Markets Or Mercantilism? Markets Or Jennifer Lind and Mercantilism? Daryl G

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Markets Or Mercantilism? Markets Or Jennifer Lind and Mercantilism? Daryl G Markets or Mercantilism? Markets or Jennifer Lind and Mercantilism? Daryl G. Press How China Secures Its Energy Supplies Since oil came to fuel the global economy, governments have sought to ensure access to critical sup- plies. In the early twentieth century, the British government worried about the United Kingdom’s reliance on Royal Dutch Shell for imports—and especially the Royal Navy’s dependence on overseas oil. The Dutch were susceptible to German pressure and might cut off Britain’s oil during a conºict. First Admiralty Lord Winston Churchill dismissed the notion of relying on markets for critical oil supplies, lamenting that the “open market is becoming an open mockery.” He insisted the British government become “the owners or, at any rate, the controllers [of oil] at the source,” and under his leadership the British acquired a 51 percent stake in the Anglo-Persian Oil Company.1 For decades, other countries followed suit, creating national oil companies (NOCs) to de- velop and secure energy supplies abroad. Today, China appears to be following in these energy mercantilist footsteps. Some analysts warn that China’s energy policies are hostile; by establishing NOCs and subsidizing their acquisition of overseas oil, the Chinese govern- ment is maneuvering to control key energy resources.2 Other observers deride China’s mercantilist policies as anachronistic; in an age of globalization, they say, China can rely on the market to obtain the oil it needs. “Energy insecurity is a myth,” writes Jonathan Kirshner, who argues that China’s government is mistaken in thinking that owning oil enhances its security. Joseph Nye agrees, noting that China “overpays” for its energy and gains no additional security in return.3 One U.S. National Security Strategy criticized Chinese leaders for “act- Jennifer Lind and Daryl G. Press are associate professors of government at Dartmouth. The authors thank numerous colleagues and friends whose advice signiªcantly improved this arti- cle, including Stephen Brooks, Eugene Gholz, Llewelyn Hughes, Shoichi Itoh, Austin Long, Jona- than Markowitz, Christopher Snyder, and the anonymous reviewers. The authors also appreciate the valuable feedback from seminar participants at Dartmouth College, Cornell University, George Washington University, the University of Chicago, the University of Notre Dame, the University of Texas at Austin, and Yale University. 1. Daniel Yergin, The Prize: The Epic Quest for Oil, Money, and Power (New York: Free Press, 1993), pp. 158, 160, 174. Anglo-Persian would later become British Petroleum. 2. Jack Farchy, “China Seeking to Revive the Silk Road,” Financial Times, May 9, 2016; Colin Shek, “China Plays for Energy in New Great Game,” Al Jazeera, October 10, 2013; Shawn McCarthy, “Po- litical Storm Brews in U.S. over Nexen Deal,” Globe and Mail, September 27, 2012; Robert Collier, “Backlash to Chinese Bid for Unocal,” San Francisco Chronicle, June 24, 2005; and David Zweig, “‘Resource Diplomacy’ under Hegemony: The Sources of Sino-American Competition in the 21st Century?” working paper no. 18 (Hong Kong: Center on China’s Transnational Relations, Hong Kong University of Science and Technology, 2005/06). 3. Jonathan Kirshner, “The Cult of Energy Insecurity and the Crisis of Energy Security,” “America International Security, Vol. 42, No. 4 (Spring 2018), pp. 170–204, doi:10.1162/ISEC_a_00310 © 2018 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College and the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. 170 Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/isec_a_00310 by guest on 30 September 2021 Markets or Mercantilism? 171 ing as if they can somehow ‘lock up’ energy supplies around the world or seek to direct markets rather than opening them up, as if they can follow a mercan- tilism borrowed from a discredited era.”4 Are policies of energy mercantilism outdated and illogical, or do they offer a coherent strategy for enhancing a country’s energy security? This article ar- gues that there is a strategic logic to energy mercantilism (meaning, efforts by the state to enhance national power by securing access to energy supplies). Far from being anachronistic or irrational, policies of energy mercantilism are a logical and potentially effective response to vulnerability. We make three key arguments. First, the logic of energy mercantilism is rooted in the economics and business literatures