Do Hedge Funds Exploit Rare Disaster Concerns?"

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

Do Hedge Funds Exploit Rare Disaster Concerns? Do Hedge Funds Exploit Rare Disaster Concerns? George P. Gaoy, Pengjie Gaoz, and Zhaogang Songx First Draft: July 2012 This Draft: July 2016 Abstract We …nd hedge funds that have higher return covariation with a disaster concern index, wihch we develop through out-of-the-money puts on various economic sector indices, earn signi…cantly higher returns in the cross section. We provide substantial evidence that these funds have better skills in exploiting the market’s ex ante rare disaster concerns (SED), which may not realize as disaster shocks ex post. In particular, high-SED funds on average outperform low-SED funds by 0:96% per month, but have less exposure to disaster risk. They continue to deliver superior future performance when SED is estimated using the disaster concern index purged of disaster risk premium, and have leverage-managing and extreme-market-timing abilities. We also provide strong evidence against alternative interpretations. Keywords: Rare disaster concern; hedge fund; skill JEL classi…cations: G11; G12; G23 We would like to thank Warren Bailey, Sanjeev Bhojraj, Craig Burnside, Martijn Cremers, Zhi Da, Christian Dorion, Itamar Drechsler, Ravi Jagannathan, Bob Jarrow, Alexandre Jeanneret, Andrew Karolyi, Soohun Kim, Veronika Krepely, Tim Loughran, Bill McDonald, Roni Michaely, Pam Moulton, Narayan Naik, David Ng, Maureen O’Hara, Sugata Ray, Gideon Saar, Paul Schultz, David Schumacher, Berk Sensory, Mila Getmansky Sherman, Laura Starks (the editor), Shu Yan, Jianfeng Yu, Lu Zheng, Hao Zhou, and two anonymous referees for their helpful discussions and comments, as well as seminar participants at the City University of Hong Kong, Cornell University, HEC Montreal, University of Notre Dame, the 2013 China International Conference in Finance, the 2013 EFA Annual Meeting, the 2013 FMA Annual Meetings, the 2014 MFA Annual Meetings, the 2015 AFA Annual Meetings, the 3rd Luxembourg Asset Management Summit, the 6th Paris Hedge Fund Research Conference, Texas A&M University, and University of Hawaii. We are especially grateful to Zheng Sun for help on clustering analysis; Kuntara Pukthuanthong for data on benchmark factors; and Sang Seo and Jessica Wachter for data on model-implied option prices. Financial support from the Q-group is gratefully acknowledged. The RIX index and its components are available from authors’ websites for academic use. The analysis and conclusions set forth are those of the authors and do not indicate concurrence by the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. ySamuel Curtis Johnson Graduate School of Management, Cornell University. Email: [email protected]; Tel: (607) 255–8729 zFinance Department, Mendoza College of Business, University of Notre Dame. E-mail: [email protected]; Tel: (574) 631-8048. xCarey Business School, Johns Hopkins University. E-mail: [email protected]. Tel: (410)-234-9392 2 1 Introduction Prior research on hedge fund performance and disaster risk focuses on the covariance between fund returns and ex post realized disaster shocks. In the time series, a number of hedge fund investment styles, characterized as de facto sellers of put options, incur substantial losses when the market goes south (Mitchell and Pulvino (2001) and Agarwal and Naik (2004)). In the cross section, individual hedge funds have heterogeneous disaster risk exposure, and funds with larger exposure to disaster risk usually earn higher returns during normal times, followed by losses during stressful times (Agarwal, Bakshi, and Huij (2010); Jiang and Kelly (2012)). At its face value, the existing evidence suggests that hedge funds are much like conventional assets in an economy with disaster risk: they earn higher returns simply by being more exposed to disaster risk. We provide novel evidence that some hedge fund managers with skills in exploiting ex ante market disaster concerns, which may not be realized as ex post disaster shocks, deliver superior future fund performance while being less exposed to disaster risk. Our basic idea is illustrated in Figure 1, which plots the monthly time-series of a rare disaster concern index (RIX) we construct using out-of-the-money put options on various economic sector indices. The index value at time t is essentially equal to the price of insurance against extreme downside movements of the …nancial market from time t to (t + ) in the future (see Section 2 for details). The graph shows the following salient feature of the market’sdisaster concerns. When market shocks occur at time t, concerns for future disasters between t and (t+) increases substantially. Most importantly, the magnitude of such increased concerns at time t seems to be enormous relative to subsequently realized losses, if any, between t and (t + ).1 This startling di¤erence between the ex ante disaster concerns and the ex post realized shocks suggests that investors may be paying a “fear premium”beyond the compensation for the disaster risk. In fact, Bollerslev and Todorov (2011) suggest that the fear premium is a critical component of market returns. Such a fear premium can be consistent with the behavior of agents with non-expected utility or constrained agents who face market frictions and are averse to tail events (Liu, Pan, and Wang (2005); Bates (2008); Caballero and Krishnamurthy (2008); Barberis (2013)), or consistent 1 Another feature of disaster concerns is that the index spikes not only when disaster shocks hit the market such as the LTCM collapse, the crash of Nasdaq, and the recent …nancial crisis, but also during bull markets such as the peak of Nasdaq and the market rally in October 2011. 