<<

FDA SAFETY ALERTS AND FIRM : THE FRIDAY EFFECT AND ITS CONSEQUENCES

Luis Diestre IE Business School Alvarez de Baena, 4 Madrid, 28006, Spain Tel: +34 (91) 5689600 Fax: +34 (91) 5689747 e-mail: [email protected]

Benjamin Barber IV IE Business School Alvarez de Baena, 4 Madrid, 28006, Spain Tel: +34 (91) 5689600 Fax: +34 (91) 5689747 e-mail: [email protected]

Juan Santaló IE Business School Alvarez de Baena, 4 Madrid, 28006, Spain Tel: +34 (91) 5689600 Fax: +34 (91) 5689747 e-mail: [email protected]

Work in progress, please do not cite or circulate without permission

1

We integrate the corporate political activity literature with impression management research to explore whether lobbying allows firms to influence the timing of negative news by the

FDA. First, we show that FDA safety alerts announced on Fridays experience a lower diffusion by healthcare experts and the media. Furthermore, we find that firms who lobby the FDA are more likely to have safety alerts for their drugs announced on Fridays. We find this effect to be stronger for severe safety alerts. Finally, we explore the implications of the lower diffusion of Friday safety alerts and find that, although safety alerts are in general effective in reducing patients’ adverse effects, this effectiveness is substantially lower for alerts announced on Fridays.

Specifically, compared to non-Friday alerts, Friday safety alerts are associated with 30% more deaths, 28% more serious adverse events (death, hospitalization, disability, life-threatening, and/or congenital anomaly) and 26% more adverse events in general.

2

Firms are dependent on governments and public institutions for their success (Bonardi,

Hillman, and Keim, 2005; De Figueiredo and Richter, 2014; Hillman, Keim, and Schuler, 2004).

Public officials determine firms’ fates by restricting market entry (e.g., issuing licenses), determining the competitive environment (e.g., regulating prices and issuing patents), or administering sanctions (e.g., issuing fines for regulatory non-compliance). Given this strong dependence on the public sphere, it is not surprising firms undertake political activities to cope with the inherent policy uncertainty. Firm’s political activities have been shown to influence decisions about taxes (Richter, Samphantharak, and Timmons, 2009), federal contracts (Ridge,

Ingram, and Hill, 2017), and regulated prices (Bonardi, Holburn, and Bergh, 2006). Overall, the corporate political activities (CPA) literature has provided rich evidence that political efforts can shape public officials’ decisions in the firm’s favor.

Yet, government officials not only make policy decisions but, in the majority of the cases, they also communicate these decisions to the public. This communication is critically important since the way officials communicate news can affect the firm as much as the content of the decisions themselves. Prior impression management studies show how the manner in which corporate news are communicated to external audiences—e.g., when is the information made public, or through which channel—strongly determines external audiences’ interpretation and reaction to that new information (Elsback, Sutton, and Principe 1998; Graffin, Haleblian, and

Kiley, 2016). When it comes to policy decisions this is especially true. Because there is a lot of uncertainty about how a new policy will affect a specific company, the way in which a firm’s stakeholders will interpret and react to a policy decision depends on how such decision is communicated. Ideally, then, firms would want policy decisions be communicated to the public in the way that triggers the most positive (or least negative) reactions. This is exactly what firms

3 do when it comes to communicating internal corporate news: the impression management literature has provided broad evidence that firms are very strategic when designing their communication activities in an attempt to manage audiences’ perceptions (Bolino, Kacmar,

Turnley, and Gilstrap, 2008; Elsbach, 2006, 2012; Graffin et al., 2016). Yet, when it comes to policy decisions, it is public officials, not firms, who communicate news to the public. The question is then: can firms “persuade” public officials to implement impression management tactics similar to the ones firms implement when they communicate internal corporate news? Are political activities helpful not only at shaping policy-making, but also at shaping policy- communication? To our knowledge, this is an unexplored question in the CPA literature.

We aim to fill this gap by looking at a specific type of policy communication: the reporting of drug safety news by the U.S. Food and Drug Administration (FDA). The FDA is responsible for identifying and reporting potential safety issues on marketed pharmaceutical drugs. When the agency discovers that a marketed drug has a previously unknown side-effect that represents a risk for patients’ health, it releases a safety alert communication where it explains the severity and scope of the drug’s safety issues, and the suggested changes in doctors’ prescription behavior. Obviously, these alerts have negative consequences for the firm selling the drug (Chen, Ganesan, and Liu, 2009). First, the announcement that the firm missed an important side-effect during the development of the drug is likely to trigger a negative reputation, which may lead to greater scrutiny in the future (Ahmed, Gardella, and Nanda, 2002; Dowdell,

Govindaraj, and Jain, 1992; Cheah, Chang, and Chieng, 2007). In addition, drug sales are likely to drop due to changes in doctors’ prescription behavior and patients’ reactions to safety scandals

(Dusetzina et al., 2012; Hurren, Taylor and Jaber, 2011).

4

In this study, we claim that the magnitude of these negative consequences will depend upon the way the FDA releases the news. Prior research in impression management has identified several factors that are likely to affect how strongly external audiences react to negative corporate news (Bolino et al., 2008; Elsbach, 2006, 2012). In this study we focus on one particular factor: the timing of the communication. How stakeholders react to safety news depends upon how quickly, and broadly, such news diffuses. Key information intermediaries, i.e. the media and industry experts, typically are the ones to provide this type of technical news to the public, however these intermediaries’ attention is not constant over time (Deephouse and

Heugens, 2009; Hoffman and Ocasio, 2001). A large literature on organizational behavior and labor economics has shown how cognitive attention varies significantly over the workweek.

Specifically, on Fridays productivity and motivation are at the lowest (Accountemps, 2013;

Sotak et al., 2015), absenteeism is at the highest (Herrman and Rockoff, 2012; Johns and Hajj,

2016; Miller Murnane, and Willet, 2008), and professionals work the least amount of hours

(Beckers et al., 2008; Harrison and Hulin, 1989; Nader et al., 2012). This means professionals are less likely to pay attention, assess, and react to events happening on Fridays. We build on this logic to propose that healthcare professionals and media will be less attentive to FDA safety alerts that take place on Fridays. Accordingly, we expect Friday alerts to experience a slower and narrower diffusion. This means that the negative consequences associated with safety alerts— negative reputation and drop in sales—should be less negative for Friday alerts.

Based on this, we expect firms will prefer their safety alerts reported on Fridays. We build on the CPA literature to examine whether firms’ corporate political activities, specifically lobbying activities, allow them to influence when the FDA communicates safety alerts. We argue that lobbying establishes a communication channel with the FDA, increasing firms’ ability to

5 influence public officials’ decisions about when to release safety news. Given that firms are likely to prefer low diffusion of safety news, we predict that corporate lobbying should increase the probability that a firm’s alert is announced on a Friday.

We then build on the assumption that firms have limited political capital. With limited political capital firms cannot exploit their relationship with public officials without some cost.

Under this assumption, we expect firms to be selective and use their political influence when it is most valuable. In our context, we expect that firms will be more likely to use their influence on the FDA for severe safety alerts—i.e., those that have a dramatic impact on patients’ health.

These alerts are more likely to trigger a stronger reputational loss and a larger drop in drug sales

(Cheah et al., 2007). Therefore, we expect that the positive effect of lobbying on the probability that an alert is issued on a Friday will be greater for severe safety alerts.

We test our predictions in a sample of 441 safety alerts reported by FDA between 1999 and 2016. First, we find that alerts reported on Fridays receive weaker diffusion by healthcare experts and mass media. To capture diffusion by healthcare experts we look at whether such experts shared safety alert news within their professional network (retweets of safety alert news in their twitter accounts), whereas to capture diffusion by mass media we look into the number of articles in U.S. newspapers covering a specific safety alert. We find that Friday alerts have far less retweets and news articles than alerts announced any other weekday. Furthermore, we find that firm lobbying increases the chances of having an alert released on a Friday by 63%. The effect is even greater for drugs whose consequences for patients’ health were severe. In these cases, the chance of a Friday alert goes from about 12% for non-lobbying firms to roughly 40% for lobbying firms. This suggests that firms strategically use their political connections to

(indirectly) implement impression management tactics in the release of negative policy news.

6

Finally, we examine the public health implications of the implementation of this Friday effect. The goal of safety alerts is to inform patients and doctors of new side-effects so they can adjust their prescription and consumption behavior accordingly and stop experiencing those negative effects (Dusetzina et al., 2012; Hurren et al., 2011). Yet, if Friday safety alerts experience a narrower and slower diffusion, it may be the case that those alerts announced on

Fridays are less effective in reducing patients’ adverse reactions. We explore this potential public health implication relying on the FDA’s Adverse Event Reporting System (FAERS), a database providing information about adverse events suffered by patients on specific drugs, and we find support for our suspicion. Specifically, we find that the number of reported medical complications decreases in the days after a safety alert communication, but that this decrease is significantly weaker for Friday alerts. Specifically, the consequences on health are significant:

Friday safety alerts are associated with 30% more deaths, 28% more serious complications

(death, hospitalization, disability, life-threatening, and/or congenital anomaly), and 26% more complaints in general.

