East Asia's Economic Success: Conflicting Perspectives, Partial Insights, Shaky Evidence Author(S): Robert Wade Source: World Politics, Vol

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

East Asia's Economic Success: Conflicting Perspectives, Partial Insights, Shaky Evidence Author(S): Robert Wade Source: World Politics, Vol Trustees of Princeton University Review: East Asia's Economic Success: Conflicting Perspectives, Partial Insights, Shaky Evidence Author(s): Robert Wade Source: World Politics, Vol. 44, No. 2 (Jan., 1992), pp. 270-320 Published by: Cambridge University Press Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2010449 . Accessed: 17/07/2011 20:08 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at . http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=cup. Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. Cambridge University Press and Trustees of Princeton University are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to World Politics. http://www.jstor.org ReviewArticle EAST ASIA'S ECONOMIC SUCCESS ConflictingPerspectives, Partial Insights, ShakyEvidence By ROBERT WADE* Alice Amsden. Asia's Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization. New York: Oxford UniversityPress, 1989, 379 pp. Stephan Haggard. Pathwaysfrom the Periphery:The Politicsof Growthin the Newly IndustrializingCountries. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990, 276 pp. Helen Hughes, ed. Achieving Industrializationin East Asia. Cambridge: Cambridge UniversityPress, 1988, 377 pp. Don't listen to "comparative advantage" advice. Whenever we wanted to do anythingthe advocates of comparativeadvantage said, "We don't have comparativeadvantage." In fact,we did everything we wanted, but whateverwe did, we did well. -Governor Park Korea Central Bank' I do not believe thatthe firmscould have organized a supercomputer project themselvesbecause businesspeopledid not believe in the feas- ibilityand profitabilityof this kind of supercomputerin the near fu- ture. Our pressureor promotionwas needed. -Senior MITI official2 THE NEOLIBERAL INTERPRETATION OF EAST ASIAN SUCCESS OVER the past two decades a literature big enough to fill a small airplane hangar has been produced on the causes of East Asian economic success. Of that which is economically literate the mainstream adopts what could be called a "neoliberal" interpretation. This says that * The authoracknowledges Adrian Wood, Ronald Dore, ManfredBienefeld, Olivia Cox- Fill, JulieGorte, and Michael Lipton. The usual exonerationapplies with more than usual force. I Quoted in Yoginder Alagh, "The NiEs and the Developing Asian and PacificRegion: A View fromSouth Asia," Asian Development Review 7, no. 2 (1989), 116.I thankDevesh Kapur forthis reference. 2 Cited in MartinFransman, The Market and Beyond: Cooperation and Competition in In- formation Technology in the Japanese System (Cambridge:Cambridge University Press, 1990), 176. World Politics 44 (January 1992), 270-320 EAST ASIA'S ECONOMIC SUCCESS 271 the East Asian countrieswere more successfulthan others in terms of long-rungrowth because, in essence,they stuck more firmlyto the pre- scriptionsfor short-runefficient resource allocation derived from the theoremsof neoclassical economics. Neoliberal here refersto a subsetof neoclassical economics. Its mem- bers believe thatas a general rule the neoclassicalprescriptions for short- run optimal resourceallocation are also the core recipe for maximizing the rate of long-termgrowth. Other neoclassicals, by contrast,draw more of a distinctionbetween the two kinds of analyses,introducing a more complex array of variables into growth issues than they use for questions of optimum resource allocation. Neoliberals are inclined to think that "getting the prices right" is both a necessaryand a nearly sufficientcondition formaximizing the rate of long-termgrowth ("get- ting" in the sense of lettingprices find theirright levels, and "right" in the sense of the relativeprices establishedin freelyoperating domestic and internationalmarkets); other neoclassicals would say that it is no more than necessary.Relatedly, neoliberals believe thatmost market fail- ure is a resultof governmentpolicies and that,even in those uncommon cases where market failureoccurs forother reasons, the welfarecosts of remedial governmentintervention can often be expected to be greater than the welfaregains. This weightingof probabilitiesis based on a rel- ativelycoherent theory of perversegovernment, as set out, forexample, in the works of William Niskanen and David Colander.3 In the neoliberal view, growth is a natural or inherentproperty of capitalisteconomies. Governmentshave an importantrole in providing those "public goods," such as physicalinfrastructure, law enforcement, macroeconomic stability,and perhaps education,that are difficultto ar- range through private contracts.But beyond that they should not go, except in those rare cases of marketfailure referred to above. The prob- lem is thatmost governmentshave in factgone well beyondthese limits, 3Niskanen, Bureaucracyand RepresentativeGovernment (Chicago: Aldine-Atherton,1971); and Colander, ed., NeoclassicalPolitical Economy: The Analysisof Rent-seekingand DUP Activ- ities(Cambridge: Ballinger,1984). For an academic example of neoliberaldevelopment eco- nomics,see Deepak Lal, The Povertyof