The Economy in a World of Trouble

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Economy in a World of Trouble Derro/iers seeking job applicaiions at the post office. The city has an ofßdai unemployment rate of 16.2%. Jirti WesI / www iimwestpholo.com An interview with Robert Brenner The Economy in a World of Trouble ROBERT BRENNER, AN editor of Against the Current and the the 1960s.The failure of the rate of profit to recover is all the author of The Economics of Global Turbulence (Verso, 2006), more remarkable, in view of the huge drop-off in the growth was interviewed by Seon^in jeong for Hankyoreh, Korea's leading of real wages, over the period. daily newspaper.This interview was published on Jonuary 19, 2009 The main cause, though not the only cause, of the decline ar)d has been slightly edited for publication here. in the rate of profit has been a persistent tendency to over- Song/in Jeong: Most media and analysts label the current crisis capacity in global manufacturing industries. What happened as a "fmancial crisis." Do you agree with this characterizaVon? was that one after another new manufacturing power entered Robert Brenner It's understandable that analysts of the the world market —• Germany and japan, the northeast Asian crisis have made the meltdown in banking and the securities Newly Industrializing Countries (NICS), the southeast Asian markets their point of departure. But the difficulty is that they Tigers, and, finally the Chinese Leviathan. have not gone any deeper. From Treasury Secretary Henry These later-developing economies produced the same Paulson and Fed Chair Ben Bernanke on down, they argue goods that were already being produced by the earlier devel- that the crisis can be explained simply in terms of problems opers, only cheaper. The result was too much supply com- in the financial sector. At the same time, they assert that the pared to demand in one industry after another, and this forced underlying real economy is strong, the so-called fundamentals down prices and in that way profits. The corporations that in good shape.This could not be more misleading. experienced the squeeze on their profits, moreover, did not meekly leave their industries; they tried to hold their place by The basic source of today's crisis is the declining vitality falling back on their capacity for innovation and speeding up of the advanced economies since 1973, and, especially, since investment in new technologies. But of course this only made 2000. Economic performance in the United States, western overcapacity worse. Europe, and Japan has steadily deteriorated, business cycle by business cycle in terms of every standard macroeconomic Due to the fall in their rate of return, capitalists were get- indicator — GDP, investment, real wages and so forth. Most ting smaller surpluses from their investments.They therefore telling, the business cycle that just ended, from 2001 through had no choice but to slow down the growth of plant and 2007, was — by far — the weakest of the postwar period, and equipment and employment. At the same time, in order to this despite the greatest government-sponsored economic restore profitability, they held down employees' pay, while stimulus in U.S. peacetime history. governments reduced the growth of social expenditures. SJ: How would you explain the long-term weakening of the real But the consequence of all these cutbacks in spending has economy since 1973, what you call in your work "the long down- been a long-term problem of aggregate demand. The persis- turn"? tent weakness of aggregate demand has been the immediate RB: What mainly accounts for it is a deep, and lasting, decline source of the economy's long-term weakness. of the rate of return on capital investment since the end of SJ: The crisis was actually triggered by the bursting of the his- AGAINST THE CURRENT» 15 toric housiryg bubble, which had been RB: The current crisis is more expanding for a full decade. What is serious than the v^orst previous your view of its significance? recession of the postwar period, RB:The housing bubble needs to be between 1979 and 1982. and could understood in relation to the suc- conceivably come to rival the Great cession of asset price bubbles that Depression, though there is no the economy has experienced since way of really knowing. Economic the middle 1990s, and especially the forecasters have underestimated role of the U.S. Federal Reserve in how had bad it is because they nurturing those bubbles. have overestimated the strength of the real economy and failed to Since the start of the long down- take into account the extent of its turn, state economic authorities dependence upon a buildup of debt have tried to cope with the problem that relied on asset price bubbles. of insufficient demand by encourag- ing the increase of borrowing, both ln the United