CONTEXT: DRUG SAFETY ALERTS

One of the roles of the FDA—the regulatory agency for pharmaceutical products in the

U.S.—is to develop and disseminate information to the public regarding safety issues on marketed drugs (CDER, 2007). After a drug is approved, the FDA may learn of new adverse experiences (i.e., new side effects in a subpopulation of patients) from post-approval clinical studies or patients’ reports to the FDA. When such information becomes available, the agency actively engages in scientific efforts to evaluate whether there is indeed a potential drug safety concern that should be communicated to the public and healthcare professionals. All this evidence is evaluated by the Drug Safety Oversight Board (a branch of the FDA), which is

7 responsible of deciding whether the emerging drug safety information should be made public or not. With each new piece of evidence, the board faces the tension between the goal of having people informed about potentially important safety information as early as possible and the goal of having that information thoroughly substantiated (CDER 2007). Thus, only when the Drug

Safety Oversight Board has concluded that the evidence of a causal relationship between the drug and the adverse events is reliable enough, such safety information is communicated.

Safety information is made public in the form of safety alert communications. Safety alerts provide the following information: a description of the newly found adverse effects (i.e., summary of the scientific findings) and a set of recommendations for healthcare professionals regarding how/when the drug should be prescribed based on the new evidence (changes in the drug’s label). Since 1993, these safety alerts are communicated through the FDA’s MedWatch web site. In addition, patients and healthcare professionals can obtain safety alert updates from other channels such as email subscription or, since 2011, the FDA’s MedWatch twitter account.

We believe this is an ideal context to examine whether firms’ political efforts can influence public officials’ communication activities for the following reasons. First, these alerts have negative consequences for the firm. They usually harm the firm through a reputational crisis and a drop in sales (Chen et al., 2009; Dusetzina et al., 2012; Hurren et al., 2011). Second, although safety alerts are communications that clearly affect firm outcomes, the firm has little, if any, influence on the process under which safety alerts emerge. Attending to the FDA’s statutes regarding the communication of safety information (CDER, 2007), the FDA has no obligation to keep the firm informed of its decisions on how and when to communicate safety information.

The FDA specifically states that it will “intend to inform the sponsor [the firm marketing the drug] at least 24 hours before the alert is communicated” but it is not bound to do so. This

8 suggests that firms, not only have little influence on how and when safety information regarding their drugs will be communicated to the public, but also have little information about how the

FDA is managing the whole process or that such a process is taking place at all. This is a context, then, where political activities can make a difference in that they may create a relationship between the firm and the agency that is more permeable to the transfer of information giving the firm a way to influence the process. We explore such a possibility in the following sections.

THEORY AND HYPOTHESES

We build on attention-based theories (Barnett, 2014; Hoffman and Ocasio, 2001; Ocasio,

1997, 2011) to analyze how safety alerts communicated on Fridays are diffused less broadly than alerts communicated any other weekday.1 Next, we draw from the CPA literature to examine how firms may strategically influence the timing of safety alert communications to their advantage: we explore if firm lobbying increases the probability that alerts are issued on Fridays.

The diffusion of safety alerts: Information intermediaries’ attention

The process through which external audiences are informed about corporate events is mediated by information intermediaries—e.g., media or industry experts (Dalton et al., 1998;

Deephouse, 2000; Lounsbury and Rao, 2004; Pollock and Rindova, 2003; Rao, Greve, and

Davis, 2001). These information intermediaries play the role of information brokers that determine what information regarding organizations reaches external audiences and when/how is the information communicated (Deephouse and Heugens, 2009; Madsen and Rodgers, 2015).

Yet, because the attention of information intermediaries is selective, and some events are more likely to capture their attention than others, not all events are equally diffused to the general public (Deephouse and Heugens, 2009; Hoffman and Ocasio, 2001; Ocasio, 1997, 2011).

1 Safety alerts are not issued on the weekends. 9

Information intermediaries’ selective attention has both, cognitive and motivational roots

(Kaplan and Henderson, 2005; Ocasio, 2011). The motivational view proposes that people’s goals, intentions and prior beliefs determine what events they pay attention to (Barnett, 2014;

Ocasio, 2011). Consistent with this, prior work finds that events that resonate more tightly with the intermediary’s identity and agenda, in the case of mass media outlets for example, have a greater likelihood of capturing their attention (Deephouse and Heugens, 2009).

The cognitive view of selective attention recognizes that there are multiple stimuli competing for people’s limited attention (Ocasio, 1997), meaning that individual and situational factors affecting people’s cognitive capabilities are likely to determine why some events are paid attention instead of others (Barnett, 2014). Information intermediaries are professional individuals (e.g., mass media journalists and industry experts) that in order to cover and diffuse an event they need to (a) notice the event, (b) assess the event, and (c) react to the event (Barnett,

2014; Deephouse and Heugens, 2009; Hoffman and Ocasio, 2001). Noticing, assessing, and reacting are activities that clearly demand information intermediaries’ cognitive resources, yet the amount of cognitive resources available are not constant. This means that those events that take place when information intermediaries’ cognitive capabilities are at their lowest level are the ones with a greater probability fall under the radar of intermediaries’ attention and thus experience a lower diffusion to external audiences.

In our study, we argue that one of the reasons why information intermediaries’ cognitive capabilities are not constant is the presence of a weekly pattern: cognitive capabilities are systematically lower in certain days of the week. Specifically, we propose that information intermediaries’ cognitive resources are at their lowest level on Fridays. Extant evidence in the organizational behavior and labor economics literatures is consistent with this claim. First,

10 research on employee motivation, a key determinant of cognitive resources, shows that motivation peaks on Mondays and Tuesdays, and is lowest on Fridays (Sotak et al., 2015). In a similar vein, surveys on employee productivity reveal that Tuesdays is the weekday in which employees report being most productive, while Fridays is the weekday in which productivity is the lowest (Accountemps, 2013). Research looking at absenteeism—when cognitive capabilities are simply null—reported higher levels of absenteeism on Fridays (Herrman and Rockoff, 2012;

Johns and Hajj, 2016; Miller et al., 2008), as well as a greater probability that employees take vacation days (paid absenteeism) on Fridays (Harrison and Hulin, 1989). In addition, studies looking at the allocation of working hours throughout the week by professionals with time flexibility (e.g., academics) found that such professionals worked the least amount of hours on

Fridays (Beckers et al., 2008; Nader et al., 2012), which implies that such weekday is the one in which employees have less cognitive resources available for their work-related activities. Recent studies in finance and accounting provide further evidence of this effect by showing how stock analysts and investors are less likely to react to events taking place on Fridays (quarterly earnings [DellaVigna and Pollet, 2009; Hirshleifer, Lim, and Teoh, 2009] and mergers and acquisitions [Louis and Sun, 2010]). This is consistent with the claim that such professionals’ cognitive resources are lower those days of the week. All this evidence that professionals exhibit a lower cognitive capacity on Fridays implies that information intermediaries will be less likely to attend to Friday events and, thus, such events will be diffused less broadly.

We apply this rationale into our context, where we explore the diffusion of information concerning the safety of pharmaceutical drugs. Safety-related information may arise from many different sources (e.g., federal agencies, patient advocacy groups, or scientific journals). Thus, keeping up to date with all those sources requires an amount of time and effort that many

11 external audiences lack (Advera, 2013). Therefore, this context is clearly one where information intermediaries play a fundamental role as brokers that disseminate safety news. In this context there are at least two main information intermediaries: healthcare experts and mass media.

Healthcare experts represent one of the key intermediaries that diffuse safety-related information within the healthcare community (Advera, 2013). Those healthcare professionals that cover drug safety events play the role of opinion leaders, and thus represent an important source of safety- related information. Mass media, in addition, is an active diffusor of safety-related information about pharmaceutical products. Major safety scandals are broadly covered in media news and represent an effective channel through which such information reaches the general public

(Ahmed et al., 2002; Cheah et al., 2007). Then, applying the logic proposed above whereby information intermediaries’ attention is lower on Fridays, we expect that healthcare professionals and media—i.e., the key information intermediaries in our context—will be less likely to diffuse safety alerts released on Fridays. This leads to our first two hypotheses:

Hypothesis 1a: The diffusion of safety alerts through healthcare experts will be lower for

safety alerts announced on Fridays.

Hypothesis 1b: The diffusion of safety alerts through mass media will be lower for safety

alerts announced on Fridays.

Consequences of FDA safety alerts

The publication of a drug safety alert by the FDA has several negative consequences for the firm marketing the drug: a reputational loss and a drop in sales (Chen et al., 2009; Dusetzina et al., 2012; Hurren et al., 2011). First, these communications are likely to affect the firm’s reputation (Ahmed et al., 2002; Dowdell et al., 1992; Cheah et al., 2007). External audiences

12 may interpret this event as a signal of the presence of key weaknesses in the firm’s drug development activities. Maybe the reason why such safety alert took place is that the firm lacks the ability to identify safety liabilities during clinical tests, which means that more safety alerts may take place for other drugs in the future. This reputational shock may have strong consequences for the firm in terms of a greater scrutiny in future drug development projects.