DevelopmentEconomics (London: IEA Hobart Pa- perback no. 16, 1983). For a policy paper based on neoliberal assumptions,see, e.g., AcceleratedDevelopment in Sub-saharanAfrica: An Agendafor Action (Washington,D.C.: World Bank, 1981),commonly known as the Berg report.For an example of tendentioususe of evidence in the neoliberalcause, see Michael Michaelyet al., LiberalizingForeign Trade: Lessonsof Experience from Developing Countries, vols. 1-7 (Oxford: Blackwells,for the World Bank, 1991), esp. summaryvolume. For a critique of neoliberalism,see ChristopherCol- clough, "Structuralismversus Neo-liberalism:An Introduction,"in Colclough and James Manor, eds., Statesor Markets?Neo-liberalism and the DevelopmentPolicy Debate (Oxford: Oxford UniversityPress, 1991). For a critique of the study by Michaely et al., see David Evans, "Institutions,Sequencing, and Trade Policy Reform" (Geneva: UNCTAD, May 1991). 272 WORLD POLITICS adopting policies thatinterfere, intentionally or not,with the freework- ing of markets.East Asian governmentshave stayedwithin these limits. Hence, East Asian economic success,which in turn resoundinglyvindi- cates the general neoliberalprescriptions. Those who outline this argumentas a preliminaryto a critique often find themselvesaccused of settingup a straw man; no respectedecono- mist is as simplisticas that,they are told. So it is importantto establish that thisis a fairshort summary of the core neoliberalposition, that it is what respectedeconomists say. Enter Helen Hughes,4editor of Achieving Industrializationin East Asia, definitelynobody's idea of a straw man. What policies have been criticalto economic success in East Asia? she asks. Her answer: The conclusionis that"unshackling exports" (that most of theEast Asian countrieshad themselvesat firstshackled) has beenthe key to success. How- ever,it is also clearthat successful performance needs several [other] policy strands.Political stability and therule of law are essential.Economic pol- iciesapparently distorted prices less than was thecase in mostother devel- opingcountries; macroeconomic management was relativelysuccessful, all economicsectors, particularly agriculture,5 were developed, and publicin- vestmentin social and physicalinfrastructural facilities was productive. Wherethese economic conditions did notprevail, as in thePhilippines, the economy faltered.Governments thus provided the environmentfor growth;but private enterprise, despite risk and uncertainty,made thein- vestmentsnecessary and throughexposure to internationalcompetition be- came efficientand profitable.(pp. xv-xvi) As for replicationby poorer countries,"There seems littledoubt that if otherdeveloping countries had followedsimilar economic policies they would also have grown more rapidlyand would thus have been able to alleviate the povertyof theirlow income groups as well as avoiding high national indebtedness"6(p. xvi). This is cast in the past tense-"if other 4Professor of economicsand directorof the National Center forDevelopment Studies at the AustralianNational University,formerly a high-rankingofficial at the World Bank. 5 It is not clear what Hughes means at this point, but she presumablymeans that the governmentdirected its attentionto developingagriculture, among othersectors. But state policies toward agriculturein Korea and Taiwan differedgreatly from standard market- based prescriptions.For an account of the highlydirigiste role of the state in developing Korean and Taiwanese agriculture,see Wade, "South Korea's AgriculturalDevelopment: The Mythof the Passive State,"Pacific Viewpoint 24 (May 1983); idem, Irrigationand
Recommended publications
  • Dirigisme Taiwan-Style'
    View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by IDS OpenDocs Dirigisme Taiwan-Style' Robert Wade There isa popular image of Taiwan as a close consistent with the way the government has in practice approximation to a free market economy. Indeed it is behaved. often held up as living proof that the basic prescription of neoclassical economics is sound not only for The government has adopted over a long period of advanced industrial countries but also for countries en time a much more aggressive set of industrial policies roule to that status.Private initiativeisalways than free trading principles would justify. It has been preferred to public, the state is kept firmly in its place. anticipating, rather than simply reacting to, changes in The chief characteristic, and the chief glory of this Taiwan's international competitive position. And it arrangement is the absence of any directional thrust has been selecting between industries and specific imposed by the authority of government. Rather, products in giving substantial incentives. market forces produce the important economic * * * decisions, while the government merely registers them. Industrialisation proceeds by virtue of the sum of the Taketheanticipationpointfirst.Theusual autonomous decisions made by each producer. interpretation says that the push into heavy and chemical industries dates from the early 1970s, after More precisely, the argument for Taiwan is that the and in response to rising real wages, competition from government did meddle in the economy during the other NICs, and rising protectionist barriers in export 1950s imposing all the familiar battery of controls markets.
