On Constitutionalizing a Balanced Budget

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

On Constitutionalizing a Balanced Budget On Constitutionalizing a Balanced Budget Joe Amick Terrence Chapman Zachary Elkins [email protected] [email protected] [email protected] May 21, 2019 Abstract Do constitutional rules that mandate a balanced budget promote fiscal discipline? Although such rules are at the heart of austerity debates across the world, we know surprisingly little about their consequences. We leverage original data on constitutional budget provisions and analyze their effect on governments' primary budget balances. We find that constitutional rules that require balanced budgets are robustly associated with fiscal discipline. The constitutional effect remains even after controlling for statutory balanced-budget rules. Furthermore, the effect strengthens as constitutions become more difficult to amend, and under conditions of borderline solvency { two implications consistent with a constitutional impact. The results will be surprising to those who appreciate both the strong pressures against fiscal discipline and the creativity of governments in devising strategies to evade spending limits. These findings are among the first cross-national, over-time study of the impact of constitutional budget commitments and, therefore, provide a reference point for policy debates surrounding financial crises in many national contexts. Keywords - public finances; constitutional amendments; balanced budget rules, primary balance Supplementary materials will be available in an online appendix. Replication files are available in the JOP Data Archive on Dataverse (http://thedata.harvard.edu/dvn/dv/jop) 2 1 Introduction The struggle to control public spending is pervasive, and the essential problem is easy to grasp. One useful characterization sees the problem as a common pool resource challenge (Weingast et al. 1981; Hallerberg and von Hagen 2009; Bawn and Rosenbluth 2006): politicians face incentives to maximize spending for their constituents but fewer incentives to rein in aggregate spending. The typical result is that total spend- ing often exceeds revenue; governments consequently borrow to finance the gap, and, ultimately, develop persistent deficit-spending habits and mounting debt. Leaders often seek to institutionalize budget rules to avoid this problem. One of the simpler approaches is one that resonates with citizens: require that disburse- ments equal receipts (a balanced-budget rule). Of course, politicians are tempted to modify or ignore these rules when faced with short-term political exigencies. One way to overcome such a \time-inconsistency" problem is to entrench budget rules constitutionally, under the premise that constitutions are more difficult to alter than are administrative rules. Constitutional rules may also be more difficult to evade and easier to enforce, yet what exactly are the effects of constitutionalizing budget rules? Are their effects on budgets substantially different from those of non-constitutional (whether statutory or regulatory) rules? These questions are at the heart of institutional design, among whose challenges are to (1) strike a balance between commitment and flexibility, and (2) adjust incentives to avoid collectively sub-optimal outcomes. The Greek debt crisis following the 2008 recession is illustrative of this challenge. The crisis stems from 2009, when the Greek finance ministry announced that previous governments had hidden debt levels, a revelation that caused Greek bond yields to skyrocket. Amidst fears of a default, the IMF and EU intervened with a bailout deal that included demands for budget reform. Three bailouts later, the Greek economy is still roiling from these events. Could the crisis have been averted with a different set of institutional rules regarding the accumulation of public debt? Specifically, would a constitutional balanced-budget provision have had any effect? Some clearly think so. Following the European financial crisis, countries took steps to entrench budget rules constitutionally. The European Fiscal Compact (formally, the Treaty on Stability, Co- ordination, and Governance in the Economic and Monetary Union), which entered into force for 16 ratifying states in January 2013, represents a binding commitment to do such. By April 2014, all twenty-five signatories had ratified the treaty. Under the treaty, signatories must implement domestic legal changes that require a balanced budget. The treaty requires that provisions be implemented in 1 domestic law, \preferably" in constitutions (Fiscal Compact, Article 3, Section 2). Although the compact is not formally EU law, its provisions allow for enforcement through the European Court of Justice, which can levy a fine of up to 0.1 percent of GDP for noncompliance (Fiscal Compact, Article 8). While the compact does not require that signatories enact a constitutional provision, a strong preference for a constitutionalized budget law represents an extraordinary attempt to tie governments' hands. This preference for constitutionalization was not added lightly; some governments (e.g., Ireland) resisted any such language { a recognition, perhaps, of the strength of constitutional commitment.1 As of January 2019, seven of the twenty-five signatories had constitutionalized a balanced-budget provision.2 The Greek and broader European experience is not unique. Austerity proponents in the United States periodically issue calls to add a constitutional balanced budget clause to the constitution. Re- searchers at the U.S. Congressional Research Service have documented dozens of such proposals