Moreover, a lower reputation may translate into a lower ability to attract consumers, alliance partners, and even employees. Also, the stigmatization that follows one of such safety crisis may hamper the firm’s ability to secure support from key stakeholders in the industry, such as advocacy groups or consumer associations.

Second, beyond a reputational loss, firms are likely to experience a drop in sales after safety alerts. There is evidence in the medical literature that safety alerts are followed by a reduction in drug consumption (Dusetzina et al., 2012; Hurren et al., 2011). Safety alert communications dictate new prescription recommendations for healthcare professionals.

Therefore, when doctors become aware of these new prescription recommendations they are likely to reduce the medication of those patients that are subject to the safety risks reported in the safety alert. In addition, patients may decide to stop taking that medication—or do not start taking it in the case of new users—without the advice of a doctor, or irrespective of the doctor’s recommendation (Dusetzina et al., 2012). Given the sense of urgency and alarm that many of these safety crises generate, it is not rare that patients stop taking a medication after an alert even before seeking medical advice (Szefler, Whelan, and Leung, 2006).

We now claim that all these costs will vary across safety alerts. Specifically, we claim the drop in sales and the reputational loss that follows a safety alert communication will be lower for alerts released on Fridays. Because Friday alerts are less likely to be diffused by healthcare

13 experts (H1a) and mass media (H1b), we expect Friday alerts to generate the least negative consequences for the firm. First, we expect that doctors will be less likely to adjust their prescription behavior after Friday alerts. Safety-related information may arise from many different sources (e.g., federal agencies, patient advocacy groups, or scientific journals) and doctors complain that they lack the time to keep up to date with all those sources (Advera, 2013).

They acknowledge that, frequently, the way in which they firstly become informed about safety issues is through their close professional network: conference meetings, conversations with specialists, sharing best practices and information with other doctors (Advera, 2013).2

This means that the probability that doctors get to know about safety news is partly determined on how broad and fast such information diffuses throughout the network of healthcare professionals. That is, it depends on the extent to which safety experts in the healthcare community—the opinion leaders on safety-related information—diffuse safety news. Given that such experts are less likely to diffuse safety alerts taking place on Fridays (H1a), we expect that in these cases it will take longer for doctors to adjust their prescription behavior.

Second, when it comes to patients, these are unlikely to follow FDA alerts directly from the MedWatch alert system. Instead, patients usually obtain safety-related information from mass media. Then, since Friday alerts receive lower media coverage (H1b), and thus are less likely to trigger a strong sense of alarm, we expect a weaker reaction by patients to such alerts—i.e., a lower probability that they stop taking the medication.

2 One would think that doctors become immediately informed about safety issues, yet this does not seem to be the case (Advera, 2013). These professionals frequently complain that they do not get updated quickly enough on safety-related issues, which means that in some cases there might be a significant delay until they incorporate new safety information in their prescription decisions (Advera, 2013). Although doctors will ultimately get informed about new safety information thanks to changes in the drug’s label and in the software doctors use to prescribe medications, these changes are not immediate. 14

Finally, if other key stakeholders such as advocacy groups, investors, competitors, or scientists, are less likely to be informed about Friday alerts due to the weaker diffusion of such alerts through the healthcare network and mass media (H1a and H1b), we expect that, not only the potential drop in sales, but also the reputational loss that follows safety alerts will be weaker for Friday alerts. The weaker coverage by media and industry experts of Friday alerts implies a lower probability that the alert leads to a scandal.

Lobbying and the timing of FDA safety alerts

All this means that, if firms could choose when to release safety alerts, they would rather have them issued on Fridays in that this would reduce the negative consequences associated to such alerts. Yet, firms do not announce safety alerts, the FDA does. The question is then: can a firm persuade the FDA into releasing a safety alert on a Friday? To answer this question, we first need to understand how the FDA itself decides when to communicate safety alerts.

Once the FDA learns about a potential safety concern, its role is to gather as much evidence and information as possible so that it can determine if the safety concern is indeed associated with the consumption of the drug in question and what subpopulation of patients is affected by such safety issues (CDER, 2007). This task is done by the Drug Safety Oversight

Board, a branch of the FDA that is responsible of deciding whether and when emerging drug safety information should be made public. Only when the Drug Safety Oversight Board believes that there is enough evidence linking the consumption of the drug with the specific safety outcome (e.g., a side-effect), and it has enough information about who is affected by those safety issues, the FDA makes a safety alert communication (CDER, 2007).

In theory then, a firm could influence this process by strategically providing key information to the FDA relative to the causal link between the drug’s consumption and the safety

15 concern, as well as information about which patients are affected by such safety concern. Firms are likely to have information about this issue—obtained through its pre- and post-marketing clinical trials—and this information could affect the Drug Safety Oversight Board’s assessment about when to issue the safety alert. Thus, providing such information to the Drug Safety

Oversight Board is one way in which a firm could influence the timing of safety alert communications. The problem, however, is that the Drug Safety Oversight Board is a branch of the FDA to which firms have little access, meaning that firms are likely to be unaware that a safety evaluation of one of their drugs is taking place. Attending to the FDA’s statutes regarding the communication of safety information (CDER, 2007), the FDA has no obligation to inform the firm about the fact that it is evaluating the safety of one of its drugs. The FDA will “intend to inform the sponsor [the firm marketing the drug] at least 24 hours before the alert is communicated” but it is not bound to do so. This means that an information provision strategy is hard to implement, not only because the firm lacks a direct channel with the Drug Safety

Oversight Board, but also because once the firm is aware that a safety evaluation is taking place it might be too late.

We build on the CPA literature to propose that lobbying activities may provide such a communication channel between the FDA’s Drug Safety Oversight Board and the firm (Hillman and Hitt, 1999; Hillman et al., 2004). Corporate lobbying has in fact been defined as an

“information provision strategy”, a definition that is consistent with the Lobbying Disclosure Act

(2 U.S.C. § 1601) that defines lobbying as the sharing of information with policy makers and agencies by individuals representing the firm interests (Hillman and Hitt, 1999).3 Therefore, lobbying activities towards the FDA may allow to open a communication channel with the

3 Irrespective of whether they were implemented by the firm itself (e.g., through its public affairs department) or through lobbying consulting agencies. 16 agency. Then, this communication channel should allow the firm to provide key information to the agency with respect to the safety concern being evaluated. This should increase the firm’s ability to influence the timing of the whole process, and thus when the safety communication will be made. Moreover, it is important to highlight that such a communication channel may work in both directions, meaning that information may leak from the agency towards the firm as well. This should increase the probability that the firm is aware that a safety evaluation on one of its drugs is taking place, which may give the firm more time to design and implement its information provision strategy in a more effective manner.

In sum, we propose that firms will rather have safety alerts issued on Fridays by the FDA to the extent that the negative consequences of such alerts will be weaker. Firm lobbying, we claim, provides the firm with a potential communication channel with the agency so that it can implement a more effective information provision strategy. This, we argue, increases the firm’s ability to influence the timing of safety alert announcements to its advantage. Consequently, we propose that firm lobbying will increase the probability that a safety alert is issued on a Friday:

Hypothesis 2: Firm lobbying will increase the probability that a safety alert is announced

on a Friday.

Political capital, however, is a finite resource. Lobbying provides a communication channel with the agency that allows the firm to gain influence on the agency’s decisions. Yet, the firm cannot use this influence indiscriminately. There is an opportunity cost associated with using political leverage on the FDA. Then, if firms can only influence a few of the governmental decision-making processes, they will pick the ones that maximize their benefit. Consequently, we expect firms to exploit their political influence—i.e., try to control the timing of the FDA’s

17 safety communications—for those alerts that will trigger the greatest negative consequences for the firm: i.e., alerts that refer to severe safety issues. Severe safety problems are those referring to potential side-effects that may cause dramatic consequences for patients’ health. These concerns are more likely to be diffused by mass media and healthcare experts, and trigger the greatest sense of alarm among patients and the healthcare community (Cheah et al., 2007). Thus, these alerts are the ones that most dramatically affect the reputation of the company (Cheah et al., 2007). Similarly, these are the alerts to which both patients and doctors will react more aggressively, leading to the largest drop in sales (Chen et al., 2009). Accordingly, these are the alerts in which the firm has more to lose if they are not announced on a Friday. Therefore, we expect that firms will be more likely to take advantage of the political influence provided by lobbying activities for severe safety alerts. This leads to our final hypothesis:

Hypothesis 3: The positive effect of firm lobbying on the probability that a safety alert is

announced on a Friday will be greater for severe safety alerts.

METHODS

Data

To test our hypotheses, we compiled data from various sources. First, to identify drug safety alerts we looked into the FDA’s MedWatch website (Carpenter et al., 2012; Cheah et al.,

2007). This web provides information for all safety alerts reported since 1996. Specifically, it provides information about the date the alert was issued, the drug(s) involved in the alert, the nature of the safety problem(s), and the FDA’s new prescription recommendations. The description provided with respect to the nature of the safety concern allowed us to assess the severity of each safety alert, a measure we used to test our last hypothesis.