    [Show full text]
  • Bringing the State Back In: Lessons from East Asia's Development Experience*
    Bringing the State Back In: Lessons from East Asia’s Development Experience* ROBERT H. WADE ince the end of communist regimes in Eastern Europe, policy makers Sand policy analysts in these »transition« states have resolutely turned away from learning about East Asia’s development experience. They have been very keen, on the other hand, to learn about Western European and North American experience – for this is the world they wish to join, or rather, re-join after the communist hiatus. With few exceptions, they un- derstand the causes of the prosperity of Western Europe and North America through the lens of »liberal« economics – as due, in large part, to the combination of (a) liberal markets for goods and financial assets only lightly restrained by public policies, (b) well-defined and well-en- forced property rights allowing secure profit-taking by owners, and (c) the rule of law, which makes government, and all other economic agents, subject to a common set of rules. This is the combination they wish to copy, in the expectation that it will yield »catch-up« growth. To the extent that they pay attention to East Asia’s catch-up experience, they under- stand it to validate the same model. To the extent that they acknowledge the existence of pro-active industrial and technology policy in either Western Europe or East Asia, they treat it as an aberration or decoration on the central thrust for largely free markets. The last thing Eastern European policy makers and policy analysts want is a state that intervenes to alter the composition of economic activ- ity within their borders; for this is what the communist state did, to di- sastrous effect.
    [Show full text]
  • Robert Wade on Zombie Ideas, Being Inside the World Bank, and the Death of Ethics in Economics After the Marginal Revolution
    Theory Talks Presents THEORY TALK #72 ROBERT WADE ON ZOMBIE IDEAS, BEING INSIDE THE WORLD BANK, AND THE DEATH OF ETHICS IN ECONOMICS AFTER THE MARGINAL REVOLUTION Theory Talks is an interactive forum for discussion of debates in International Relations with an emphasis of the underlying theoretical issues. By frequently inviting cutting-edge specialists in the field to elucidate their work and to explain current developments both in IR theory and real-world politics, Theory Talks aims to offer both scholars and students a comprehensive view of the field and its most important protagonists. Citation: Schouten, P. (2015) ‘Theory Talk #72: Robert Wade on Zombie Ideas, Being Inside the World Bank, and the Death of Ethics in Economics after the Marginal Revolution’, Theory Talks, http://www.theory- talks.org/2015/12/theory-talk-72.html (07-12-2015) WWW.THEORY-TALKS.ORG ROBERT WADE ON ZOMBIE IDEAS, BEING INSIDE THE WORLD BANK, AND THE DEATH OF ETHICS IN ECONOMICS AFTER THE MARGINAL REVOLUTION The global economy is at the core of some of the main issues in contemporary International Relations. But how do we understand the global economy and what impact does that have on how we deal with the power politics around it? A fault line seems to have emerged between those who take economic theory seriously and those who denounce it for being part of the problem. Informed by his training as an anthropologist, Robert H. Wade—professor at the LSE—takes a different tack: he bases his engagement with the way in which Adam Smith has been appropriated to advocate for a dominant view of ‘free markets’ on real-world economics and in-depth accounts of insiders.