on ªrm behavior. Companies tend to fear disruptions to their supply chains under four conditions: when their supplies come from industries beset by imperfect contracting, when their suppliers are collusive, when supplies are geographically concentrated, and when supplies are located in regions that suffer frequent conºicts. All four of these conditions plague the oil sector, making states justiªably concerned about access to energy. Second, the approaches that states adopt to mitigate energy insecurity are analogous to the steps that ªrms take to reduce the risk to their supply chains. Firms and states secure supplies by (1) gaining control or inºuence over key suppliers; (2) diversifying products, suppliers, and transportation routes; (3) creating inventories; and (4) providing security to protect vulnerable assets. Third, China’s energy policies are underpinned by energy mercantilist logic. China is highly vulnerable to energy disruptions; its leaders explain their energy policies as a response to this vulnerability; and their policies have en- hanced China’s energy security in meaningful ways. Notably, Beijing’s energy mercantilist policies help insulate China from some of the coercive tools that the United States might wield against China (e.g., an embargo or a blockade) during a conºict in the South China Sea or over Taiwan. These arguments have important implications for U.S.-China relations and & the World: National Security in the New Era” conference, Tobin Project, Cambridge, Massachu- setts, November 14–16, 2008. On Chinese policy speciªcally, see Erica S. Downs, “The Chinese En- ergy Security Debate,” China Quarterly, March 2004, pp. 21–41; Dan Blumenthal and Philip Swagel, “Chinese Oil Drill,” Wall Street Journal, June 8, 2006; Minxin Pei, “China’s Big Energy Dilemma,” Straits Times, April 13, 2006; Joseph S. Nye Jr., “The Wrong Way of Thinking about Oil,” Korea Her- ald, February 27, 2006; Philip Andrews-Speed, “Do Overseas Investments by National Oil Com- panies Enhance Energy Security at Home? A View from Asia,” in Andrews-Speed et al., eds., Oil and Gas for Asia: Geopolitical Implications of Asia’s Rising Demand (Seattle, Wash.: National Bureau of Asia Research, September 2012), pp. 29–41; and Kevin Kane, “Energy Security Dilemma Bubble: Cold War Thinking in a World Supply Oil Market,” Northeast Asia Energy Focus, Vol. 7, No. 1 (Spring 2010), pp. 52–64. 4. The National Security Strategy of the United States of America (Washington, D.C.: President of the United States, March 2006), p. 41. Downloaded from http://www.mitpressjournals.org/doi/pdf/10.1162/isec_a_00310 by guest on 30 September 2021 International Security 42:4 172 international politics. First, by connecting a wide range of seemingly unrelated activities under the energy mercantilist rubric—for example, not merely over- seas energy acquisitions but also diplomacy with major oil producers, di- versiªcation, inventories, and security policies—this article highlights the prevalence of energy mercantilist behavior today. Analysts sometimes warn that China’s energy mercantilism reveals its leaders’ revisionist intentions, but many countries (including the United States) vigorously pursue energy mer- cantilism.5 Beijing’s behavior appears less aggressive and more reasonable when one recognizes it as a common practice—and when one notes that China’s principal geopolitical adversary also practices it. Second, China’s energy mercantilism is neutralizing one of the United States’ preferred tools of coercion: the oil weapon. The United States has em- ployed energy coercion repeatedly, and U.S. analysts openly contemplate it as an option against China.6 China’s energy policies, however, have signiªcantly lessened the potential bite of a U.S. embargo or blockade. In the past, the U.S. military could have easily cut off China’s oil imports during a war. Today, China could order its tankers to resist efforts to board its vessels; use its im- proved military capabilities to attack blockading ships; enlist its petroleum- rich trade partners to protest the U.S. action; increase the ºow through its overland pipelines; and release oil from its large petroleum reserves. The immediate result: an important instrument of U.S. military power—energy coercion—is eroding. The longer-term consequence: China’s successful en- ergy policies will drive the United States to enhance other, but perhaps more escalatory, means of coercion. Finally, and more broadly, this article offers a window into the ongoing struggle between liberalism and mercantilism, whose outcome will help shape the political and economic order in the twenty-ªrst century. If well-functioning global markets negate the logic of mercantilism, then the spread of liberalism has dampened one of the perennial causes of conºict in international politics, as its supporters claim.7 But if states still have incentives to engage in mercan- 5. Stephen D. Krasner, Defending the National Interest: Raw Materials Investments and U.S. Foreign Policy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1978). 