Ending Military Conscription
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
Research Reports ENDING MILITARY Figure 2 presents military recruitment regimes world- wide. Conscription is still dominant in Asia and Africa. CONSCRIPTION* In Latin America the use of conscription has been in a steady decline, with (de facto) abolitions in Uruguay (1989), Nicaragua (1990), Honduras (1994), Argentina PANU POUTVAARA* AND (1995), Peru (1999), Chile (2005) and Ecuador (2008). NDREAS AGENER A W ** While the decision to abolish or maintain the mili- tary draft has country-specific aspects in each single Current trends case, certain groups of motivations for the abolition of conscription can be identified: Throughout most of the 20th century, military con- • Conscription in the US was abolished in 1973, to- scription (the draft) was a prominent feature of na- wards the end of the Vietnam War. Liberal defer- tional military doctrines. Both world wars were ment rules and, later, the use of lotteries had gen- fought mainly by conscripts. Among the 12 founding erated a strong sense of the unfairness and biased countries of NATO in 1949, only Canada did not rely selectiveness of the draft system, which added to on conscription (Iceland did and still does not have the public discontent with the Vietnam War. In armed forces). While the United Kingdom (1960), the debate about the pros and cons of abolishing Luxembourg (1967) and the United States (1973) the draft, economists (most notably Milton Fried- adopted all-volunteer forces quite early during the man) had substantial impact, arguing that con- Cold War, military conscription was the dominant scription is “inequitable, wasteful, and inconsis- mode of peacetime recruitment in the alliance until tent with a free society” (Friedman 1974, 253). mid-1990s. Likewise, throughout the entire existence (1955–91) of the Warsaw Pact, all its members used • In continental Europe, with its dominant histori- conscription. cal view that every citizen has an obligation to Figure 1 maps the changes in mil- Figure 1 itary recruitment across Europe MILITARY RECRUITMENT IN EUROPE, 1993–2011 since 1993 (after the break-up of Czechoslovakia and Yugoslavia). Initially only Ireland, Luxem- bourg, Malta and the United Kingdom relied on all-voluntary service. In 2011, most countries do. The only EU countries still using conscription are Austria, Cyprus, Denmark (in which it is quite easy to avoid the service in practice), Estonia, Finland and Greece. * University of Munich and Ifo Institute for Economic Research. ** University of Hannover and Ifo Insti- tute for Economic Research. We thank Max Ostermayer for helping us Sources: Own compilation, based on Wikipedia (2011), “Conscription” and selected gov- with the figures. ernment sources. CESifo DICE Report 2/2011 36 Research Reports Figure 2 tarism, human rights violations, MILITARY RECRUITMENT AROUND THE WORLD economic mismanagement and corruption. In the wake of demo- cratization, armed forces suffered considerable losses in prestige, leading civilian goverments in quite a number of countries to abolish or suspend conscription. Typically, also countries without conscription during peacetime re- tain the option to re-introduce conscription in case of war – when it might be infeasible to mobilize Sources: Own compilation, based on CIA (2011), “World Factbook”, Wikipedia (2011) “Conscription” and selected government sources. the necessary manpower by vol- unteers or through fiscal taxes perform some service at the call of the state, the alone. Similar arguments can explain the use of con- decline in the use of conscription followed the scription in countries like Israel, where the military end of the Cold War. After the collapse of the doctrine relies on the ability to mobilize most citi- Soviet Union and the end of the Warsaw Pact, zens to fight in case of a large-scale conflict. European governments no longer saw the need to Generally, there is a positive correlation between the prepare for large-scale warfare in Europe. This military threat perceived by countries and their use allowed many countries to seek budgetary savings of conscription (Mjoset and van Holde 2002). The by reducing the sizes of armies and reserves. At recent abolishment of military draft in several the same time, military capabilities were increas- European countries can then be explained by (the ingly aimed at peacekeeping and international perception of) reduced military threat after the fall missions for which conscripts are ill-suited and, in of the Iron Curtain. most countries, inadmissible by law. Military tech- nology moved away from territorial mass forces to smaller, mobile units equipped with sophisti- The economic case against conscription cated weaponry, increasing the necessity of pro- fessionalization. The