    [Show full text]
  • 02 Gallagher-Interview.Indd
    The Economic Crisis and the Developing World CRISIS AND REGULATION The Economic Crisis and the Developing World: What Next? Interview with Robert Wade and José Antonio Ocampo Kevin Gallagher Some believe that the current fi nancial and economic crises have ended the dominance of the Washington Consensus once and for all. In a ceremony at Tufts University, two eminent international economists, Robert Wade and José Antonio Ocampo, were recently awarded the Leontief Prize for advancing economic thought. They were interviewed by Kevin Gallagher on the many issues affecting the future of developing economies, including trade agreements with the developed world. The perceptive interview and provocative responses provide rare, clear-minded discussion about enlightened policy for the world’s poorer nations. ROBERT WADE is professor of political economy and development at the London School of Economics. JOSÉ ANTONIO OCAMPO is a professor of international and public affairs and codirector, with Joseph Stiglitz, of the Initiative for Policy Dialogue, Columbia University. KEVIN GALLAGHER is assistant professor of international relations at Boston University and research associate at the Global Development and Environment Institute (GDAE), Tufts University. This interview with José Antonio Ocampo and Robert Wade was conducted on the occasion of their being awarded the GDAE’s 2008 Wassily Leontief Award for Advancing the Frontiers of Economic Thought, November 17, 2008. Challenge, vol. 52, no. 1, January/February 2009, pp. 27–39. © 2009 M.E. Sharpe,
    [Show full text]
  • 13 Apr 2011 DRAFT – NOT for QUOTATION the RETURN of INDUSTRIAL POLICY Robert Wade London School of Economics
    1 13 Apr 2011 DRAFT – NOT FOR QUOTATION THE RETURN OF INDUSTRIAL POLICY Robert Wade London School of Economics ABSTRACT: Recent events (like the global financial crisis, the long North Atlantic slump, and the uprisings in the Middle East and North Africa), on top of accumulating evidence that many middle income countries are stuck in a “middle income trap”, have generated a renewed interest in industrial policy – in the state playing a more active role in accelerating industrial upgrading and diversification than sanctioned by the neoclassical mainstream. In other words, a renewed interest in moving beyond the “regulatory” state towards the “developmental” state. After the introduction, this paper describes the core arguments of the neoclassical mainstream against industrial policy, and the kinds of empirical evidence used to support the negative judgement. It then outlines some of the main flaws in this evidence. The standard empirical tests consider industrial policy only in its “hard”, price distorting forms, such as protection and subsidies. And they examine effects mainly at the “micro” level, in the link between the policies and various aggregates of individual firms. The paper argues that industrial policy also consists of “soft” measures, not readily captured by measures of money spent or prices distorted; and it also has “meso” level effects on supra-firm structures, which are also not readily captured by the standard tests. With the “hard/soft” and “micro/meso” distinctions in mind, the paper shows that the US – generally understood to be a classic “regulatory” state, without industrial policies (or else ones which pick losers) – has long deployed “under the radar” soft industrial policies operating at the meso level; in particular, public policies and institutions for creating and sustaining networks between firms, venture capitalists, universities, and public agencies.
    [Show full text]
  • An Inquiry Into the Development of Nations
    OUP CORRECTED PROOF – FINAL, 05/08/19, SPi Asian Transformations OUP CORRECTED PROOF – FINAL, 05/08/19, SPi UNU World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU-WIDER) was established by the United Nations University as its first research and training centre and started work in Helsinki, Finland, in 1985. The mandate of the institute is to undertake applied research and policy analysis on structural changes affecting developing and transitional economies, to provide a forum for the advocacy of policies leading to robust, equitable, and environmentally sustainable growth, and to promote capacity strengthening and training in the field of economic and social policymaking. Its work is carried out by staff researchers and visiting scholars in Helsinki and via networks of collaborating scholars and institutions around the world. United Nations University World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU-WIDER) Katajanokanlaituri 6B, 00160 Helsinki, Finland <www.wider.unu.edu> OUP CORRECTED PROOF – FINAL, 05/08/19, SPi Asian Transformations An Inquiry into the Development of Nations Edited by DEEPAK NAYYAR A study prepared for the United Nations University World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU-WIDER) 1 OUP CORRECTED PROOF – FINAL, 05/08/19, SPi 1 Great Clarendon Street, Oxford, OX2 6DP, United Kingdom Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford. It furthers the University’s objective of excellence in research, scholarship, and education by publishing worldwide. Oxford is a registered trade mark of Oxford University Press in the UK and in certain other countries © United Nations University World Institute for Development Economics Research (UNU-WIDER) 2019 World Institute for Development Economics Research of the United Nations University (UNU-WIDER), Katajanokanlaituri 6B, 00160 Helsinki, Finland The moral rights of the authors have been asserted First Edition published in 2019 Impression: 1 Some rights reserved.