States, during the public and private. At first they recent business cycle of the years turned to state budget deficits, and 2001 -2007. GDP growth was by far in this way they did avoid really the slowest of the postwar epoch. deep recessions. But as time went There was no increase in private on, governments could get ever sector employment The increase § less growth from the same amount in plant and equipment was abouti of borrowing. In effect, in order to a third off the previous postwar s stave off the sort of profound crises low. Real wages were basically flat!. that historically have plagued the There was no increase in median I capitalist system, they had to accept family income for the first time ^ a slide toward stagnation. since WWII. Economic growth was I During the early 1990s. govern- driven entirely by personal con-1 ments in the United States and sumption and residential invest- file housing bubble marked the final uugc ol Lhe "boam.'lts ment, made possible by easy credit Europe, led by the Clinton admin- collapse is accelerating títe meltdown. istration, famously tried to break and rising house prices. their addiction to debt by moving together toward balanced Economic performance was this weak, despite the enor- budgets. The idea was to let the free market govern the mous stimulus from the housing bubble and the Bush admin- economy. But because profitability had still not recovered, istration's huge federal deficits. Housing by itself accounted the reduction in deficits delivered a big shock to demand, and for almost one-third of the growth of GDP and close to half helped bring about the recessions and slow growth between of the increase in employment in the years 2001 -2005. It was !99I and 1995. therefore to be expected that when the housing bubble burst, To get the economy expanding again, U.S. authorities ended consumption and residential investment would fall, and the up adopting an approach that had been pioneered by Japan economy would plunge. during the later 1980s. By keeping interest rates low. the SJ: Many assert that the current crisis is a typical financial crisis, Federal Reserve made it easy to borrow so as to encourage not a "Marxian" one of overproduction and falling profit, arguing investment in financial assets. As asset prices soared, corpo- that the financial speculatiorhbubble-bust has played the central rations and households experienced huge increases in their rote in this crisis. How would you respond? weaith, at least on paper.They v^ere therefore able to borrow RB: I don't think it's helpful to counterpose in that way the on a titanic scale, vastly increase their investment and con- real and financial aspects of the crisis. As I emphasized, it is a sumption, and in that way drive the economy. Marxian crisis in that it finds its roots in a longterm fall and So. private deficits replaced public ones. What might failure to recover the rate of profit, which is the fundamental be called "asset price Keynesianism" replaced traditional source of the extended slowdown of capital accumulation Keynesianism.We have therefore witnessed for the last dozen right into the present. In 2001, the rate of profit for U.S. non- years or so the extraordinary spectacle of a world economy financiai corporations was the lowest of the postwar period, in which the continuation of capital accumulation has come except for 1980. Corporations therefore had no choice but to literally to depend upon historic waves of speculation, care- hold back on investment and employment, further darkening fully nurtured and rationalized by state policy makers — and the business climate. regulators! — first the historic stock market bubble of the This is what accounts for the ultra-slow growth during the later 1990s, then the housing and credit market bubbles from business cycle that just ended. Nevertheless, to understand the early 2000s. the current collapse, you have to demonstrate the connection S/: You were prophetic in forecasting the current crisis as well as between the weakness of the real economy and the financial the 2001 recession. Whot is your outlook for the global economy? meltdown. The main link is the economy's ever-increasing Will it worsen, or will it recover before the end of 2009? Do dependence on borrowing to keep it turning over, and the you expect that the current crisis will be as severe as the Great government's ever greater reliance on asset price run-ups to Depression.^ allow that borrowing to continue. 16» MARCH/APRIL2009 The basic condition for the housing and credit market Resurgent" (Gerard Dumeni!) between the 1980s and the present bubbles was the perpetuation of low costs of borrowing. The What do you think of such a thesis? weakness of the world economy, especially after the crises RB: The idea of a finance led-capitalism is a contradiction of 1997-1998 and 2001-2002.