and seemingly continual legislative committee hearings and floor debates since the 1930's (Saturno and Lynch 2018). A statement from Texas Senator John Cornyn in 2016 captures the standard line in favor of such a rule: \we are on an unsustainable course, and so far we've done nothing to address it. We can address our nation's runaway debt through a balanced budget amendment, the kind of fiscal rule that can put us back on course" (emphasis added).3 It is not surprising to hear calls for austerity from conservative leaders (especially in campaign mode) and a balanced-budget rule is a straightforward articulation of that view. Yet even left-oriented politicians have supported balanced budget amendments. In 1995, then Senator Biden, explaining his support for a balanced budget amendment in a New York Times op-ed, wrote \The question for me is not whether the budget must be in perfect balance. The question is whether we can indefinitely sustain deficits of 200 billion and more without permanently and dangerously limiting future options for our children's generation."4 Of course, these calls may ring hollow in a constitutional environment like that in the United States where amendments are rarely adopted. As we will show, the seeming futility of balanced-budget adoption at the federal level in the United States is exceptional. A growing number of national constitutions contain such a provision, especially now that international organizations and treaties encourage the practice. Unfortunately, policy makers in capi- 1See Burret and Schnellenbach (2014) for more on the fiscal compact. Kohler and Koenig (2015) provide an analysis of the Stability and Growth Pact and find that it produced uneven deficit-reducing results since 1999. 2Balanced-budget provisions are tracked by the Comparative Constitutions Project and in-force provisions for such are available online at constituteproject.org 3Juliegrace Brufke. "Senate GOP Lawmakers Want Balanced Budget Amendment Added To Constitution." The Libertarian Republican 17 March 2016. 4Joe Biden. '\Why I switched." The New York Times. 25 February 1995. 2 tal cities can only guess at the effects of these laws. Because politicians often hurdle the \parchment barriers" of higher law, it remains an open question as to whether balanced budget provisions are effective at control- ling public debt.5 Moreover, countries that undertake the extreme measure of requiring a balanced budget in their constitution may be those that are most in need of fiscal discipline, and hence least likely to be solvent. Conversely, adopters may be those countries in which fulfilling such a provision is easiest, leading analysts to overestimate the provision's effectiveness. Whichever group is more susceptible, the motivation for implementing such provisions must be considered in any analysis of their effects. This article is among the first to assess cross-nationally whether constitutional balanced budget provisions contribute to less deficit spending.6 We do so by leveraging yearly data on constitutional provisions covering 52 countries from 1950 to 2011, and comparing the effects of constitutional provisions to lower-level, statutory budget rules. We begin by reviewing work on the role of constitutional provisions in budgetary governance. Second, we expand on theories of constitutions as both commitment and coordination devices and apply these theories to budget law. In this vein, we develop theory about the kinds of provisions in constitutions that are most likely to be enforced. Third, we describe some of the historical detail and distribution of balanced-budget provisions in the world's constitutions. Finally, we analyze cross-national time-series data on the relationship between budget provisions (constitutional and statutory) and budget balances. We also analyze within-country data on balances over time for a small set of cases that experienced a shift in their constitutional provision on balanced budgets. On the whole, the evidence
Recommended publications
  • Working Paper No. 222
    Money and Taxes: The Chartalist L. Randall Wray” Working Paper No. 222 January 1998 *Senior Scholar, The Jerome Levy Economics Institute L. Rnndull Wray Introductory Quotes “A requirement that certain taxes should be paid in particular paper money might give that paper a certain value even if it was irredeemable.” (Edwin Cannan, Marginal Summary to page 3 12 of Adam Smith’s The Wealth of Nations, in Smith 1937: 3 12) “[T]he money of a State is not what is of compulsory general acceptance, but what is accepted at the public pay offices...” (Knapp 1924: vii) “Money is the creation of the state; it is not true to say that gold is international currency, for international contracts are never made in terms of gold, but always in terms of some national monetary unit; there is no important distinction between notes and metallic money.... ” Keynes (Keynes 1983: 402) “In an economy where government debt is a major asset on the books of the deposit- issuing banks, the fact that taxes need to be paid gives value to the money of the economy. The virtue of a balanced budget and a surplus insofar as the commodity value (purchasing power) of money is concerned is that the need to pay taxes means that people work and produce in order to get that in which taxes can be paid.” (Minsky 1986: 23 1) *****k*************X*********************~***********~****** Introduction In conventional analysis, money is used to facilitate exchange; its value was long determined by the value of the precious metal it represented, although under a fiat money system, its value is determined by the quantity of commodities it can purchase.