18

Second, in order to capture coverage and diffusion by healthcare professionals and mass media we relied on two different datasets. To capture dissemination by healthcare experts we look at how many healthcare professionals interested in safety-related issues decided to share safety alerts information. The FDA opened a twitter account in 2011 where it started announcing safety alerts (@medwatch). Since this twitter account only reports safety-related information, it is mainly followed by healthcare professionals with a special interest on drug safety. Therefore, we believe this is a place where we can find healthcare professionals with expertise on safety issues and capture the extent to which these experts disseminate safety-related information.

Accordingly, we look at the number of retweets of the safety alert communications done by the

FDA through its @medwatch twitter account to capture dissemination of safety-related information throughout the healthcare community.

To capture the dissemination of safety alerts by mass media we look into the Factiva database for articles covering safety alerts in U.S. newspapers. Specifically, we searched for all the articles published in between the day of the alert and six days after the alert, where the name of the drug appeared in the article. We then read these drug-related articles and kept those where the article referred to the drug safety alert in question. We build on the assumption that diffusion of safety alerts by these media outlets captures how quickly the public becomes informed about safety news.

To identify how much firms are lobbying the FDA we use data from the Center for

Responsive Politics’ OpenSecrets database.4 This database tracks all lobbying activities disclosed by government mandated reports from registered lobbyists in regard to their lobbying activities. In accordance with the Lobbying Disclosure Act all lobbyists, both internal and

4 https://www.opensecrets.org/ 19 external to the firm, are required to file quarterly reports about their lobbying activities. This database is available for the 1998 to 2016 period, and these reports include the name of the client/employer, lobbying expenditures, and importantly for this study, which agency/agencies were lobbied.

Finally, to create our control measures we draw from the FDA’s orange book database to find information about the drugs that are in the market and the firms that own each of these drugs; and the FDA’s @drugs data to obtain information on the regulatory approval of those drugs (i.e., post-marketing requirements, priority reviews, etc.).

Sample

To create our final list of drug alerts we take the following steps. First, because lobby data (OpenSecrets) is available since 1998, we look at safety alerts for the 1999 to 2016 period.

Second, we only look at alerts on drugs and do not consider alerts on other products such as medical devices. Third, we restrict our sample to safety alerts on branded drugs (i.e., not generics), since for these we can identify the company that owns the drug. Alerts on branded drugs (not generics) represented around 74% of all drug safety alerts in our studied period.

Fourth, we remove those safety alerts that refer to drugs that are owned by more than one company. In these cases, since there is more than one firm linked to the drug, we would not know which firm’s characteristics are affecting our main outcomes, and whose firm’s lobbying activities will influence the timing of the safety alert announcement. Finally, in those few cases where we have more than one alert on the same drug on the same day, we “collapse” both alerts into one single alert. After all these steps, we end up with a sample of 441 drug safety alerts.

For the test in which we look at the diffusion of safety alerts by healthcare experts our sample is smaller. Because we look at the number of experts that retweet the FDA’s MedWacth

20 tweet informing about a safety alert, and this twitter account was opened in 2011, we can only look at alerts between 2011 and 2016. The sample for this test includes 139 drug safety alerts.

Measures

Healthcare experts diffusion. As explained above, we look at the number of retweets done by healthcare experts to safety alert tweets (through the FDA’s MedWatch twitter account).

The FDA opened up the MedWatch twitter account in 2011 to provide a means to disseminate safety alerts information throughout the healthcare community. Those healthcare professionals that play the role of opinion leaders when it comes to safety-related information are likely to follow such twitter account. Thus, we expect that the intensity with which these healthcare experts share and comment the safety alert information through their social median accounts will capture the extent to which such safety alert is diffused.

Mass media diffusion. To capture media diffusion we look at the number of articles that mention each safety alert the day after the FDA makes the announcement. To obtain such information we looked at newspaper articles in the U.S. using the Factiva dataset. Our final measure consistent in the total number of articles in the three days after the safety alert announcement.5

Friday. We create a dummy variable that takes a value of 1 if the safety alert was published on a Friday and 0 otherwise. It may be the case that an alert is released on a Thursday and that Friday is a holiday. We found three of such cases and decided to treat those days as a

Friday in that attention should also we weaker before a holiday.6

5 We tried alternative windows in the robustness tests section. We also tried an alternative measure consisting on a dummy variable taking the value of 1 if there were no news at all on the alert and 0 otherwise (see robustness tests section). 6 Removing these three observations provides almost identical results (available upon request). 21

Lobbying the FDA. We first gather all lobbying activities for those public and private pharmaceutical firms that suffered a drug safety alert. Second, we only account for lobbying efforts that target the FDA, since this is the kind of lobbying that may allow the firm influence the decision on when to announce drug safety alerts. We do not expect, for example, that lobbying the Department of Defense or the Department of Transportation will help firms influence FDA decisions on safety alerts. Then, we create a dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if the firm lobbied the FDA and 0 otherwise.7 We look whether the firm lobbied the FDA in the two years before the safety alert, assuming that such time window captures the presence of political ties with the agency.8

Severity. To capture each safety alert’s severity we constructed a dummy variable that took the value of 1 when the safety risks reported in the safety alert communication refer to major (life-threatening) health problems and 0 otherwise.

Controls. We include several controls in our tests. At the firm level, we add the following measures. First, we control for the number of branded drugs the firm got approved in the last ten years as a proxy for firm size (prior drugs firm). We obtain this information from the FDA’s orange book, which lists all drug approvals for each firm. Second, we control for the number of safety alerts the firm has suffered in all of its drugs in the previous five years, which is obtained from the Medwatch website described above (prior alerts firm). We expect that the presence of prior safety alerts on the same firm may affect how broadly a new safety alert is covered and disseminated. Third, we control for whether the firm is publicly traded or not, as a way to capture the firm’s visibility (firm public). Finally, for our tests looking at how lobbying the FDA affects

7 We tried an alternative measure consisting on the actual amount of lobbying expenditures and we found similar support for our theory (see robustness tests section). 8 We tried two alternative windows, 1-year and 3-year, and found similar support for our theory (see robustness tests section). 22 the probability that a safety alert is announced on a Friday, we also include a control for how much the firm has lobbied agencies other than the FDA (other lobbying). This way we rule out the possibility that our measure of lobby is in reality capturing some firm unobserved factor.

At the drug-alert level, we control for the following factors. First, we include a measure of the number of safety alerts the drug had in the previous five years, which we obtain from the

MedWatch website (prior alerts drug). The presence of previous alerts on the same drug may affect how doctors and patients react to new alerts. Second, we control for whether the drug required post-marketing tests after approval (post-marketing). In some cases, the manufacturer is required by the FDA to undertake post-marketing clinical trials to assess some safety aspects about the drug that could not be assessed during drug development, and this may affect how the healthcare community reacts to safety news. Third, we also include the average number of adverse events on the drug in the year before the alert, to control for the safety characteristics of the drug before the communication (prior adverse events). Fourth, we add a dummy variable that takes the value of 1 if there were other alerts communicated that same day and 0 otherwise (other alerts) and another dummy that takes the value of 1 if the alert in question refers to more than one single drug in its communication and 0 otherwise (other drugs). Finally, we include a control for whether the drug enjoyed a priority review (priority review) and the logged number of days since the FDA approved the drug (time since approval). If the FDA is seen as needlessly fast- tracking the drug, this could be seen as the FDA acting too quickly. Likewise, if the drug has problems soon after the FDA approved the drug as safe and effective, the FDA might be seen in a negative light. In both cases the FDA may have an interest to communicate the alert in a day that the reaction will be weaker, i.e., a Friday.

Analysis

23

Identification strategy

For our tests on the effect of Friday on healthcare experts diffusion and mass media diffusion, due to the count nature of these outcomes, we relied on a negative binomial estimation

(H1a and H1b).9 When we test the effect of lobbying the FDA and alert severity on Friday, given the binary nature of this dependent variable, we use a logistic regression estimation (H2 and H3).

We include year fixed-effects to control for temporal dynamics in the reaction to drug safety alerts in all of our estimations.

Note that the regressions on the effect of Friday on healthcare experts diffusion and mass media diffusion may report biased coefficients if the day in which alerts are announced is not exogenous. According to our theory, firms may be influencing the announcement day. Hence, there may be a positive correlation on the likelihood that an alert is announced on a Friday and the importance of the alert for the firm, i.e., how much coverage the alert will receive. This means that the coefficient of the Friday variable may be upwards biased. In the results section below we show how the effect of Friday on the number of retweets and media articles is negative and significant. Therefore, if this coefficient is upwards biased, the real impact of announcing alerts on Fridays should be even more negative than what our estimations display.

RESULTS

In Table 1 we report descriptive statistics and correlations. Before undertaking our , we examine the validity of our story by performing some simple descriptive comparisons with our final sample. Specifically, we look into the distribution of safety alerts along the days of the week. In Figure 1 we show such distribution and how there are more alerts

9 We also tried an OLS estimation and the results provide similar support for our theory (available upon request). 24 announced as the days of the week go on, with Friday having more announcements than any other day with having about 27% of all announcements.