    [Show full text]
  • Public Lecture: 'Globalization, Development and Inequality' by Joseph Stiglitz, Ravi Kanbur and Robert Wade
    Public Lecture: 'Globalization, Development and Inequality' by Joseph Stiglitz, Ravi Kanbur and Robert Wade Date / Time: January 8, 2013 - 5:00pm - 7:00pm Venue: Sathya Sai Samskruta Sadanam, Hosur Road, Next to Forum Mall, Bangalore - 560029 Enquiries / RSVP: [email protected] Facebook Link: Link to Facebook Abstract: The speakers are interested in identifying the complex global interactions that influence poverty and development as well as strategies for development that have proven successful in promoting equitable growth, promoting capabilities and reducing poverty. Given these enormous challenges and the need for a great variety of initiatives at multiple levels to resolve them, the first step is to build a new generation of scholars and practitioners that understand these issues. One of the key problems in realizing the potential of globalization, to make it fairer and to tackle the scourge of poverty, is that the approach must be integrated across not only different disciplines, but also regions. A Note on the Speaker: About Joseph Stiglitz Joseph E. Stiglitz was born in Gary, Indiana in 1943. A graduate of Amherst College, he received his PHD from MIT in 1967, became a full professor at Yale in 1970, and in 1979 was awarded the John Bates Clark Award, given biennially by the American Economic Association to the economist under 40 who has made the most significant contribution to the field. He has taught at Princeton, Stanford, MIT and was the Drummond Professor and a fellow of All Souls College, Oxford. He is now University Professor at Columbia University in New York and Co- Chair of Columbia University's Committee on Global Thought.
    [Show full text]
  • After the Crisis: Industrial Policy and the Developmental State in Low-Income Countrie
    Global Policy Volume 1 . Issue 2 . May 2010 150 After the Crisis: Industrial Policy and the Developmental State in Low-Income Countries Research Article Robert Wade London School of Economics and Political Science Abstract Policy Implications The current global economic crisis has been • Liberalizing markets, attracting FDI and pro- disastrous for many millions of people. But it has moting good governance are not necessary condi- also had the desirable effect of prompting a little tions of long-term economic growth and more skepticism towards the economic beliefs that development in low-income countries. have constituted the mainstream view about public • In the wake of the global financial crisis and the economic strategy for the past three decades, both impending surge of new technologies, the role of in the major western states and in international industrial policy – promoting some sectors or lending organizations like the World Bank and the products ahead of others – should be expanded. IMF. They have at their core the proposition that • Import replacement as well as export orientation ‘government failure is generally worse than market are crucial components of a successful industrial failure’, which supports the default policy setting of policy. ‘more free market’ in most countries most of the • Four organizational features are important in a time. The new crisis-induced skepticism is good developmental state: (1) an even balance between news because the previous confidence rested more the state and business groups; (2) a public service on what J. S. Mill called ‘the deep slumber of a mindset among state officials; (3) delivery of settled opinion’ than on a solid empirical base.
    [Show full text]
  • The Management of Common Property Resources: Collective Action As an Alternative to Privatisation Or State Regulation
    Cambridge Journal of Economics 1987,11, 95-106 The management of common property resources: collective action as an alternative to privatisation or state regulation Robert Wade* Under what circumstances will villagers co-operate to supply themselves with goods and services that they all need but could not provide for themselves individually? In what circumstances are those who face a potential 'tragedy of the commons' able to organise a system of rules by which the tragedy is averted? Many writers on collective action and common property consider that these circum- stances are very limited. A long line of collective action theorists has argued that people placed in a situation in which they could all benefit from co-operation will be unlikely to co-operate in the absence of an external enforcer of agreements. An equally long line of theorists on property rights has argued that common property resources are bound to be over-exploited as demand rises. The only solution is private enclosure, according to some theorists, or state regulation, according to others.1 In Robert Smith's words, 'it is by treating a resource as a common property that we become locked in its inexorable destruction' (1981, p. 465). My own research findings from South India are difficult to reconcile with these argu- ments. Within one small area, I found some villages with a more sophisticated set of arrangements for regulating canal irrigation and grazing (and for supplying other public goods as well) than had been previously reported for Indian villages. Other villages nearby, however, showed no sign of these arrangements.