    [Show full text]
  • A Balanced Budget Constitutional Amendment: Background and Congressional Options
    A Balanced Budget Constitutional Amendment: Background and Congressional Options Updated August 22, 2019 Congressional Research Service https://crsreports.congress.gov R41907 A Balanced Budget Constitutional Amendment: Background and Congressional Options Summary One of the most persistent political issues facing Congress in recent decades is whether to require that the budget of the United States be in balance. Although a balanced federal budget has long been held as a political ideal, the accumulation of large annual budget deficits and the associated growth of public debt in recent years has heightened concern that some action to require a balance between revenues and expenditures may be necessary. The debate over a balanced budget measure actually consists of several interrelated debates. Most prominently, the arguments of proponents have focused on the economy and the possible harm resulting from consistently large deficits and a growing federal debt. Another issue involves whether such a requirement should be statutory or made part of the Constitution. Some proponents of a balanced budget requirement oppose a constitutional amendment, fearing that it would prove to be too inflexible for dealing with future circumstances. Opponents of a constitutional amendment often focus on the difficulties of implementing or enforcing any amendment. Their concerns have been numerous and varied. How would such a requirement affect the balance of power between the President and Congress? Between the federal courts and Congress? Although most proponents would prefer to establish a balanced budget requirement as part of the Constitution, some advocates have suggested using the untried process provided under Article V of the Constitution for a constitutional convention as an alternative to a joint resolution passed by two-thirds vote in both houses of Congress.
    [Show full text]
  • Sustainable Budgeting Brian K
    Western Kentucky University TopSCHOLAR® Economics Faculty Publications Economics 7-2010 Sustainable Budgeting Brian K. Strow Western Kentucky University, [email protected] Claudia W. Strow Western Kentucky University, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.wku.edu/econ_fac_pub Part of the Finance Commons, and the Public Economics Commons Recommended Repository Citation Strow, Brian K. and Strow, Claudia W., "Sustainable Budgeting" (2010). Economics Faculty Publications. Paper 7. http://digitalcommons.wku.edu/econ_fac_pub/7 This Conference Proceeding is brought to you for free and open access by TopSCHOLAR®. It has been accepted for inclusion in Economics Faculty Publications by an authorized administrator of TopSCHOLAR®. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Sustainable Budgeting by Brian K. Strow & Claudia W. Strow Associate Professors of Economics, Department of Economics, Western Kentucky University, 1906 College Heights Blvd., Bowling Green, KY 42101 USA E-mail address: [email protected] Phone: (270) 745-3627 Fax: (270) 745-3190 Abstract At the forefront of current discussion and social conscience is the importance of ecological sustainability. An also important but often overlooked issue is the importance of sustainable budgeting practices for our various levels of government. Governments often provide social services such as food, clothing, shelter, education, public safety, or health care. If the money to pay for the social services comes from additional government debt, social services to future citizens become imperiled. In this paper, the authors set forth a theoretical framework for sustainable government decision making with special emphasis on sustainable governmental budgeting. The authors outline the intricacies of sustainable budgeting, describe why sustainable budgeting is important, and illustrate which countries and states are doing the best and worst jobs of sustainable budgeting.
    [Show full text]
  • The Balanced Budget Amendment and Economic Thought
    CORE Metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk Provided by University of Minnesota Digital Conservancy THE BALANCED BUDGET AMENDMENT AND ECONOMIC THOUGHT Edward Foster* The last decade has seen a continuing effort to amend the Con­ stitution to limit spending by the federal government, require an annually balanced federal budget, or both. The proposed amend­ ment would have a big impact on the economy, and many econo­ mists have spoken out on the subject, mostly in opposition, but some in support. Two related concerns lie behind the movement. First, many people believe that federal spending is excessive. It grew from 3% of total output in 1929 to 13% in 1947 (its low point between the high defense spending of the war years and the domestic spending of the post-war years). The post-war peak was 24.9% in 1982. In 1984, it stood at 24% of output. Opposition to large government stems from (nineteenth century) liberal political philosophy. The economists who support the amendment generally share that phi­ losophy. But part of their justification is more narrowly economic, based on concerns about economic efficiency. High taxes sap incen­ tives, distort economic choices, and waste resources on tax reduc­ tion schemes. On the spending side of the budget, the size of the income flows controlled by government encourages us all to com­ pete for our share, wasting resources in the process. The second concern underlying the amendment is deficit spending. The federal government ran surpluses in seven of the fourteen years after World War II, from 1947 to 1960, but it has done so only once since then, in 1969.