Recommended publications
  • Modern Intellectual History
    0RGHUQ,QWHOOHFWXDO+LVWRU\ KWWSMRXUQDOVFDPEULGJHRUJ0,+ $GGLWLRQDOVHUYLFHVIRU0RGHUQ,QWHOOHFWXDO+LVWRU\ (PDLODOHUWV&OLFNKHUH 6XEVFULSWLRQV&OLFNKHUH &RPPHUFLDOUHSULQWV&OLFNKHUH 7HUPVRIXVH&OLFNKHUH 7+($&&,'(17$/0$5;,67$1'5(*81'(5)5$1.$1'7+( ³1(20$5;,67´7+(25<2)81'(5'(9(/230(17± &2'<67(3+(16 0RGHUQ,QWHOOHFWXDO+LVWRU\)LUVW9LHZ$UWLFOH$SULOSS '2,63XEOLVKHGRQOLQH$SULO /LQNWRWKLVDUWLFOHKWWSMRXUQDOVFDPEULGJHRUJDEVWUDFWB6 +RZWRFLWHWKLVDUWLFOH &2'<67(3+(167+($&&,'(17$/0$5;,67$1'5(*81'(5)5$1.$1' 7+(³1(20$5;,67´7+(25<2)81'(5'(9(/230(17± 0RGHUQ,QWHOOHFWXDO+LVWRU\$YDLODEOHRQ&-2GRL 6 5HTXHVW3HUPLVVLRQV&OLFNKHUH 'RZQORDGHGIURPKWWSMRXUQDOVFDPEULGJHRUJ0,+,3DGGUHVVRQ0D\ Modern Intellectual History,page1 of 32 C Cambridge University Press 2016 ! doi:10.1017/S1479244316000123 the accidental marxist: andre gunder frank and the “neo-marxist” theory of underdevelopment, 1958–1967 cody stephens Department of History, University of California–Santa Barbara E-mail: [email protected] Based on newly available archival records, this article examines the life and thought of Andre Gunder Frank from his years as a graduate student in development economics to the publication of his first and most influential book. A closer look at the evolution of Frank’s thought provides new insight into the relationship of his brand of “neo-Marxist” development theories with both classical Marxism and modernization theory. Frank interpreted Marxist political debates according to the categories of thought of 1950s American development economics, and in doing so he both misinterpreted fundamental aspects of Marxism and simultaneously generated lively theoretical debates that remain relevant today. Paul Sweezy thought Andre Gunder Frank’s Capitalism and Underdevelopment in Latin America (hereafter CU)wouldbeabighit.AstheheadofMonthlyReview Press, a small but important publishing operation held together largely by his own efforts, Sweezy had to choose carefully the projects on which he would expend his and his small staff’s limited time and energy.
    [Show full text]
  • The Politics of Market Reform Altering State Development Policy in Southern Africa
    ASPJ Africa & Francophonie - 3rd Quarter 2013 The Politics of Market Reform Altering State Development Policy in Southern Africa SHAUKAT ANSARI* Introduction outh Africa’s transition from a racially exclusive apartheid state to a liberal democracy—referred to as a “double transition” to denote the economic dynamics behind the political transformation—has attracted the attention of a substantial number of researchers from a variety of disciplines.1 The topic of radical transformation in the African NationalS Congress’s (ANC) official position on state developmental policy has aroused perhaps the greatest interest among scholars. Prior to 1994, few observers would have predicted that the white minority in South Africa would relinquish its formal rule predicated on racial domination while avoiding the initiation of structural transformations involving a fundamen- tal reorientation of existing social relations. Yet, the end of apartheid and the liberation movement’s victory did not result in the transformation of capitalist social-property relations. In fact, upon taking power, the ANC implemented a homegrown, neoliberal structural adjustment program that opened South Africa to foreign economic interests and propelled the coun- try down a path of market liberalization. Explanations offered by scholars to account for this policy shift within the ANC can be roughly divided into two competing models. According to the first one, the South African government’s ability to maneuver was se- verely restricted by structural constraints imposed by international and domestic business interests in a post–Cold War environment. The fact that *The author is a doctoral candidate at the University of Toronto in the Department of Political Science.
    [Show full text]
  • 1 Introduction: Why Geopolitical Economy?
