 1985 and ends in 2017:Q2. Sections VII and VIII describe the particle filtering methods used for the computation of marginal data densities as well as the impulse responses. ⇤The views in this paper do not necessarily represent the views of the Bank for International Settlements, the Federal Reserve Board, any other person in the Federal Reserve System or the Federal Open Market Committee. Any errors or omissions should be regarded as solely those of the authors. †For correspondence: Benjamin K. Johannsen, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington D.C. 20551. email [email protected].
    [Show full text]
  • What Macroeconomists Should Know About Unit Roots
    This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1991, Volume 6 Volume Author/Editor: Olivier Jean Blanchard and Stanley Fischer, editors Volume Publisher: MIT Press Volume ISBN: 0-262-02335-0 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/blan91-1 Conference Date: March 8-9, 1991 Publication Date: January 1991 Chapter Title: Pitfalls and Opportunities: What Macroeconomists Should Know About Unit Roots Chapter Author: John Y. Campbell, Pierre Perron Chapter URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c10983 Chapter pages in book: (p. 141 - 220) JohnY. Campbelland PierrePerron PRINCETONUNIVERSITY AND NBER/PRINCETONUNIVERSITY AND CRDE Pitfalls and Opportunities:What MacroeconomistsShould Know about Unit Roots* 1. Introduction The field of macroeconomics has its share of econometric pitfalls for the unwary applied researcher. During the last decade, macroeconomists have become aware of a new set of econometric difficulties that arise when one or more variables of interest may have unit roots in their time series representations. Standard asymptotic distribution theory often does not apply to regressions involving such variables, and inference can go seriously astray if this is ignored. In this paper we survey unit root econometrics in an attempt to offer the applied macroeconomist some reliable guidelines. Unit roots can create opportunities as well as problems for applied work. In some unit root regressions, coefficient estimates converge to the true parameter values at a faster rate than they do in standard regressions with stationary variables. In large samples, coefficient estimates with this property are robust to many types of misspecification, and they can be treated as known in subsequent empiri- cal exercises.
    [Show full text]
  • High-Dimensional Predictive Regression in the Presence Of
    High-dimensional predictive regression in the presence of cointegration⇤ Bonsoo Koo Heather Anderson Monash University Monash University Myung Hwan Seo† Wenying Yao Seoul National University Deakin University Abstract We propose a Least Absolute Shrinkage and Selection Operator (LASSO) estimator of a predictive regression in which stock returns are conditioned on a large set of lagged co- variates, some of which are highly persistent and potentially cointegrated. We establish the asymptotic properties of the proposed LASSO estimator and validate our theoreti- cal findings using simulation studies. The application of this proposed LASSO approach to forecasting stock returns suggests that a cointegrating relationship among the persis- tent predictors leads to a significant improvement in the prediction of stock returns over various competing forecasting methods with respect to mean squared error. Keywords: Cointegration, High-dimensional predictive regression, LASSO, Return pre- dictability. JEL: C13, C22, G12, G17 ⇤The authors acknowledge financial support from the Australian Research Council Discovery Grant DP150104292. †Corresponding author. His work was supported by Promising-Pioneering ResearcherProgram through Seoul National University(SNU) and from the Ministry of Education of the Republic of Korea and the Na- tional Research Foundation of Korea (NRF-0405-20180026). Author contact details are [email protected], [email protected], [email protected], [email protected] 1 1 Introduction Return predictability has been of perennial interest to financial practitioners and scholars within the economics and finance professions since the early work of Dow (1920). To this end, empirical studies employ linear predictive regression models, as illustrated by Stam- baugh (1999), Binsbergen et al.
    [Show full text]
  • The Role of Models and Probabilities in the Monetary Policy Process
    1017-01 BPEA/Sims 12/30/02 14:48 Page 1 CHRISTOPHER A. SIMS Princeton University The Role of Models and Probabilities in the Monetary Policy Process This is a paper on the way data relate to decisionmaking in central banks. One component of the paper is based on a series of interviews with staff members and a few policy committee members of four central banks: the Swedish Riksbank, the European Central Bank (ECB), the Bank of England, and the U.S. Federal Reserve. These interviews focused on the policy process and sought to determine how forecasts were made, how uncertainty was characterized and handled, and what role formal economic models played in the process at each central bank. In each of the four central banks, “subjective” forecasting, based on data analysis by sectoral “experts,” plays an important role. At the Federal Reserve, a seventeen-year record of model-based forecasts can be com- pared with a longer record of subjective forecasts, and a second compo- nent of this paper is an analysis of these records. Two of the central banks—the Riksbank and the Bank of England— have explicit inflation-targeting policies that require them to set quantita- tive targets for inflation and to publish, several times a year, their forecasts of inflation. A third component of the paper discusses the effects of such a policy regime on the policy process and on the role of models within it. The large models in use in central banks today grew out of a first generation of large models that were thought to be founded on the statisti- cal theory of simultaneous-equations models.
    [Show full text]
  • Lecture: Introduction to Cointegration Applied Econometrics
    Lecture: Introduction to Cointegration Applied Econometrics Jozef Barunik IES, FSV, UK Summer Semester 2010/2011 Jozef Barunik (IES, FSV, UK) Lecture: Introduction to Cointegration Summer Semester 2010/2011 1 / 18 Introduction Readings Readings 1 The Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences (2003): Time Series Econometrics: Cointegration and Autoregressive Conditional Heteroscedasticity, downloadable from: http://www-stat.wharton.upenn.edu/∼steele/HoldingPen/NobelPrizeInfo.pdf 2 Granger,C.W.J. (2003): Time Series, Cointegration and Applications, Nobel lecture, December 8, 2003 3 Harris Using Cointegration Analysis in Econometric Modelling, 1995 (Useful applied econometrics textbook focused solely on cointegration) 4 Almost all textbooks cover the introduction to cointegration Engle-Granger procedure (single equation procedure), Johansen multivariate framework (covered in the following lecture) Jozef Barunik (IES, FSV, UK) Lecture: Introduction to Cointegration Summer Semester 2010/2011 2 / 18 Introduction Outline Outline of the today's talk What is cointegration? Deriving Error-Correction Model (ECM) Engle-Granger procedure Jozef Barunik (IES, FSV, UK) Lecture: Introduction to Cointegration Summer Semester 2010/2011 3 / 18 Introduction Outline Outline of the today's talk What is cointegration? Deriving Error-Correction Model (ECM) Engle-Granger procedure Jozef Barunik (IES, FSV, UK) Lecture: Introduction to Cointegration Summer Semester 2010/2011 3 / 18 Introduction Outline Outline of the today's talk What is cointegration? Deriving Error-Correction Model (ECM) Engle-Granger procedure Jozef Barunik (IES, FSV, UK) Lecture: Introduction to Cointegration Summer Semester 2010/2011 3 / 18 Introduction Outline Robert F. Engle and Clive W.J. Granger Robert F. Engle shared the Nobel prize (2003) \for methods of analyzing economic time series with time-varying volatility (ARCH) with Clive W.
    [Show full text]