    [Show full text]
  • A Balanced Budget for a Stronger America House Budget Committee | March 2015
    Table of Contents Introduction 3 The Challenges We Face 7 Securing Economic Opportunity 11 Strengthening Health and Retirement Security 16 Protecting the Nation 23 Building Stronger Communities 26 Holding Washington Accountable 30 Appendix I: Long-Term Budget Outlook 33 Appendix II: CBO’s Estimate of the Macroeconomic Effects of Deficit Reduction 34 Appendix III: Summary Tables 36 2 | Page A Balanced Budget for a Stronger America House Budget Committee | March 2015 Introduction At the core of America’s character lies a founding belief that we as a people ought to always strive to build a better, more innovative, open and free society. It’s an understanding and obligation passed down from generation to generation. When we look at America today, we see a nation that is not living up to its economic or leadership potential, and the reason why has nothing to do with the quality and character of the American people. Rather, Washington has been unable or unwilling to tackle big challenges with positive solutions. That has to change. The new normal of slow economic growth and low expectations is unacceptable. We know we can do better. This begins by putting forth a set of solutions that will restore accountability to government so that it serves the needs of its people in the most efficient and effective way possible. In so doing, we will help build an economy that works for all Americans. How do we achieve this? With fiscal and economic policies that shift the focus away from Washington and toward American families, businesses, innovators and local leaders who know the best way forward for their communities.
    [Show full text]
  • Balanced Budget Rules and Fiscal Outcomes: Evidence from Historical Constitutions Zareh Asatryan, Cesar Castellón, and Thomas Stratmann Discus­­ Si­­ On­­ Paper No
    Dis cus si on Paper No. 16-034 Balanced Budget Rules and Fiscal Outcomes: Evidence from Historical Constitutions Zareh Asatryan, Cesar Castellón, and Thomas Stratmann Dis cus si on Paper No. 16-034 Balanced Budget Rules and Fiscal Outcomes: Evidence from Historical Constitutions Zareh Asatryan, Cesar Castellón, and Thomas Stratmann First Version: April 8, 2016 This Version: October 4, 2017 Download this ZEW Discussion Paper from our ftp server: http://ftp.zew.de/pub/zew-docs/dp/dp16034.pdf Die Dis cus si on Pape rs die nen einer mög lichst schnel len Ver brei tung von neue ren For schungs arbei ten des ZEW. Die Bei trä ge lie gen in allei ni ger Ver ant wor tung der Auto ren und stel len nicht not wen di ger wei se die Mei nung des ZEW dar. Dis cus si on Papers are inten ded to make results of ZEW research prompt ly avai la ble to other eco no mists in order to encou ra ge dis cus si on and sug gesti ons for revi si ons. The aut hors are sole ly respon si ble for the con tents which do not neces sa ri ly repre sent the opi ni on of the ZEW. Balanced Budget Rules and Fiscal Outcomes: Evidence from Historical Constitutions Zareh Asatryan∗y Cesar´ Castellon´ z Thomas Stratmannx ∗ZEW yUniversity of Mannheim zClemson University xGeorge Mason University First Version: April 8, 2016 This Version: October 4, 2017 Abstract This paper studies the reduced-form effects of constitutional-level balanced budget rules (BBRs) on fiscal outcomes.