    1 INTRODUCTION: WHY GEOPOLITICAL ECONOMY? The owl of Minerva, Hegel once remarked, takes wing at dusk. Knowledge results from reflection after the tumult of the day. This gloomy view may be too sweeping, but it certainly applies to the multipolar world order. Influential figures began hailing it in the wake of the 2008 financial crisis and the Great Recession. The American president of the World Bank spoke of ‘a new, fast-evolving multi-polar world economy’ (World Bank, 2010). Veteran international financier George Soros predicted that ‘the current financial crisis is less likely to cause a global recession than a radical realignment of the global economy, with a relative decline of the US and the rise of China and other countries in the developing world’ (2008). However, the multipolar world order was much longer in the making. Developments of this magnitude simply don’t happen overnight even in a crisis (though, as we shall see, emerging multipolarity was a decisive factor in causing it), and this has important implications for prevailing understandings of the capitalist world order. Recent accounts stressed its economic unity: globalization conceived a world unified by markets alone while empire proposed one unified by the world’s most powerful – ‘hegemonic’ or ‘imperial’ (the terms tended to be used interchangeably) – state. They also assumed either that nation-states were not relevant to explaining the world order (globalization), or that only one, the United States, was (empire). We can call these views cosmopolitan, a term the Oxford English Dictionary defines as ‘not restricted to any one country or its inhabitants’ and ‘free from national limitations or attachments’.
    [Show full text]
  • Globalización Económica Y Crisis Americana. Comentario a Partir De
    Carles Manera Globalizacion´ economica´ y crisis americana. Comentario a partir de Robert Brenner y Joseph Stiglitz • CARLES MANERA Universitat de les Illes Balears El fenomeno´ de la «nueva» globalizacion´ –para oponerlo a la «vieja», que los histo- riadores economicos´ identificamos a fines del siglo XIX– esta´ generando una abundante bibliograf´ıa que pretende explicar, desde angulos´ diversos, la articulacion´ de la econom´ıa capitalista en un periodo que se considera «readaptativo». De entre ese ingente material, imposible de resenar,˜ cabe destacar las aportaciones de dos expertos que son bien conoci- dos por economistas e historiadores, habida cuenta sus contribuciones espec´ıficas tiempo atras.´ Me refiero a sendos libros firmados por el profesor de la Universidad de Columbia y Premio Nobel de Econom´ıa, J. Stiglitz (Los felices 90. La semilla de la destruccion´ ) y por el director del Center for Social Theory and Comparative History de UCLA, R. Brenner (La expansion´ economica´ y la burbuja bursatil´ ), al que siempre hemos relacionado con el famoso debate de la transicion´ del feudalismo al capitalismo –amen´ de su magn´ıfico trabajo sobre los comerciantes ingleses del siglo XVII–, y que fue ampliamente citado por la rica controversia que mantuvo con el marxismo mas´ circulacionista, encarnado primero en P. Sweezy y, despues,´ en I. Wallerstein. Valga esta precision´ para que el lector sepa que no nos referimos a un homonimo,´ sino que estamos ante el genuino Brenner, que ha dejado aparcadas –por el momento, al menos– sus teor´ıas sobre los procesos economi-´ cos en sociedades preindustriales para dar paso, con identicos´ br´ıos, a nuevos materiales e interpretaciones que afectan, sobre todo, a las contradicciones presentes de la econom´ıa mundial.