[Insert Table 1 and Figure 1 about here]

However, we argue that the announcement of Fridays will not be random: we expect politically active firms to be more likely than politically inactive firms to get announcements on

Fridays. Figures 2a and 2b show the distribution of safety alerts for both types of firm. We can see a drastic difference between the firms that are politically active and those that are not. In

Figure 2b, which includes safety alerts on drugs owned by firms that lobby the FDA, there is a greater frequency of Fridays. A Kolmogorov–Smirnov test shows that this distribution is statistically different from a distribution of available weekdays in that same period at the 0.1% level. Conversely, for firms that do not lobby the FDA (Figure 2a), the distribution of alert announcements is relatively uniform. Although Fridays are still the most often day, a

Kolmogorov–Smirnov test shows that this distribution is not statistically different from a distribution of available weekdays. The fact that the distribution of alerts throughout the weekdays for non-lobbying firms is not different from a distribution of available weekdays suggests that the FDA does not seem to have a “natural” tendency to release safety alerts on a particular day.

[Insert Figures 2a and 2b]

Finally, because we predict this difference to be greater for severe safety alerts, we look at this in Figures 3a and 3b, where we show the distribution of severe safety alerts only along weekdays for lobbying and non-lobbying firms. When find that Friday alerts occur in approximately 35% of the cases for firms that Lobby but in only 22% of the cases for firms that do not lobby.

25

[Insert Figures 3a and 3b]

In the first four columns of Table 2 we report the effect of Friday on healthcare experts diffusion and mass media diffusion. If Friday alerts receive less attention, then we should see fewer people retweeting MedWatch safety alerts when the announcement is made on Fridays.

Likewise, we would expect fewer news articles being written about the alert for Friday alerts than for the alerts announced any other weekday. The results in Table 2 provide support to our predictions in Hypotheses 1a and 1b. Models 1 and 3 just include the control variables. Models 2 and 4 show that Friday alerts have fewer retweets and media articles (β = -0.501, p < 0.01 and β

= -0.261, p < 0.01 respectively).

[Insert Table 2 about here]

In Models 5, 6 and 7 of Table 2 we estimate the effect of lobbying the FDA on the probability that the alert is released on a Friday. Model 5 just includes control variables. In

Model 6 we include lobbying the FDA, and find that this variable has a positive and significant effect on the probability that an alert is communicated on a Friday (β = 0.834, p < 0.01). This evidence supports hypothesis 2. Finally, in Model 7 we add the interaction between lobbying the

FDA and safety alert severity. We find that this interaction has a positive and marginally significant effect on the probability of Friday (β = 1.221, p < 0.10). This finding provides partial support for hypothesis 3. These results mimic the descriptive analysis we provided above: lobbying is positively and significantly associated with an increased likelihood of the FDA releasing an alert on Friday, and this effect is even stronger for severe safety alerts.

Graphical analysis

While Table 2 shows the statistical relationship between lobbying the FDA and Friday, the interpretation of logistic models is not straightforward. For nonlinear estimations, a graphical

26 interpretation of the size and significance of the effects is necessary.10 For this we use a simulation-based approach developed by King, Tomz, and Wittenberg (2000), which was introduced into the management literature by Zelner (2009). We analyze the main and interaction effects by taking 100,000 post-estimated draws from a random multivariate normal distribution using the coefficients and variance-covariance matrices from our estimations in Models 6 and 7.

We then multiply the coefficients obtained in each draw with the real values of the underlying data, but altering our main explanatory variables lobbying the FDA and safety alert severity. This creates a statistical counterfactual that allows us to estimate the predicted probability of an alert being on a Friday depending on whether the firm lobbied or whether the drug alert was severe, while everything else for each observation stayed the same. Figure 4a shows the results for the main effect of firm lobbying (Model 6) while Figure 4b shows the results for the interaction effect (Model 7).

[Insert Figures 4a and 4b about here]

These graphical analyses provide further evidence in support for H2 and H3. First, Figure

4a shows how lobbying the FDA strongly increases the predicted probability of an alert being on

Friday. The baseline percentage of an alert being on Friday with no lobbying is about 22%.

When firms lobby this increases up to 36%, which corresponds to over a 63% increase in the likelihood of a Friday alert. This suggests that having political connections with the FDA increases the probability of receiving a favorable alert date. Looking at Figure 4b we can see that this relationship is much stronger for severe safety alerts. Figure 4b shows that, for severe alerts, lobbying increases the probability of Friday from about 12% to 40% (a 233% increase).

10 The interpretation of the size and statistical significance of the main and interaction coefficients is not straightforward in nonlinear estimations in that the relationship between an independent variable and a dependent variable depends on the values of the other variables included in the model (Ai and Norton, 2003; Hoetker, 2007). 27

Robustness tests

We try several alternative measures for media coverage. First, we look into different time windows beyond the three-day window used in our main tests. We look at the number of articles covering the safety alert in the one, two, four, five, and six days right after the announcement also. All these measures provide similar support to H1b. Second, we look at a dummy variable taking the value of 1 if there were no articles at all covering the alert and 0 otherwise. We run a logistic regression on this alternative measure and again find support for H1b.

In addition, to ensure that our results are not simply a byproduct of a specific specification of lobbying, we set out to test several alternative specifications of our lobbying the

FDA variable in Table 3. Here we look at three alternative ways to calculate lobbying: 1) the amount of money the firm spent lobbying the FDA in the previous two years, 2) a dummy variable that takes a value of 1 if the firm lobbied the FDA within the previous year, and 3) a dummy variable that takes a value of 1 the firm lobbied the FDA in the previous three years.

Each of these measures is designed to assure that we are capturing something stable about the relationship between the firm and the FDA. Our results are essentially identical across all of these specifications: both the main effect of lobbying the FDA and its interaction with safety alert severity are positive and significant (available upon request). This helps assure that our results are not being driven by an arbitrary specification of lobbying but rather from a stable relationship between the firm and the FDA.

Moreover, as with all studies looking at the impact of lobby on policy outcomes, our study needs to be mindful about endogenity (De Figueiredo and Richter, 2014; Richter et al.,

2009). However, it is difficult to imagine a story about reverse-causality. A firm would need to realize years in advance that it might receive an alert (on a Friday) and start lobbying more. This

28 seems implausible. Nonetheless, to safeguard against this potential problem, we run a Heckman selection model in order to account for a potential endogenous selection into lobbying. In the first stage, we regress firm lobbying on our control variables and the amount of campaign donations to politicians in the same time period as an instrument. Because firms that engage in one type of political strategy are likely to engage in other political strategies as well, we assume that firms that engage more in political donations are more likely to lobby the FDA. Moreover, it is unlikely that political donations will influence the FDA’s decision on when to announce the

FDA given that donations to candidates allow firm to enjoy political leverage once these candidates are elected, something that will take place after the alert is announced. Hence, lobbying in other activities satisfies the two conditions needed to be a good instrumental variable: relevance and exogeneity. Next, in the second step, we re-estimate Friday as a function of lobbying the FDA including the inverse Mills ratio calculated from the first step (Hamilton and Nickerson, 2003; Shaver, 1998).11 We find similar results: firms that are politically active with the FDA are still more likely to receive alerts on Fridays (available upon request).

PUBLIC HEALTH IMPLICATIONS: PATIENT ADVERSE EVENTS

So far, we have shown that politically connected firms are much more likely to get FDA drug alerts on Fridays, the day in which attention is at its lowest. Yet, there might be a potential unattended consequence: this increases the prevalence of the kind of alerts (Fridays) that may be the least effective in achieving their function. The goal of safety alerts is to inform patients and doctors of new side-effects so they can adjust their prescription and consumption behavior accordingly and stop experiencing those negative effects (Dusetzina et al., 2012; Hurren et al.,

11 The inverse Mills ratio, λ, was calculated as λ1=(ϕ(βX))/(Φ(βX)) when lobbying the FDA is equal to 1 and λ0=−ϕ(βX)/([1−Φ(βX)]) when lobbying the FDA is equal to 0, where ϕ(ꞏ) is the standard normal pdf and Φ(ꞏ) is the standard normal cdf. 29

2011). Yet, if Friday safety alerts experience a narrower and slower diffusion then it could be the case that those alerts announced on Fridays are less effective in reducing patients’ adverse reactions. By increasing the prevalence of Friday alerts, the FDA would be making this problem worse.

Data. We explore this potential public health implication using the FDA’s Adverse Event

Reporting System (FAERS), a database providing information about adverse events suffered by patients on specific drugs. This data is available since 1998 and provides information on the day in which a given adverse event was experienced, the severity of such adverse event (e.g., whether it led to death, hospitalization, etc.), and the drug that caused the adverse event. These adverse events are reported by doctors, pharmacists, nurses, manufacturers, and patients, and provide a viable proxy for the prevalence of side-effects with marketed drugs. We explore if alerts indeed lead to a reduction in adverse events (i.e., if safety alerts are effective), and if this reduction is weaker for Friday alerts.