6. On a U.S. blockade of China, see Evan B. Montgomery, “Reinforcing the Front Line: U.S. Defense Strategy and the Rise of China” (Washington, D.C.: Center for Strategic and Budgetary Assessments, February 1, 2017); T.X. Hammes, “Offshore Control Is the Answer,” Proceedings, Vol. 138, No. 12 (December 2012), p. 318; Jeffrey E. Kline and Wayne P. Hughes Jr., “Between Peace and the Air-Sea Battle: A War at Sea Strategy,” Naval War College Review, Vol. 65, No. 4 (Autumn 2012), pp. 35–41; and Sean Mirski, “Stranglehold: The Context, Conduct, and Consequences of an American Naval Blockade of China,” Journal of Strategic Studies, Vol. 36, No. 3 (2013), pp. 385–421, doi:10.1080/01402390.2012.743885.
Recommended publications
  • Understanding Open Market Operations
    Foreword The Federal Reserve Bank of New York is responsible for Michael Akbar Akhtar, vice president of the day-to-day implementation of the nation’s monetary pol- Federal Reserve Bank of New York, leads the reader— icy. It is primarily through open market operations—pur- whether a student, market professional or an interested chases or sales of U.S. Government securities in the member of the public—through various facets of mone- open market in order to add or drain reserves from the tary policy decision-making, and offers a general per- banking system—that the Federal Reserve influences spective on the transmission of policy effects throughout money and financial market conditions that, in turn, the economy. affect output, jobs and prices. Understanding Open Market Operations pro- This edition of Understanding Open Market vides a nontechnical review of how monetary policy is Operations seeks to explain the challenges in formulat- formulated and executed. Ideally, it will stimulate read- ing and implementing U.S. monetary policy in today’s ers to learn more about the subject as well as enhance highly competitive financial environment. The book high- appreciation of the challenges and uncertainties con- lights the broad and complex set of considerations that fronting monetary policymakers. are involved in daily decisions for open market opera- William J. McDonough tions and details the steps taken to implement policy. President Understanding Open Market Operations / i Acknowledgment Much has changed in U.S. financial markets and institu- Partlan for extensive comments on drafts; and to all of tions since 1985, when the last edition of Open Market the Desk staff for graciously and patiently answering my Operations, written by Paul Meek, was published.
    [Show full text]
  • The Economic Club of New York 431 Meeting 106 Year September 9, 2013 the Honorable Henry M
    The Economic Club of New York 431st Meeting 106th Year September 9, 2013 ___________________________________ The Honorable Henry M. Paulson, Jr. Former U.S. Secretary of the Treasury Chairman of the Paulson Institute ___________________________________ Questioners: Andrew Tisch Former Chair of the Economic Club of New York Co-Chair of Loews Corporation Floyd Norris Chief Financial Correspondent, The New York Times The Economic Club of New York – Henry M. Paulson, Jr., – September 9, 2013 Page 1 Roger Ferguson: Well, good afternoon everyone. I would encourage all who have not yet done so to please take your seats so that we can get started with our program. And let me start by welcoming all of you to this, the 431st meeting of the Economic Club of New York. I am Roger Ferguson. I am the chairman of the club which is now in its 106th year as the nation’s leading non-partisan forum for economic policy speeches. Throughout the long history of the Economic Club of New York, we’ve had more than 1,000 guest speakers appear before us establishing a strong tradition of excellence which we continue today. I would like to begin by recognizing the 200 members of our Centennial Society who have contributed their support to the club to ensuring its continued financial stability. Thanks to all of you for helping to ensure the club can continue to fulfill its mission well into the next century. I would also like to welcome the students who are with us and to thank our members for making their attendance possible.