    [Show full text]
  • Curriculum Vitae ROBERT H. WADE
    Curriculum Vitae ROBERT H. WADE – BIO * Professor of political economy at the London School of Economics since 2001. New Zealand/UK citizen * Winner of Leontief Prize for Advancing the Frontiers of Economic Thought, 2008. Other winners (since it began in 2000) include J. K. Galbraith, Amartya Sen, Richard Nelson, Robert Frank, Herman Daly, Alice Amsden, Juliet Schor, Dani Rodrik, Daniel Kahneman, Nick Stern, Frances Stewart, Albert Hirschman. * Google Scholar citation score (Harzing’s index): ranked #2 out of 87 full professors of Political Science/Government, IR, European Studies, and International Development at LSE, Essex and Oxford (September 2010). * Out of some 60 applications, selected to be first holder of Sanjaya Lall visiting professor at Oxford University, 2011. * Governing the Market (Princeton UP, 1990, 2004) won American Political Science Association’s Best Book/Article in Political Economy award, for publications in 1989-91. It has been translated into Chinese (twice, one for mainland, one for Taiwan), Korean, Japanese, Vietnamese, Spanish. * Founding member of the ‘Financial Times’ Economists’ Forum, a by-invitation group which it described as “50 of the world’s most influential economists”. * At least four papers of past few years are “most cited” or “most downloaded”: (1) “Is globalization reducing poverty and inequality?”, World Development, 32, 4, 2004. The single most frequently downloaded paper from World Development in 2007 and 2008 (source: managing editor Karen Molgaard). (2) "On the causes of increasing poverty and inequality, or why the Matthew effect prevails", New Political Economy, 9, 2, June, 2004. The most frequently downloaded paper from New Political Economy in 2007 (source: editor Nicola Phillips).
    [Show full text]
  • WIDER Working Paper 2018/120: Industrial Development in Asia
    WIDER Working Paper 2018/120 Industrial development in Asia Trends in industrialization and industrial policy experiences of developing Asia Ha-Joon Chang and Kiryl Zach* September 2018 Abstract: Industrial transformation of Asia arguably constitutes the most surprising and dramatic change in the global economy in the last fifty years. This paper provides an outline of some of the most important trends of this development and analyses selected national industrial policies that promoted structural transformation in developing Asia during the period. In the first part, we describe crucial dimensions of industrialization in the region—its extent, its historical trajectory, and the resulting industrial upgrading. In the second part, we use four case studies—of the Republic of Korea, Malaysia, China, and India—to describe some of the strategies which Asian economies used in order to induce industrial development. We argue that more successful cases did not try to implement a golden policy template but rather pragmatically adopted their policies to overcome specific bottlenecks and meet strategic objectives. Keywords: industrialization, industrial policy, structural transformation, development, case studies, developing Asia JEL classification: L16, L52, O14, O25 Acknowledgements: We thank Deepak Nayyar and the reviewers for their invaluable suggestions throughout the preparation of this paper. Earlier versions were presented in seminar at Central Institute for Economic Management (CIEM) in Hanoi, Vietnam. We also thank Rob Vos, Robert Wade, Kaushik Basu, Frances Stewart, Finn Tarp, Tony Addison, and other seminar participants for their insightful comments and suggestions. *Centre of Developing Studies, University of C ambridge, Cambridge, UK; corresponding author: Ha-Joon Chang, email: [email protected].
    [Show full text]
  • How South Korea and Taiwan Grew Rich
    GROWTH POUCY 55 Getting interventions right: how South Korea and Taiwan grew rich Dani Rodrik Columbia University 1. INTRODUCTION To any economist interested in growth, the East Asian experience since the early 1960s poses enduring challenges. In 1960, South Korea was poorer than many sub-Saharan African countries, and Taiwan not all that much richer (Table 1). Since then, these two countries have experienced average increases in per-capita income of 6.8% and 6.2% respectively, with the result that they have left far behind not only these African countries, but also others like Mexico and Argentina which had been much richer. How these two countries managed to transform themselves from economic basket cases into economic powerhouses remains something of an enigma. The standard story to which most orthodox economists subscribe is one of export-led growth (see, for example, Tsiang, 1984; Kreuger, 1985; World Bank, 1993; little, 1994). During the 1950s, the story goes, both of these countries engaged in traditional import substitution policies, with multiple exchange rates, high levels of trade protection, and repressed financial markets. By the late 1950s, each country had exhausted the 'easy stage' of import substitution. This, together with the impending reduction in US aid - which had been the main source of I am grateful tojagdish Bhagwati, Paul de Grauwe, Ann Harriion, Aivind Panagariya, Andi^ Rodriguez-Clare, Robert Wade, Adrian Wood, Ahvyn Young, Panel memben and especially Gene Grouman and Charles Wyplosz for helpful comments, Eytsung Kim for excellent research assistance, and the CEPR MIRAGE project for financial assistance. 56 DANIRODWK Table 1.
    [Show full text]