Sample. For this, we match the 441 drug-alerts in our sample with the FAERS database.

This matching, however, is not straightforward. Often times, the name of the drug would be abbreviated in the FAERS database. Take for example Adderall: there is Adderall or Adderall

XR. Yet, the FAERS database will just report Adderall as the drug causing the reported adverse event. Therefore, we match adverse events to drug safety alerts by looking at the first name of the drug only (e.g., Adderall). This means that we may be incorrectly assigning adverse events to certain drug safety alerts. We believe this is mainly adding noise, biasing our estimates downwards and making it harder to find statistically significant effects.

Next, to explore whether the number of reported adverse events is reduced after a safety alert, and if this reduction depends on the weekday in which the safety alert is announced (Friday

30 versus non-Friday), we need to transform our sample of 441 alerts. Since we want to compare the number of adverse events reported in the days before and after the drug alert, we need to look into several days, some before and some after the announcement, for each safety alert. It is unclear, however, how many days before and after the alert we need to look at to identify differences in the responses to Friday and non-Friday alerts. This depends on how long it takes for doctors and patients to react and incorporate safety news into their drug prescription and consumption behavior respectively. We adopt a conservative approach and look into the three months before and after the announcement.12 Moreover, because some drugs received more than one alert in our period of study, it is important to account for the possibility that reactions to a given drug alert are “contaminated” by the temporal proximity to another alert on the same drug.

Accordingly, in those cases where we have two alerts on the same drug whose windows overlap, we remove those two alerts from the sample.

Measures. To identify the day in which a patient suffered an adverse event with a specific drug, we look at the specific information included in the FAERS dataset where it provides the date in which the patient reported experiencing the adverse event. This date is different from the date in which this adverse event was reported to the FDA, a date that is also provided in this database. Although in the vast majority of the cases, the date in which the adverse event was reported to the FDA is very close to the date when the patient experienced the event, in some other cases these two dates are very far apart. Since we are interested on how drug alerts impact whether patients keep experiencing the same complications associated with the drug, we use the date the patients experienced the adverse event to create our main outcome in this first test.

12 We look also into 1-month and 6-months windows and the results are substantially the same, although with smaller differences between Friday and non-Friday alerts as we increase the window size (available upon request). 31

Often times, the reports of these adverse events spike in time, with no events being reported and then suddenly dozens being reported on a random day. To account for the peaks and valleys in reporting, we add one to all of these variables and take the natural logarithm in order to control for its skewed distribution. Moreover, we look into three different types of adverse events: total adverse events, serious adverse events, and death adverse events. Total adverse events includes all adverse events reported in the FAERS database. This is the broadest measure: it does not differentiate between a headache and a death. We also look at serious adverse events, which we measure by looking at adverse events that were recorded as death, hospitalization, disability, life-threatening, and/or congenital anomaly. Lastly, we look at death adverse events, which only captures those adverse events that led to the death of the patient. The last two measures can only be used for safety alerts announced after 2004, the year in which information about the seriousness of concerns become available.

Analysis. We use a difference-in-differences approach where we compare the number of adverse events before and after the alert announcement. We rely on an ordinary least squares

(OLS) regression to estimate the amount of adverse events on a given day as a function of (1) a dummy variable (after) that takes a value of 1 for those days after the alert was announced, (2) a dummy variable (Friday) that takes a value of 1 if the alert was announced on a Friday, and (3) all the control variables used in our tests. Thus, we expect after to have a negative coefficient: if safety alerts are effective, we should find less adverse events reported after the alert. Yet, we expect this reduction to vary depending on the weekday in which the alert is announced.

Specifically, if less people are paying attention to Friday alerts, we expect these alerts to generate

32 a lower reduction in adverse events, meaning that the coefficient of the interaction between after and Friday should be positive. We use fixed-effects at the year and day levels.13

Results. The results of these estimations are reported in Table 3. Overall, for all three types of adverse events, we find strong evidence that safety alerts are in average effective: the coefficient of the variable after is always negative and significant at the 1% level. In addition, we find that the interaction between the variables Friday and after is positive and significant at the

1% level in all three models, suggesting that Friday alerts do not reduce adverse events in the same amount as non-Friday alerts do. Note that the interaction coefficient saps a large portion of the benefits of the alert (coefficient of the main effect of after), and in the case of serious and death adverse events it essentially negates all of the benefits gained by the alert. This suggests that alerts may not reduce serious adverse events and deaths when they are released on Fridays.

[Insert Table 3 about here]

DISCUSSION

This study shows that Friday safety alerts are paid less attention than alerts taking place other days of the week. Friday alerts are shared less intensively by healthcare experts and are associated with fewer articles in mass media, suggesting that healthcare professionals and media are paying less attention to Friday safety news. We argue this decreased attention is why firms are pushing for Friday announcements by the FDA. Indeed, the alerts announced on Fridays are disproportionately associated with firms that have been actively lobbying the FDA in the recent years. This suggests that firms who are politically connected are able to affect the timing of safety alerts. Furthermore, we show that releasing drug safety alerts on Fridays is associated with increased patient problems when compared to alerts released any other weekday.

13 We tried an alternative specification including firm, drug, and alert fixed-effects and the results of these estimations provide similar support (available upon request). 33

Theoretical contributions

We believe our paper contributes to several literatures. First, we show how corporate political activities allow firms to influence public officials’ communication strategies. While the

CPA literature has mostly focused on how firms’ political efforts can shape the content of public policy, our paper shows that there is an additional dimension of public activities— communication—that firms can influence through their non-market strategies. Through lobbying, firms are able to persuade public officials to implement similar impression management tactics to the ones they implement in their communication of internal corporate news. In addition, our paper builds on the assumption that political capital is limited, and as any scarce resource, used strategically. Our evidence suggests that firms are more likely to leverage on their political influence when they have more to gain from it.

Second, our paper bridges the CPA and the impression management literatures. It shows how firms can implement impression management tactics even when a third party, outside the firm’s control, decides upon the communication strategy. Moreover, this paper shows how timing can be a rather effective impression management tactic. Until now, the analysis of how the timing of news affects stakeholder reactions has been largely relegated to the finance and accounting literatures in the context of earning reports and acquisition announcements. Our study shows how the day of the week in which events take place strongly influences the extent to which media and industry experts cover and diffuse such events.

Practical implications

We believe our paper has important policy implications in the context of public health.

Extant evidence suggests that prescription drugs cause about 2 million hospitalizations and

100,000 deaths every year in the United States due to known side-effects (Lazarou, Pomeranz,

34 and Corey, 1998; Light, Lexchin, and Darrow, 2013). This means that FDA safety communications are not always effective. Our study suggests one plausible reason why some of these alerts are not effective in reducing patients’ adverse reactions: those alerts announced on

Fridays are not diffused as quickly and broadly as alerts announced any other weekday. This finding leads to clear policy recommendations: (1) alerts should not be released on Fridays and

(2) the method through which the healthcare community gets informed about safety issues should be improved.

Limitations and future research

Our paper has several limitations. First, we look into a very unique context: drug safety alerts. It is unclear whether our conclusion that firms’ lobbying activities help firms influence the timing of policy decisions will apply into other policy decisions. Second, we proxy diffusion of safety news throughout the healthcare community by looking at retweets and media articles.

These are just two of all the many channels through which this type of information is diffused.

Therefore, it is unclear if our proxies provide a valid approach to capture the presence of a Friday effect in the dissemination of safety news. Future research with richer and more sophisticated data could shed light on this issue. Finally, we argue that lobbying the FDA explains the timing of safety alerts, but the mechanism through which this happens is unclear. How does lobby work is still a black box, and thus a limitation of almost every study in the CPA literature.

Overall, we believe our study provides a novel approach towards understanding the extent to which political efforts allow to influence the timing of policy news, and the potential implications of such strategies. We hope this will spur further research on this relevant topic.

35

36

REFERENCES

Accountemps. 2013. Survey on worker productivity. Available at https://www.roberthalf.com/work-with-us/our-services/accountemps

Advera. 2013. Post FDA-approval drug safety data: Why they are vital and how they can be made accessible, actionable, and predictable. Available at www.adverseevents.com.

Ai, C., Norton, E.C. 2003. Interaction terms in Logit and Probit models. Economics Letters, 80: 123–129.

Ahmed, P., Gardella, J. and Nanda, S., 2002. Wealth effect of drug withdrawals on firms and their competitors. Financial Management, pp.21-41.

Barnett, M.L., 2014. Why stakeholders ignore firm misconduct: A cognitive view. Journal of Management, 40(3), pp.676-702.

Beckers, D.G., van Hooff, M.L., van der Linden, D., Kompier, M.A., Taris, T.W. and Geurts, S.A., 2008. A diary study to open up the black box of overtime work among university faculty members. Scandinavian journal of work, environment & health, pp.213-223.

Bolino, M.C., Kacmar, K.M., Turnley, W.H. and Gilstrap, J.B., 2008. A multi-level review of impression management motives and behaviors. Journal of Management, 34(6), pp.1080-1109.