    [Show full text]
  • Macroeconomics Course Outline and Syllabus
    City University of New York (CUNY) CUNY Academic Works Open Educational Resources New York City College of Technology 2018 Macroeconomics Course Outline and Syllabus Sean P. MacDonald CUNY New York City College of Technology How does access to this work benefit ou?y Let us know! More information about this work at: https://academicworks.cuny.edu/ny_oers/8 Discover additional works at: https://academicworks.cuny.edu This work is made publicly available by the City University of New York (CUNY). Contact: [email protected] COURSE OUTLINE FOR ECON 1101 – MACROECONOMICS New York City College of Technology Social Science Department COURSE CODE: 1101 TITLE: Macroeconomics Class Hours: 3, Credits: 3 COURSE DESCRIPTION: Fundamental economic ideas and the operation of the economy on a national scale. Production, distribution and consumption of goods and services, the exchange process, the role of government, the national income and its distribution, GDP, consumption function, savings function, investment spending, the multiplier principle and the influence of government spending on income and output. Analysis of monetary policy, including the banking system and the Federal Reserve System. COURSE PREREQUISITE: CUNY proficiency in reading and writing RECOMMENDED TEXTBOOK and MATERIALS* Krugman and Wells, Eds., Macroeconomics 3rd. ed, Worth Publishers, 2012 Leeds, Michael A., von Allmen, Peter and Schiming, Richard C., Macroeconomics, Pearson Education, Inc., 2006 Supplemental Reading (optional, but informative): Krugman, Paul, End This Depression
    [Show full text]
  • German Political and Economic Ideology in the Twentieth Century
    EUROPEAN JOURNAL OF CULTURAL AND POLITICAL SOCIOLOGY https://doi.org/10.1080/23254823.2018.1559745 German political and economic ideology in the twentieth century and its theological problems: The Lutheran genealogy of ordoliberalism Troels Krarup Department of Sociology, Copenhagen University, Copenhagen, Denmark ABSTRACT Ordoliberalism is widely considered to be the dominant ideology of the German political elite today and consequently responsible at least in part for its hard ‘austerity’ line during the recent Eurozone crisis. This article presents a genealogy of the main concerns, concepts and problems around which early German ordoliberalism was formed and structured as a political and economic ideology. Early ordoliberalism is shown to be rooted in an interwar Germanophone Lutheran Evangelical tradition of anti-humanist ‘political ethics’. Its specific conceptions of the market, the state, the individual, freedom and duty were developed on a Lutheran Evangelical basis. Analytically, the article considers ideological influences of theology on political and economic theory not so much in terms of consensus and ideational overlap, but rather in terms of shared concerns, concepts and problems across different positions. ARTICLE HISTORY Received 18 March 2018; Accepted 10 December 2018 KEYWORDS Ordoliberalism; ideology; Europe; economic thought; religion; genealogy JEL Classification A12 relation of economics to other disciplines; A13 relation of economics to social values; B29 history of economic thought since 1925: other 1. Introduction: unity and variety in neoliberalism In Colombel’s(1994, p. 128) accurate rephrasing of Foucault’s(1993, p. 35) ‘history of the present’, genealogy is ‘the history of a problem of which the present relevance must be assessed’. One such problem, one that is of major political, cultural and sociological interest in Europe today, relates to the particular German tradition of economic and political thinking termed ordoliberalism.