smaller intake of draftees Economists traditionally were and are unambiguous raised equity concerns as conscription was no in favoring a volunteer army (for surveys see Sandler longer hitting the full (male) age cohort but only and Hartley 1995, chapter 6; Warner and Asch 2001 those unlucky enough to be called up to service. or Poutvaara and Wagener 2007a, 2011), echoing Adam Smith’s verdict of the “irresistible superiority • For the Baltic, central and eastern European coun- which a well-regulated standing [i.e., all-volunteer] tries, which all started out with conscript armies, army has over a militia [i.e., temporary conscrip- the prospect of NATO membership meant the tion]” (Smith 1976, 701). Smith’s arguments focus on necessity of downsizing and restructuring their comparative advantage and the benefits from spe- armed forces. The role model of the alliance lead- cialization. Military conscription violates the princi- ers, increasing levels of draft avoidance, and the ple of comparative advantage, which demands that public opinion that conscript forces were a vestige jobs be assigned to those who are relatively most of the Cold War or Soviet totalitarianism promot- productive in doing them, by forcing everybody into ed the eventual abolition of conscription in all a military occupation, irrespective of relative pro- countries except for Estonia (Williams 2005). ductivities. In consequence, the match between peo- ple and jobs will be inefficient. Benefits from spe- • Many Latin American countries were ruled by cialization arise when individuals become more pro- military dictatorships until the 1980s. The juntas ductive due to experience and frequent practice. relied heavily on conscription for military reasons Effective military operations require a considerable (in border disputes and inner conflicts with Mar- degree of training and mastery in handling complex xist movements) as well as for sake of indoctrina- weapon systems. Drafted short-term soldiers are in- tion and social control. During their regimes these ferior to long-term professionals. In combat, the use armies had amassed dismal records of reckless mili- of less advanced military technology, lack of training, 37 CESifo DICE Report 2/2011 Research Reports and the easy availability of apparently expendable Similar studies are, to our knowledge, not available soldiers lead to higher casualties and “cannon-fod- for the more recent abolitions of military conscrip- der”-type battlefield tactics.1 tion, say, in European NATO members. However, some summary indicators may also provide interest- ing insights. Compared to the 1980s, the “militariza- Consequences of the abolition of conscription tion” of society has declined across NATO, both in terms of the share of the labor force working for the Military expenditures, personnel and budgets military (a decline from an average of 2.7 to 1.1 per- cent between the late 1980s and the late 2000s) and, While quite a number of countries have abolished with the notable exception of the US over the past conscription over the past 20 years, a comparative decade, defense expenditures as a share of GDP, study of their experiences – military, fiscal or econo- which dropped from an average of 4.8 to 2.9 percent mic – is still missing. In parts, this is due to the fact that (NATO 2010). For more detailed comparisons, we the abolition of the draft generally runs parallel to group “old” NATO countries (i.e., members as of other changes (say, shifts in political regimes, geo- 1985) in Figures 3 and 4 according to their recruit- political developments or military technologies) that ment regimes. make it difficult to isolate the “pure” draft effects. Econometric analyses are not available, and compar- As Figure 3 shows, there are no obvious differences isons have to be based on rough summary indicators. in military expenditure trends between “old” NATO For the government budget, oper- Figure 3 ating a draft system is generally 3 DEFENCE EXPENDITURES OF "OLD" NATO MEMBERS, 1985–2009 cheaper than a professional army. in 2000 prices % of GDP 7 Conscripts are not paid the mar- 2.5 conscription (a) 6 ket value of their labor service and abolition (b) are granted fringe benefits such as 5 UK and CA 2 USA health plans, family support, old- 4 age provisions, etc., on a much 3 smaller scale than professional sol- 1.5 2 diers (if at all). These savings are 1 partially offset by the generally 1 0 smaller size of all-volunteer forces 1985–89 1990–94 1995–99 2000–04 2005–09 5-year averages (allowed for due to increased pro- 0.5 (a) Unweighted averages across 1985 NATO members using conscription over full period, 1985–2009 (DK, ductivity). In an early study, Oneal GE, GR, NO, TK). (b) Unweighted averages across 1985 NATO members which abolished conscription after 1985 (BE, FR,