Bonardi, J.P., Hillman, A.J. and Keim, G.D., 2005. The attractiveness of political markets: Implications for firm strategy. Academy of Management Review, 30(2), pp.397-413.

Bonardi, J.P., Holburn, G.L. and Bergh, R.G.V., 2006. Nonmarket strategy performance: Evidence from US electric utilities. Academy of Management Journal, 49(6), pp.1209-1228.

Carpenter, D., Chattopadhyay, J., Moffitt, S. and Nall, C., 2012. The complications of controlling agency time discretion: FDA review deadlines and postmarket drug safety. American Journal of Political Science, 56(1), pp.98-114.

CDER, 2007. Drug Safety Information–FDA’s Communication to the Public.

Cheah, E.T., Chan, W.L. and Chieng, C.L.L., 2007. The corporate social responsibility of pharmaceutical product recalls: An empirical examination of US and UK markets. Journal of , 76(4), pp.427-449.

Chen, Y., Ganesan, S. and Liu, Y., 2009. Does a firm's product-recall strategy affect its financial value? An examination of strategic alternatives during product-harm crises. Journal of Marketing, 73(6), pp.214-226.

37

Dalton, R.J., Beck, P.A., Huckfeldt, R. and Koetzle, W., 1998. A test of media-centered agenda setting: Newspaper content and public interests in a presidential election. Political Communication, 15(4), pp.463-481.

De Figueiredo, J.M. and Richter, B.K., 2014. Advancing the empirical research on lobbying. Annual Review of Political Science, 17, pp.163-185.

Deephouse, D.L., 2000. Media reputation as a strategic resource: An integration of mass communication and resource-based theories. Journal of management, 26(6), pp.1091-1112.

Deephouse, D.L. and Heugens, P.P., 2009. Linking social issues to organizational impact: The role of infomediaries and the infomediary process. Journal of Business Ethics, 86(4), pp.541- 553.

DellaVigna, S. and Pollet, J.M., 2009. Investor inattention and Friday earnings announcements. The Journal of Finance, 64(2), pp.709-749.

Dowdell, T.D., Govindaraj, S. and Jain, P.C., 1992. The Tylenol incident, ensuing regulation, and stock prices. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 27(2), pp.283-301.

Dusetzina, S.B., Higashi, A.S., Dorsey, E.R., Conti, R., Huskamp, H.A., Zhu, S., Garfield, C.F. and Alexander, G.C., 2012. Impact of FDA drug risk communications on health care utilization and health behaviors: a systematic review. Medical care, 50(6), p.466.

Elsbach, K. D. 2006. Organizational perception management. Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum.

Elsbach, K. D. 2012. A framework for reputation management over the course of evolving controversies. In M. L. Barnett & T. G. Pollock (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of corporate reputation: 466-486. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press.

Elsbach, K.D., Sutton, R.I. and Principe, K.E., 1998. Averting expected challenges through anticipatory impression management: A study of hospital billing. Organization Science, 9(1), pp.68-86.

Graffin, S.D., Haleblian, J.J. and Kiley, J.T., 2016. Ready, AIM, acquire: Impression offsetting and acquisitions. Academy of Management Journal, 59(1), pp.232-252.

Hamilton, B.A., Nickerson, J.A. 2003. Correcting for endogeneity in strategic management research. Strategic Organization, 1: 53–80.

Harrison, D.A. and Hulin, C.L., 1989. Investigations of absenteeism: Using event history models to study the absence-taking process. Journal of Applied Psychology, 74(2), p.300.

Herrmann, M.A. and Rockoff, J.E., 2012. Worker absence and productivity: Evidence from teaching. Journal of Labor Economics, 30(4), pp.749-782.

38

Hillman, A.J. and Hitt, M.A., 1999. Corporate political strategy formulation: A model of approach, participation, and strategy decisions. Academy of management review, 24(4), pp.825- 842.

Hillman, A.J., Keim, G.D. and Schuler, D., 2004. Corporate political activity: A review and research agenda. Journal of Management, 30(6), pp.837-857.

Hirshleifer, D., Lim, S.S. and Teoh, S.H., 2009. Driven to distraction: Extraneous events and underreaction to earnings news. The Journal of Finance, 64(5), pp.2289-2325.

Hoetker, G. 2007. The use of logit and probit models in strategic management research: critical issues. Strategic Management Journal, 28: 331–343.

Hoffman, A.J. and Ocasio, W., 2001. Not all events are attended equally: Toward a middle-range theory of industry attention to external events. Organization science, 12(4), pp.414-434.

Hurren, K.M., Taylor, T.N. and Jaber, L.A., 2011. Antidiabetic prescribing trends and predictors of thiazolidinedione discontinuation following the 2007 safety alert. Diabetes Research and Clinical Practice, 93: 49-55.

Johns, G. and Al Hajj, R., 2016. Frequency versus time lost measures of absenteeism: Is the voluntariness distinction an urban legend?. Journal of Organizational Behavior, 37(3), pp.456- 479.

Kaplan, S. and Henderson, R., 2005. Inertia and incentives: Bridging organizational economics and organizational theory. Organization Science, 16(5), pp.509-521.

King, G., Tomz, M. Wittenberg, J., 2000. Making the most of statistical analyses: Improving interpretation and presentation. American Journal of Political Science, 347–361.

Lazarou, J., Pomeranz, B.H. and Corey, P.N., 1998. Incidence of adverse drug reactions in hospitalized patients: a meta-analysis of prospective studies. Jama, 279(15), pp.1200-1205.

Light, D.W., Lexchin, J. and Darrow, J.J., 2013. Institutional of pharmaceuticals and the myth of safe and effective drugs.

Louis, H. and Sun, A., 2010. Investor inattention and the market reaction to merger announcements. Management Science, 56(10), pp.1781-1793.

Lounsbury, M. and Rao, H., 2004. Sources of durability and change in market classifications: A study of the reconstitution of product categories in the American mutual fund industry, 1944– 1985. Social Forces, 82(3), pp.969-999.

Madsen, P.M. and Rodgers, Z.J., 2015. Looking good by doing good: The antecedents and consequences of stakeholder attention to corporate disaster relief. Strategic Management Journal, 36(5), pp.776-794.

39

Miller, R.T., Murnane, R.J. and Willett, J.B., 2008. Do worker absences affect productivity? The case of teachers. International Labour Review, 147(1), pp.71-89.

Nader, I.W., Pietschnig, J. and Voracek, M., 2012. Academic workload, research productivity, and end of life: A single-case historiometric study. Psychological reports, 110(3), pp.701-708.

Ocasio, W., 1997. Towards an attention-based view of the firm. Strategic management journal, pp.187-206.

Ocasio, W., 2011. Attention to attention. Organization Science, 22(5), pp.1286-1296.

Pollock, T.G. and Rindova, V.P., 2003. Media legitimation effects in the market for initial public offerings. Academy of Management Journal, 46(5), pp.631-642.

Rao, H., Greve, H.R. and Davis, G.F., 2001. Fool's gold: Social proof in the initiation and abandonment of coverage by Wall Street analysts. Administrative Science Quarterly, 46(3), pp.502-526.

Richter, B.K., Samphantharak, K. and Timmons, J.F., 2009. Lobbying and taxes. American Journal of Political Science, 53(4), pp.893-909.

Ridge, J.W., Ingram, A. and Hill, A.D., 2017. Beyond lobbying expenditures: How lobbying breadth and political connectedness affect firm outcomes. Academy of Management Journal, 60(3), pp.1138-1163.

Shaver, J.M. 1998. Accounting for endogeneity when assessing strategy performance: does entry mode choice affect FDI survival? Management Science, 44: 571–585.

Szefler, S.J., Whelan, G.J. and Leung, D.Y., 2006. “Black box” warning: Wake-up call or overreaction?. Journal of and clinical , 117(1), p.26.

Sotak, K.L., Spain, S.M., Dionne, S.D. and Yammarino, F.J., 2015, January. A within-person approach to observing cyclical patterns of motivation. Academy of Management Proceedings, 1: 12933.

Zelner, B.A., 2009. Using simulation to interpret results from logit, probit, and other nonlinear models. Strategic Management Journal, 30: 1335–1348.