    [Show full text]
  • A Critique of John Stuart Mill Chris Daly
    Southern Illinois University Carbondale OpenSIUC Honors Theses University Honors Program 5-2002 The Boundaries of Liberalism in a Global Era: A Critique of John Stuart Mill Chris Daly Follow this and additional works at: http://opensiuc.lib.siu.edu/uhp_theses Recommended Citation Daly, Chris, "The Boundaries of Liberalism in a Global Era: A Critique of John Stuart Mill" (2002). Honors Theses. Paper 131. This Dissertation/Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the University Honors Program at OpenSIUC. It has been accepted for inclusion in Honors Theses by an authorized administrator of OpenSIUC. For more information, please contact [email protected]. r The Boundaries of Liberalism in a Global Era: A Critique of John Stuart Mill Chris Daly May 8, 2002 r ABSTRACT The following study exanunes three works of John Stuart Mill, On Liberty, Utilitarianism, and Three Essays on Religion, and their subsequent effects on liberalism. Comparing the notion on individual freedom espoused in On Liberty to the notion of the social welfare in Utilitarianism, this analysis posits that it is impossible for a political philosophy to have two ultimate ends. Thus, Mill's liberalism is inherently flawed. As this philosophy was the foundation of Mill's progressive vision for humanity that he discusses in his Three Essays on Religion, this vision becomes paradoxical as well. Contending that the neo-liberalist global economic order is the contemporary parallel for Mill's religion of humanity, this work further demonstrates how these philosophical flaws have spread to infect the core of globalization in the 21 st century as well as their implications for future international relations.
    [Show full text]
  • Download Article
    Advances in Social Science, Education and Humanities Research (ASSEHR), volume 252 3rd International Conference on Judicial, Administrative and Humanitarian Problems of State Structures and Economic Subjects (JAHP 2018) The Money Factor from the Perspective of the Adherents of a Subsistence Economy and Mercantilism Yakov Yadgarov Department of Economic Theory Financial University under the Government of the Russian Federation Moscow, Russia E-mail: [email protected] Sergei Tolkachev Vladimir Ostroumov Department of Economic Theory Department of Economic Theory Financial University under the Government of the Russian Financial University under the Government of the Russian Federation Federation Moscow, Russia Moscow, Russia E-mail: [email protected] E-mail: [email protected] Abstract—The purpose of this work is to outline general considering the special role of this factor in all aspects of and special aspects in different perceptions of the place and public life, have also considered the money factor. role of money and money circulation in economic life. This is done by means of historical and economic analysis of the views This is clearly reflected, first, in natural economy "money of the adherents of subsistence economic ideology in the ideology". Towering achievements are considered, from Ancient world and the Middle Ages, as well as of the views of interpretations of the essence and purpose of money by rulers, mercantilists, who were the pioneers of market economic scholars, and philosophers of ancient Oriental and Antique ideology. The objective was to show substantial aspects of public entities until medieval times in those countries in conventional money theory existed in these time periods and which interpretation of the purpose of the money was seen include alternative versions, such as nominalist, metallist, and through the prism of religious, philosophical, and moral- quantity theories.
    [Show full text]
  • Money Supply ECON 40364: Monetary Theory & Policy
    Money Supply ECON 40364: Monetary Theory & Policy Eric Sims University of Notre Dame Fall 2017 1 / 59 Readings I Mishkin Ch. 3 I Mishkin Ch. 14 I Mishkin Ch. 15, pg. 341-348 2 / 59 Money I Money is defined as anything that is accepted as payments for goods or services or in the repayment of debts I Money serves three functions: 1. Medium of exchange 2. Unit of account 3. Store of value I Any asset can serve as a store of value (e.g. house, land, stocks, bonds), but most assets do not perform the first two roles of money I Money is a stock concept { how much money you have (in your wallet, in the bank) at a given point in time. Income is a flow concept 3 / 59 Roles of Money I Medium of exchange role is the most important role of money: I Eliminates need for barter, reduces transactions costs associated with exchange, and allows for greater specialization I Unit of account is important (particularly in a diverse economy), though anything could serve as a unit of account I As a store of value, money tends to be crummy relative to other assets like stocks and houses, which offer some expected return over time I An advantage money has as a store of value is its liquidity I Liquidity refers to ease with which an asset can be converted into a medium of exchange (i.e. money) I Money is the most liquid asset because it is the medium of exchange I If you held all your wealth in housing, and you wanted to buy a car, you would have to sell (liquidate) the house, which may not be easy to do, may take a while, and may involve selling at a discount if you must do it quickly 4 / 59 Evolution of Money and Payments I Commodity money: money made up of precious metals or other commodities I Difficult to carry around, potentially difficult to divide, price may fluctuate if precious metal or commodity has consumption value independent of medium of exchange role I Paper currency: pieces of paper that are accepted as medium of exchange.