    [Show full text]
  • Marxism and the Solidarity Economy: Toward a New Theory of Revolution
    Class, Race and Corporate Power Volume 9 Issue 1 Article 2 2021 Marxism and the Solidarity Economy: Toward a New Theory of Revolution Chris Wright [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.fiu.edu/classracecorporatepower Part of the Political Science Commons Recommended Citation Wright, Chris (2021) "Marxism and the Solidarity Economy: Toward a New Theory of Revolution," Class, Race and Corporate Power: Vol. 9 : Iss. 1 , Article 2. DOI: 10.25148/CRCP.9.1.009647 Available at: https://digitalcommons.fiu.edu/classracecorporatepower/vol9/iss1/2 This work is brought to you for free and open access by the College of Arts, Sciences & Education at FIU Digital Commons. It has been accepted for inclusion in Class, Race and Corporate Power by an authorized administrator of FIU Digital Commons. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Marxism and the Solidarity Economy: Toward a New Theory of Revolution Abstract In the twenty-first century, it is time that Marxists updated the conception of socialist revolution they have inherited from Marx, Engels, and Lenin. Slogans about the “dictatorship of the proletariat” “smashing the capitalist state” and carrying out a social revolution from the commanding heights of a reconstituted state are completely obsolete. In this article I propose a reconceptualization that accomplishes several purposes: first, it explains the logical and empirical problems with Marx’s classical theory of revolution; second, it revises the classical theory to make it, for the first time, logically consistent with the premises of historical materialism; third, it provides a (Marxist) theoretical grounding for activism in the solidarity economy, and thus partially reconciles Marxism with anarchism; fourth, it accounts for the long-term failure of all attempts at socialist revolution so far.
    [Show full text]
  • The Winding Paths of Capital
    giovanni arrighi THE WINDING PATHS OF CAPITAL Interview by David Harvey Could you tell us about your family background and your education? was born in Milan in 1937. On my mother’s side, my fam- ily background was bourgeois. My grandfather, the son of Swiss immigrants to Italy, had risen from the ranks of the labour aristocracy to establish his own factories in the early twentieth Icentury, manufacturing textile machinery and later, heating and air- conditioning equipment. My father was the son of a railway worker, born in Tuscany. He came to Milan and got a job in my maternal grand- father’s factory—in other words, he ended up marrying the boss’s daughter. There were tensions, which eventually resulted in my father setting up his own business, in competition with his father-in-law. Both shared anti-fascist sentiments, however, and that greatly influenced my early childhood, dominated as it was by the war: the Nazi occupation of Northern Italy after Rome’s surrender in 1943, the Resistance and the arrival of the Allied troops. My father died suddenly in a car accident, when I was 18. I decided to keep his company going, against my grandfather’s advice, and entered the Università Bocconi to study economics, hoping it would help me understand how to run the firm. The Economics Department was a neo- classical stronghold, untouched by Keynesianism of any kind, and no help at all with my father’s business. I finally realized I would have to close it down. I then spent two years on the shop-floor of one of my new left review 56 mar apr 2009 61 62 nlr 56 grandfather’s firms, collecting data on the organization of the production process.
    [Show full text]
  • The Old and New Economics of Imperialism
    THE OLD AND NEW ECONOMICS OF IMPERIALISM G REGORY A LBO riting forty years ago in the first volume of the Socialist Register, Hamza WAlavi argued that it was necessary to turn to an analysis of a ‘new impe- rialism’, because the ‘end of direct colonial rule … [had] not yet precipitated that final crisis which was to see the end of monopoly capitalism and to herald the age of socialism.’ Insisting that the key dynamic in the world economy could no longer be captured by the classic theories of imperialism of territorial expan- sionism in the search for economic outlets, he concluded that the principal aim of … the new imperialism is not the export of capital as a means of exploiting cheap labour overseas. It is rather that of concen- trating investment at home to expand production in the metropolitan country and of seeking to dominate world markets on which it establishes its grasp by a variety of means …1 This insight, at once theoretical and political, remains central to the analysis of the new imperialism today in terms of the systemic reproduction of uneven development and the hierarchical organizational arrangement of the world market through formally equal economic exchanges and political relations between states.2 By locating imperialism in terms of the law of value and the rule of law, ‘consent’ can be seen as important as ‘coercion’ in understanding modern imperialism. The internationalisation of capital during the long period of neoliberalism since the 1980s has given rise to new patterns and contradictions in the world market and has had profound effects on the institutionalization of state power, the organization of state apparatuses and the relations between states.