40

Table 1 Descriptive Statistics and Correlations a N = 441 Mean s.d. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16

1 Mass media diffusion 7.67 6.57 1.00

2 Healthcare experts diffusion 3.99 4.70 0.27 1.00

3 Friday 0.27 0.44 -0.25 -0.12 1.00

4 Lobbying the FDA 0.33 0.47 0.00 0.09 0.17 1.00

5 Other lobbying 4.22 5.49 -0.04 -0.01 -0.02 -0.11 1.00

6 Severity 0.42 0.36 0.09 0.13 -0.08 0.21 0.25 1.00

7 Prior drugs firm 1.95 0.89 0.08 0.08 -0.18 0.13 0.07 -0.06 1.00

8 Prior alerts firm 6.18 7.60 -0.17 0.09 0.09 0.28 -0.03 0.06 0.22 1.00

9 Firm public 0.46 0.50 0.03 0.22 -0.03 0.38 0.24 0.25 0.31 0.18 1.00

10 Prior alerts drug 0.94 1.41 0.00 0.04 0.00 0.13 0.02 -0.02 0.19 0.45 0.05 1.00

11 Post-marketing 0.39 0.49 0.13 0.19 -0.10 0.06 -0.15 0.06 0.34 -0.05 -0.04 0.19 1.00

12 Prior adverse effects 6.17 2.25 0.04 0.16 -0.03 0.12 0.07 0.02 0.17 0.33 0.19 0.22 -0.01 1.00

13 Other alerts 0.27 0.44 -0.02 0.00 0.02 -0.01 0.22 0.25 0.09 0.12 0.10 0.05 0.02 0.23 1.00

13 Other drugs 0.24 0.43 0.23 0.09 -0.22 -0.16 -0.32 -0.29 0.07 -0.29 -0.16 -0.12 0.12 -0.23 -0.22 1.00

13 Priority review 0.25 0.43 -0.14 0.13 0.05 0.20 0.19 0.27 0.02 0.12 0.18 0.16 0.24 0.04 0.25 -0.31 1.00

14 Time since approval 7.37 0.96 0.08 -0.03 0.20 0.08 -0.01 -0.11 -0.21 0.10 0.03 -0.17 -0.36 0.46 -0.13 -0.15 -0.24 1.00 a Descriptive statistics and correlations with Healthcare experts diffusion are calculated on a sample of 139 observations .

41

Table 2 Main Results a, b Dependent Variable Healthcare experts diffusion Mass media diffusion Friday Model 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 0.809 0.615 1.323** 1.387** -2.480+ -2.388* -2.301 Intercept (0.742) (0.715) (0.455) (0.445) (1.290) (1.327) (1.461) -0.501** -0.261** Friday - - - - - (0.181) (0.101) 0.834** 0.274 Lobbying the FDA - - - - - (0.299) (0.459) 1.221+ Lobbying the FDA x Severity ------(0.764) -0.020 -0.002 0.001 Other lobbying - - - - (0.024) (0.025) (0.027) 0.433* 0.358* 0.136 0.130 -0.302 -0.332 -0.856+ Severity (0.174) (0.177) (0.126) (0.125) (0.377) (0.381) (0.487) 0.055 0.058 -0.001 -0.016 -0.306+ -0.363* -0.349+ Prior drugs firm (0.079) (0.076) (0.061) (0.062) (0.175) (0.181) (0.193) 0.017 0.008 0.002 0.002 -0.024 -0.037 -0.041 Prior alerts firm (0.073) (0.070) (0.009) (0.009) (0.026) (0.026) (0.029) 0.042 0.039 0.201* 0.229* 0.512+ 0.162 0.188 Firm public (0.151) (0.145) (0.085) (0.083) (0.265) (0.283) (0.308) 0.123 0.154 0.108** 0.111* -0.028 -0.030 -0.026 Prior alerts drug (0.120) (0.117) (0.034) (0.034) (0.106) (0.108) (0.105) 0.111 0.129 -0.105 -0.101 0.321 0.351 0.318 Post-marketing (0.189) (0.183) (0.101) (0.099) (0.277) (0.278) (0.280) -0.011 -0.019 0.098** 0.095** -0.026 -0.042 -0.032 Prior adverse effects (0.040) (0.036) (0.020) (0.020) (0.067) (0.066) (0.066) 0.224 0.361 0.204+ 0.240* 1.042** 1.047** 1.067** Other alerts (0.283) (0.303) (0.111) (0.110) (0.326) (0.327) (0.318) 0.189 0.084 0.134 0.100 -0.670 -0.574 -0.605 Other drugs (0.169) (0.162) (0.130) (0.126) (0.353) (0.354) (0.366) -0.295 -0.230 -0.044 -0.034 0.046 0.050 0.095 Priority review (0.191) (0.188) (0.098) (0.101) (0.322) (0.324) (0.315) 0.153+ 0.199* -0.122* -0.118* 0.152 0.132 0.141 Time since approval (0.091) (0.089) (0.051) (0.051) (0.153) (0.152) (0.157) Observations 139 139 441 441 416 416 416 Log Likelihood -400.8 -397.3 -989.8 -986.2 -214.6 -210.9 -209.5 a Significance levels: ** p < 0.01, * p < 0.05, + p < 0.10. b All models include alert year fixed-effects. Robust standard errors in parentheses.

42

Table 3 Effectiveness of safety alerts a, b Dependent Variable Total adverse events Serious adverse events Death adverse events Model 1 2 3 4 5 6 8 9 10 0.331** 0.331** 0.336** 0.024 0.019 0.024 -0.072** -0.073** -0.071** Intercept (0.025) (0.025) (0.025) (0.023) (0.023) (0.023) (0.013) (0.013) (0.012) -0.035** -0.035** -0.046** -0.020** -0.020** -0.028** -0.007** -0.007** -0.012** After (0.005) (0.005) (0.006) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) 0.052** 0.031** 0.014* 0.002 -0.010** -0.020** Friday - - - (0.006) (0.008) (0.006) (0.008) (0.003) (0.004) 0.042** 0.031** 0.019** After x Friday ------(0.011) (0.011) (0.006) -0.054** -0.052** -0.052** -0.074** -0.073** -0.073** -0.038** -0.038** -0.038** Severity (0.007) (0.008) (0.008) (0.007) (0.007) (0.007) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) 0.019** 0.023** 0.023** -0.003 -0.002 -0.002 -0.017** -0.018** -0.018** Prior drugs firm (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) 0.002** 0.001** 0.001** 0.004** 0.004** 0.004** 0.003** 0.003** 0.003** Prior alerts firm (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) 0.019** 0.016** 0.016** -0.012** -0.014** -0.014** -0.001 -0.001 -0.001 Firm public (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.003) (0.003) (0.002) 0.030** 0.030** 0.030** 0.032** 0.032** 0.032** 0.004+ 0.004+ 0.004+ Prior alerts drug (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) 0.002 -0.001 -0.001 0.011+ 0.010+ 0.010+ 0.018** 0.019** 0.019** Post-marketing (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) 0.917** 0.915** 0.915** 0.602** 0.602** 0.602** 0.181** 0.181** 0.181** Prior adverse effects (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) -0.054** -0.062** -0.062** -0.048** -0.051** -0.051** 0.021** 0.023** 0.023** Other alerts (0.007) (0.007) (0.007) (0.007) (0.007) (0.007) (0.004) (0.004) (0.004) -0.006 -0.006 -0.006 -0.014* -0.014* -0.014* -0.007* -0.007* -0.007* Other drugs (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) -0.009 -0.009 -0.009 0.033** 0.034** 0.034** 0.051** 0.051** 0.051** Priority review (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.006) (0.003) (0.003) (0.003) -0.032** -0.033** -0.033** 0.007** 0.007** 0.007** 0.009** 0.009** 0.009** Time since approval (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) Observations 78,554 78,554 78,554 62,264 62,264 62,264 62,264 62,264 62,264 R2 0.530 0.530 0.531 0.407 0.407 0.407 0.178 0.178 0.178 a Significance levels: ** p < 0.01, * p < 0.05, + p < 0.10. b All models include alert year and day fixed-effects. Robust standard errors in parentheses.

43

FDA Drug Alert Announcement Day

Announcements FDA of %

0.00 0.05 0.10 0.15 0.20 0.25 Monday Tuesday Wednesday Thursday Friday

Figure 1. Distribution of safety alerts.

FDA Announcement Day without Lobbying FDA Announcement Day when Firms Lobby

Announcements FDA of % Announcements FDA of %

0.00 0.05 0.10 0.15 0.20 0.25 0.30 0.35 0.00 0.05 0.10 0.15 0.20 0.25 0.30 0.35 Monday Tuesday Wednesday Thursday Friday Monday Tuesday Wednesday Thursday Friday

Figure 2a and 2b. Distribution of safety alerts as a function of FDA lobbying.

Severe Alerts Announcement Day without Lobbying Severe Alerts Announcement Day when Firms Lobby

Announcements FDA of % Announcements FDA of %

0.00 0.05 0.10 0.15 0.20 0.25 0.30 0.35 0.00 0.05 0.10 0.15 0.20 0.25 0.30 0.35 Monday Tuesday Wednesday Thursday Friday Monday Tuesday Wednesday Thursday Friday

Figure 3a and 3b. Distribution of severe safety alerts as a function of FDA lobbying.

44

Friday Alerts & Lobbying

● Lobbying ● No Lobbying Density 0 5 10 15

0.00.10.20.30.40.50.6

Predicted Probability of Fr iday Alert Figure 4a. Effect of Lobbying the FDA on the probability of Friday.

Friday Alerts, Lobbying, and Alert Severity

● Severe Alert − Lobbying ● Severe Alert − No Lobbying Density 0246810

0.00.10.20.30.40.50.60.7

Predicted Probability of Fr iday Alert Figure 4b. Effect of lobbying the FDA on the probability of Friday for severe safety alerts.

45