    [Show full text]
  • Voluntary National Content Standards in Economics 2Nd Edition Voluntary National Content Standards in Economics
    Voluntary national ContEnt StandardS in EConomics 2nd Edition Voluntary national ContEnt StandardS in EConomics 2nd Edition WRITING COMMITTEE ACKNOWLEDGMENTS John Siegfried, Writing Committee Chair Many individuals reviewed the Voluntary National Vanderbilt University Content Standards in Economics, 2nd Edition. The individuals listed below provided special assistance Alan Krueger, Writing Committee Co-Chair in helping develop the content of the standards. Through February 2009 Princeton University Stephen Buckles Vanderbilt University Susan Collins University of Michigan Bonnie Meszaros University of Delaware Robert Frank Cornell University James O’Neill University of Delaware Richard MacDonald St. Cloud State University Robert Strom Ewing Marion Kauffman Foundation KimMarie McGoldrick University of Richmond John Taylor Stanford University George Vredeveld University of Cincinnati FUNDING The Council for Economic Education gratefully acknowledges the funding of this publication by the United States Department of Education, Office of Innovation and Improvement, Excellence in Economic Education: Advancing K-12 Economic & Financial Education Nationwide grant award U215B050005-08. Any opinions, findings, conclusions, or recommendations expressed in the publication are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the view of the U.S. Department of Education. Copyright © 2010, Council for Economic Education, 122 East 42 Street, Suite 2600, New York, NY 10168. All rights reserved. The Content Standards and Benchmarks in this document may be reproduced for non-commercial educational and research purposes. Notice of copyright must appear on all pages. Printed in the United States of America. ISBN 978-1-56183-733-5 5, 4, 3, 2, 1 ii Voluntary national Content StandardS IN eCONOMiCS Contents PREFACE . v FOREWORD TO THE FIRST EDITION .
    [Show full text]
  • Editorial IE 6 08.Indd
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Appelbaum, Eileen Article — Published Version The Obama moment Intereconomics Suggested Citation: Appelbaum, Eileen (2008) : The Obama moment, Intereconomics, ISSN 0020-5346, Springer, Heidelberg, Vol. 43, Iss. 6, pp. 314-315, http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10272-008-0265-8 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/42015 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu DOI: 10.1007/s10272-008-0265-8 The Obama Moment he election of Barack Obama on November 4 to serve as the next president of the USA Twas a triumph of hope over history for America. In these perilous times we, along with millions in other lands, have pinned our hopes for the future on the intellect, inspiration and compassion of this gifted leader.