    [Show full text]
  • Who Are These Economists, Anyway?
    mm-T&A09GalbraithSF.qxp:Layout 1 11/10/09 3:40 PM Page 85 Who Are These Economists, Anyway? by James K. Galbraith Of course, there were exceptions to these trends: a few economists challenged the assumption of rational behavior, questioned the belief that financial markets can be trusted and pointed to the long history of financial crises that had devastating economic consequences. But they were swimming against the tide, unable to make much headway against a pervasive and, in retrospect, foolish complacency. —Paul Krugman, New York Times Magazine , September 6, 2009 Amen. While normal ecclesiastic practice places this word at the end of the prayer, on this occa - sion it seems right to put it up front. In two sentences, Professor Paul Krugman, Nobel Laureate in Economics for 2008 and in some ways the leading economist of our time, has summed up the failure of an entire era in economic thought, practice, and policy discussion. And yet, there is something odd about the role of this short paragraph in an essay of over 6,500 words. It’s a throwaway. It leads nowhere. Apart from one other half-sentence, and three passing mentions of one person, it’s the only discussion—the one mention in the entire essay— of those economists who got it right. They are not named. Their work is not cited. Their story remains untold. Despite having been right on the greatest economic question of a generation—they are unpersons in the tale. Krugman’s entire essay is about two groups, both deeply entrenched at (what they believe to be) the top of academic economics.
    [Show full text]
  • What's at Stake in the Transition Debate? Rethinking the Origins of Capitalism And
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by SOAS Research Online This is the accepted version of Anievas, Alexander and Nisancioglu, Kerem (2013) What’s at Stake in the Transition Debate? Rethinking the Origins of Capitalism and the ‘Rise of the West’ Millennium: Journal of International Studies Vol. 42 (1), 78-102. Published version available from Sage at: http://journals.sagepub.com/doi/10.1177/0305829813497823 Accepted version downloaded from SOAS Research Online: http://eprints.soas.ac.uk/20673/ What’s at Stake in the Transition Debate? Rethinking the Origins of Capitalism and the ‘Rise of the West’ Alexander Anievas & Kerem Nisancioglu Introduction Recent years have witnessed a veritable historiographical revolution in the study of the early modern epoch. This has come from a disparate group of scholars1 challenging what they see as the fundamentally ‘Eurocentric’ nature of extant theoretical and historical approaches. Debates over the origins of capitalism have subsequently taken on new dimensions as scholars have forcefully problematized notions of an inextricable and self-propelling ‘rise of the West’ whilst relativizing the uniqueness of a singular Western modernity. Once side-lined to the margins of historical and sociological investigation, the non-Western sources, dynamics and experiences of capitalist modernity have thus been at the forefront of these literatures acting as a much needed corrective to the essentializing, self-aggrandizing narratives of an internally-generated ‘European miracle’. Perhaps the most significant contribution of this literature has been the resolute focus on the relations of interconnection and co-constitution between the West and ‘the rest’ in their joint making of the modern world.
    [Show full text]
  • Reply to Critics Robert Brenner
    Reply to Critics Robert Brenner As is well-understood, the postwar economy, has gone profitability. So, the conceptual challenge in explaining through two major phases. During the long boom between each progression from long boom through long downturn the end of the 1940s and the early 1970s, most of the ad- — and in particular that of the postwar epoch — is to ex- vanced capitalist economies (outside the United States and plain the, hypothetically typical, sequence from the repro- the United Kingdom) experienced record-breaking rates of duction of a high rate of profit, to the onset of falling profit- investment, output, productivity, and wage growth, along ability, and, finally, to the failure of profitability to recover. with low unemployment and only brief and mild recessions. Lastly, there is the “middle-range” hypothesis that capi- But during the long downturn that followed, the growth of tal accumulation historically tends to take the form of un- investment fell significantly and issued in much-reduced even development, a pattern of interaction between earlier productivity growth and sharply-slowed wage growth (if developing, technologically leading, and hegemonic blocs not absolute decline), along with depression-level unem- of capital, and later developing, technologically following, ployment (outside the United States) and a succession of and hegemonized blocs of capital, which itself tends to fol- serious recessions and financial crises. In The Economics of low a definite progression over time. From this standpoint, Global Turbulence (henceforth EGT), I sought to explain the pattern of German and US economic development with the foundations of the long boom, show why long boom respect to that of Great Britain in the period from the 1880s turned to long downturn, and to account for the persistence to the Great Depression provides a very rough template for of the long downturn.