    [Show full text]
  • Nominality of Money: Theory of Credit Money and Chartalism Atsushi Naito
    Review of Keynesian Studies Vol.2 Atsushi Naito Nominality of Money: Theory of Credit Money and Chartalism Atsushi Naito Abstract This paper focuses on the unit of account function of money that is emphasized by Keynes in his book A Treatise on Money (1930) and recently in post-Keynesian endogenous money theory and modern Chartalism, or in other words Modern Monetary Theory. These theories consider the nominality of money as an important characteristic because the unit of account and the corresponding money as a substance could be anything, and this aspect highlights the nominal nature of money; however, although these theories are closely associated, they are different. The three objectives of this paper are to investigate the nominality of money common to both the theories, examine the relationship and differences between the two theories with a focus on Chartalism, and elucidate the significance and policy implications of Chartalism. Keywords: Chartalism; Credit Money; Nominality of Money; Keynes JEL Classification Number: B22; B52; E42; E52; E62 122 Review of Keynesian Studies Vol.2 Atsushi Naito I. Introduction Recent years have seen the development of Modern Monetary Theory or Chartalism and it now holds a certain prestige in the field. This theory primarily deals with state money or fiat money; however, in Post Keynesian economics, the endogenous money theory and theory of monetary circuit place the stress on bank money or credit money. Although Chartalism and the theory of credit money are clearly opposed to each other, there exists another axis of conflict in the field of monetary theory. According to the textbooks, this axis concerns the functions of money, such as means of exchange, means of account, and store of value.
    [Show full text]
  • European Debt and Deficit Rules – Critique and Alternatives DRAFT
    Why 60 and 3 percent? European debt and deficit rules – critique and alternatives DRAFT Paper presented for the 23rd Conference of the Forum for Macroeconomics and Macroeconomic Policies (FMM) 24.-26. October “The Euro at 20 – macroeconomic challenges” Jan Priewe Professor em. of economcs, HTW Berlin – University of Applied Sciences; Senior Research Fellow at IMK – Macroeconomic Policy Institute in Hans-Boeckler- Foundation Berlin, October, 2018 Key words: European Monetary Union, fiscal policy, public debt JEL-Code: E62, E69, F45, H60 Contact: [email protected] 1 Abstract The 60 percent debt limit and the 3 percent deficit cap, invented in Maastricht, are enshrined in the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (TFEU) and the “Fiscal Compact”. These two numbers have become cornerstones of the complex fiscal policy framework of the European Monetary Union (EMU) in the secondary law of the EU. The European authorities never provided sound economic justifications for the 3 and 60 percent rule, especially not for the debt cap. There is no other advanced country outside the EU that has a legal or even a constitutional debt cap. The caps are not stock-flow consistent. Both numbers came into the Maastricht Treaty by incidence. The paper investigates the reasoning for the rules by the European Commission, the IMF and in academia. Indirect support comes from debates about debt sustainability identified with sovereign debt “solvency”, from the IMF-concept of “fiscal space” and theories about intertemporal budget constraints. The implicit balanced budget rule in the EMU rulebook has also roots in Buchanan’s Political Economy of public debt, a pre- Keynesian philosophy.
    [Show full text]
  • Balanced Budget Rules and Fiscal Policy: Evidence from the States James M
    BALANCED BUDGET RULES AND FISCAL POLICY: EVIDENCE FROM THE STATES JAMES M. POTERBA* Against this backdrop, the variation in The persistence of fiscal deficits in many budget practices across states within the industrial democracies has spawned a United States provides a valuable source vast theoretical literature in political econ- of information on the potential effects of omy on why nations run budget deficits, fiscal institutions. One must recognize at along with a sharp policy debate concern- the outset that it is difficult to interpret ing fiscal institutions that might reduce correlations between fiscal institutions these deficits. The debate on fiscal institu- and budget outcomes; budget institutions tions, such as proposed balanced budget may be endogenous. Changes in institu- amendments for the federal government, tions that affect the prospect of deficit fi- involves relatively little empirical evidence nance may reflect changing political sup- on the potential effects of such institu- port for budget deficits, and as such tions. The lack of such evidence can be cannot be viewed as “natural experi- traced to several factors. First, some of ments” in fiscal institutions. Riker (1980) the proposed institutions under discussion argues that essentially all political institu- are budgetary innovations that have not tions reflect the “congealed preferences” been tried on a national or subnational of the electorate. Institutions that no scale before. Second, there is relatively lit- longer suit a majority of the electorate tle intranational variation over time in the will be overturned. This harsh view is nature of budget processes. Therefore, it probably too extreme, because at least is difficult to compare fiscal policy before some of the variation in state fiscal insti- and after significant institutional reforms.