    [Show full text]
  • (Missing: How Lowering Land Prices Encourages Saving
    George’s Economics of Abundance: Replacing dismal choices with practical resolutions and synergies Mason Gaffney Introduction: Resolutions vs. trade-offs It is part of George’s genius that his proposals solve one problem by resolving it with another, turning two problems into one solution. It is something like tuning up the orchestra for a concert, turning dissonance into harmony, and keeping the beat together, turning cacaphony into rhythm. It is the mark of good solutions that they reconcile and resolve, rather than simply “trade-off.”1 That is what George means when he writes that “the laws of the universe are harmonious.” That is what Founding Fathers like Washington, Jefferson and Franklin meant by a “natural order.” Like them, George is a deist in spirit, a believer in the consistency of the universe. The concept that some things are more “natural” than others is not arbitrary. The clue that one has found the “natural” law is that it makes forces harmonize and team together instead of clashing, and neutralizing each other.2 The principle of constructive synthesis–a touch of Hegel–is another way of perceiving the value of turning cacaphony into harmony.3 Economists today offer us mainly “trade-offs” and hard choices. For every good thing we must give up another, so net gains are just marginal. That is the approved posture: it makes one seem hard-headed, worldly, and practical. Too much positive thinking sounds suspiciously optimistic, and invites rebellious cynical muttering that “there ain’t no free lunch.” It goes back at least to Malthus, who offered mankind the hard choice of food vs.
    [Show full text]
  • Translating Ideas Into Action
    DIALOGUE uis Moreno, president of the Inter-Amer- ican Development Bank, strode to the podium at ELI’s annual dinner to intro- duce Henry “Hank” Paulson, former sec- retary of the treasury and chief executive of Goldman Sachs — and winner of the 2016 ELI Award for career achievement in environmental policy. L“He’s a man of big ideas but not just any ideas,” Moreno said. “He wants to translate ideas into action. This is a characteristic that you seldom find, because ideas are easy, realizations are difficult. The world owes a lot to Hank. I come from a region that has had a lot Translating Ideas of financial crises. Hank managed these in a way that not only saved the United States but saved the world. Into Action He did it because of his tenacity, because of his capac- ity to think big, his ability to bring people together to find common ground.” Former banker and Treasury Secretary Following Moreno’s introduction, Paulson took the stage along with Beveridge & Diamond managing HANK PAULSON took the stage at the annual principal Ben Wilson, who was to be Paulson’s inter- dinner and responded to questions about locutor during a dialogue on his long and interesting career. environmental protection in China and Ben Wilson: Secretary Paulson, you have focused environmental policy in the United States on China for many years as an important region for environmental progress. Take a moment please and and internationally. Paulson’s conclusion: tell us why China is important. When did your inter- It takes business, NGOs, and government est in that country first begin? Hank Paulson: As my career progressed at Gold- working together to get things done man Sachs, I wanted to stay in Chicago, and I was finally made co-head of investment banking in that city.
    [Show full text]
  • Open Market Operations and Money Supply at Zero Nominal Interest Rates
    Open Market Operations and Money Supply at Zero Nominal Interest Rates Roberto Robatto∗ University of Chicago October 21, 2012 (first draft: February 2012) Abstract What are the paths of money supply that are consistent with zero nominal interest rates and that can be implemented through open market operations? To answer this question, I present an Irrelevance Proposition for some open market operations that exchange money and one-period bonds at the zero lower bound. The result has implications for the conduct of monetary policy (non-irrelevant open market operations modify the equilibrium) and for the implementation of the Friedman rule (any growth rate of money supply above the negative of the rate of time preferences can implement zero nominal interest rate forever, even a positive growth rate, provided that the government collects \large enough" surpluses). The result holds under several specifications, including models with heterogeneity, non- separable utility, borrowing constraints, incomplete and segmented markets and sticky prices; and generalizes to any situation in which the cost of holding money vs. bonds is zero, such as the payment of interest on money. ∗Email: [email protected]. I am extremely greatful to Fernando Alvarez for his suggestions and guidance. I would like to thank also John Cochrane, Thorsten Drautzburg, Tom Sargent, Harald Uhlig and participants to the AMT, Capital Theory and Economic Dynamics Working Groups at the University of Chicago for their comments. 1 1 Introduction At zero nominal interest rates, money is perfect substitutes for bonds from the point of view of the private sector. Money demand is thus not uniquely determined, therefore the equilibrium in the money market depends on the supply of money.
    [Show full text]