    [Show full text]
  • Capitalism, Laws of Motion and Social Relations of Production
    Historical Materialism 21.4 (2013) 71–91 brill.com/hima Capitalism, Laws of Motion and Social Relations of Production Charles Post Borough of Manhattan Community College-City University of New York [email protected] Abstract Theory as History brings together twelve essays by Jarius Banaji addressing the nature of modes of production, the forms of historical capitalism and the varieties of pre-capitalist modes of production. Problematic formulations concerning the relationship of social-property relations and the laws of motion of different modes of production and his notion of merchant and slave- holding capitalism undermines Banaji’s project of constructing a non-unilinear, non-Eurocentric Marxism. Keywords modes of production, social-property relations, origins of capitalism, historical capitalism, plantation slavery, merchant capitalism Over the past four decades, Jairus Banaji has contributed to the revival of a non-dogmatic, anti-Stalinist Marxism. His theoretical and empirical research ranges over a breathtaking array of topics – the long and complex evolution of social relations of production in Europe from the fall of the Roman Empire to the consolidation of feudalism, the dynamics of rural social structures in South Asia over the past two centuries, value and crisis theory, and the development of labour organisation and struggle in transnational corporations.1 Banaji has also made classical Marxist texts, including segments of Kautsky’s The Agrarian Question2 and Grossman’s The Law of Accumulation,3 available to English-speaking audiences. In all of his work, Banaji consistently challenges The author would like to thank Robert Brenner, Liam Campling, Vivek Chibber, David McNally, Teresa Stern and Ellen Meiksins-Wood for their comments and suggestions on an earlier version of this essay.
    [Show full text]
  • Book Review Essay: Capital Resurgent? the Political Economy of Gérard Duménil and Dominique Lévy Matthew Nichter Department O
    Book Review Essay: Capital Resurgent? The Political Economy of Gérard Duménil and Dominique Lévy Matthew Nichter Department of Sociology University of Wisconsin-Madison [email protected] Duménil, Gérard and Dominique Lévy. 2004. Capital Resurgent: Roots of the Neoliberal Revolution. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. 256 pages, ISBN-13: 978-0-674-01158-8 ($59.00). Written from a broadly Marxist perspective, Capital Resurgent proposes a sweeping interpretation of nearly one hundred and fifty years of capitalist development, illuminating the ‘neoliberal revolution’ of the past quarter century through comparisons with earlier periods. French economists Gérard Duménil and Dominique Lévy have produced an ambitious book, replete with useful data and provocative hypotheses, that summarizes and synthesizes their growing oeuvre. At the center of their story is the rate of profit: the return on capital investment. Reinforcing the findings of Robert Brenner (1998, 2002a) and others (e.g. Armstrong, Glyn and Harrison 1991; Chan-Lee and Sutch 1985; Poletayev 1992; Shaikh 1999; Webber and Rigby 1996; Weisskopf 1992), Duménil and Lévy show that the ‘golden age’ of post-World War II prosperity in the U.S. and Europe1 depended upon high profit rates, which permitted rapid capital accumulation and stable employment. As profit rates declined during the late 1960s, 1970s, and early 1980s – by about 45 percent, according to the authors’ calculations – investment slowed, unemployment rose, and governments faced chronic budgetary problems. Duménil and Lévy argue that the most important cause of the declining rate of profit in both the U.S. and Europe during this period was stagnant productivity. Between the mid-1960s and early 1980s, capital productivity (output per dollar of fixed capital investment) declined by about 30 percent.
    [Show full text]