    [Show full text]
  • UK Sovereign Wealth Fund to Which Governments Take Place in Westminster Hall on 14 December 2016 at 9:30Am
    DEBATE PACK Number CDP 2016/0243, 9 December 2016 Matthew Keep, UK Sovereign Wealth Jennifer Brown, Matthew Ward Fund Contents 1. Background 2 Summary What is a sovereign wealth fund? 2 This pack has been prepared ahead of the debate on a UK sovereign wealth fund to Which governments take place in Westminster Hall on 14 December 2016 at 9:30am. The subject for the operate a sovereign debate has been chosen by John Penrose MP. wealth fund? 2 Why have foreign governments set up There is some disagreement about what defines a sovereign wealth fund, but generally: sovereign wealth funds? 2 • they are investment funds that are directly owned by a sovereign government A sovereign wealth fund • they invest in a range of domestic and international assets seeking returns on for the UK? 3 their investment • they are typically funded from government budget surpluses, often arising from 2. Press Articles 4 significant exports of commodities such as oil 3. Press releases 6 4. Parliamentary Over 30 countries have sovereign wealth funds, many are based on receipts from oil material 8 and gas. Norway has the largest fund with assets of $885 billion. 4.1 Debates 8 4.2 Statements 8 The UK government doesn’t have a sovereign wealth fund and the Government 4.3 Parliamentary currently has no plans to introduce one; its focus is on reducing the deficit and Questions 8 decreasing government debt. 5. Further reading 14 The sponsor of this debate, John Penrose MP, has published a report proposing that the UK establishes a sovereign wealth fund once the UK government reaches a budget surplus.
    [Show full text]
  • Price Level Determinacy and Monetary Policy Under a Balanced-Budget Requirement
    Price Level Determinacy and Monetary Policy under a Balanced-Budget Requirement Stephanie Schmitt-Groh´e Mart´n Uribe Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System April 1997 Abstract This paper analyzes the implications of a balanced budget fiscal policy rule for the determinacy of the price level in a cash–in–advance economy under three alternative monetary policy regimes. It shows that in such stylized models with flexible prices and a period–by–period balanced budget requirement the price level is determinate under a money growth rate peg and is indeterminate under a pure nominal interest rate peg. Under a feedback rule whereby the nominal interest rate is set as an increasing function of the inflation rate the price level is determinate for intermediate values of the inflation elasticity of the feedback rule and is indeterminate for both very low and very high values of the inflation elasticity. Finally, regardless of the particular monetary policy specification, a rational expectations equilibrium consistent with the optimal quantity of money may not exist. JEL Classification Numbers: E63, E52, E31 We would like to thank Dale Henderson, Eric Leeper, and seminar participants at the Board of Governors, Indiana University, and Michigan State University for comments. The opinions expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect views of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System or other members of its staff. Address for correspondence: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Washington DC 20551; [email protected] or [email protected]. 1 Introduction In the past decade, the idea of imposing fiscal discipline through a balanced-budget rule has gained con- siderable importance in the economic policy debate.
    [Show full text]
  • The Politics of the Coffee Economy: the Conflicts Between the Republican
    9961 - The politics of the coffee economy: the conflicts between the republican ISSN: 2177 ISSN: oligarchies in Taubaté's Convention Project Caio César Vioto de Andrade• Abstract: This paper intends to deal with the approval process of the Taubaté Convention, in 1906, YEAR X, No. 20, December 2019 during the Rodrigues Alves government, which sought to solve the crisis generated by the fall in international coffee prices, the country's main export product since at least 1895. Towards the history of the politics, from Rosanvallon (2010), we consider the idea of "history making itself" that deals with how social and political actors understand a situation and how the political scope is permeated in modernity by tensions and conflicts, from which emanate social reflections and transformations, starting from political activity. In this way, we consider that the intervention of the State in the coffee economy, symbolized by the Convention, was not only an economic inevitability, but a political choice, after intense conflicts within the most important oligarchies of the First Republic, especially that of Sao Paulo, the main interested in the coffee valorization, and which conflicted with the President of the Republic, hesitant about the project. Keywords: Taubaté Convention, New; First Republic; Political History. Introduction In this article, we intend to explore the political disputes involved around the Taubaté Convention of 1906, a milestone in the policy of intervention in the coffee economy, in the face of the crisis in international coffee prices, which had lasted more than a decade. Our focus is the Rodrigues Alves government, in which discussions about the need and type of measures to be taken to address the problem were intensified, and in which the three main producing states, São Paulo, Minas Gerais and Rio de Janeiro, through their governors, the articulations began on the said Convention.
    [Show full text]