1 with market mispricing or sentiment (Bondarenko (2004); Han (2008)). Under these circumstances, hedge fund managers with better skills in exploiting such disaster concerns or “fear premium”could deliver superior future fund performance. How can some hedge funds exploit such ex ante disaster concerns better than others while being less exposed to the ex post realization of disaster shocks? First, some fund managers may be better than others at identifying market concerns that are fears with no subsequent disaster shocks. By supplying disaster insurance to investors with high disaster concerns, some fund managers pro…t more than others who do not possess such skills and are thus unable to take advantage of these opportunities.2 Second, even when disaster concerns are subsequently realized as disaster shocks, some fund managers may be better than others at identifying whether there is a “fear premium” beyond the compensation for realized shocks. By extracting such a “fear premium”, they pro…t more than others who do not possess such skills. Third, “di¢ culty in inference regarding ... severity of disasters ... can e¤ectively lead to signi…cant disagreements among investors about disaster risk” (Chen, Joslin, and Tran (2012)). Di¤erent investors can have di¤erent disaster concerns with di¤erent levels of “fear premium”when the market’sdisaster concern is high, regardless of whether it is followed by a realized disaster shock or not. Some hedge fund managers may have better skills at identifying the investors who are willing to pay higher premiums for disaster insurance. From an operational perspective, even some of the standard …nancial insurance contracts, including options on …xed-income securities, currencies, and a subset of equities, are traded on over-the-counter (OTC) markets. Thus, hedge funds with di¤erent networks may have di¤ering ability to locate investors who are willing to pay high premiums. In summary, skills in exploiting disaster concerns can contribute to higher returns for certain hedge funds, and at the same time not necessarily make them more exposed to disaster shocks. While the covariance between hedge fund returns and ex post realized shocks helps us to under- stand hedge fund risk pro…les, it is the covariance between hedge fund returns and ex ante disaster concerns that helps us to identify skillful fund managers. In principal, when the market’s disaster concern is high, funds with more skilled managers should earn higher contemporaneous returns 2 “Supplying disaster insurance”here does not literally mean hedge funds write a disaster insurance contract to investors. As argued by Stulz (2007), hedge funds, as a group of sophisticated and skillful investors who frequently use short sales, leverage, and derivatives, are capable of supplying earthquake-type rare disaster insurance through dynamic trading strategies, market timing, and asset allocations. 2 than those with less skilled managers in supplying disaster insurance. Empirically, we measure fund skills in exploiting rare disaster concerns (SED) using the covariation between fund returns and the disaster concern index we construct.3 Consistent with our view that hedge funds exhibit di¤erent levels of skills in exploiting disaster concerns, we document substantial heterogeneity of SED across hedge funds as well as signi…cant persistence in SED. Our main tests focus on the relation between the SED measure and future fund performance. In our baseline results, funds in the highest SED decile on average outperform funds in the lowest SED decile by 0:96% per month (Newey-West t-statistic of 2:8).4 Moreover, high-SED funds exhibit signi…cant performance persistence. The return spread of the high-minus-low SED deciles ranges from 0:84% per month (t-statistic of 2:6) for a three-month holding horizon, to 0:44% per month (t- statistic of 1:9) for a 12-month holding horizon. We also show that the outperformance of high-SED funds is pervasive across almost all hedge fund investment styles. These results are inconsistent with the view that hedge funds earn higher returns on average simply by being more exposed to disaster risk. If the SED measure, as the covariation between fund returns and the disaster concern index, is interpreted as measuring disaster risk exposure, high-SED funds on average should earn lower returns (rather than the higher returns we document) because they are good hedges against disaster risk under this interpretation.
Recommended publications
  • Can Sweden Afford Another High Equity Premium?
    Undergraduate Economic Review Volume 6 Issue 1 Article 3 2010 Can Sweden Afford Another High Equity Premium? Matthew K. Miller University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.iwu.edu/uer Recommended Citation Miller, Matthew K. (2010) "Can Sweden Afford Another High Equity Premium?," Undergraduate Economic Review: Vol. 6 : Iss. 1 , Article 3. Available at: https://digitalcommons.iwu.edu/uer/vol6/iss1/3 This Article is protected by copyright and/or related rights. It has been brought to you by Digital Commons @ IWU with permission from the rights-holder(s). You are free to use this material in any way that is permitted by the copyright and related rights legislation that applies to your use. For other uses you need to obtain permission from the rights-holder(s) directly, unless additional rights are indicated by a Creative Commons license in the record and/ or on the work itself. This material has been accepted for inclusion by faculty at Illinois Wesleyan University. For more information, please contact [email protected]. ©Copyright is owned by the author of this document. Can Sweden Afford Another High Equity Premium? Abstract This paper calculates the empirical equity premium in Sweden between 1919-2006 and disaster probabilities of 25% and 50% contractions in real Gross Domestic Product. The calculation puts the equity premium at approximately 8%, 2% higher than what appears in the historical United States data, due to rare disaster events outside and idiosyncratic to Sweden. This study makes two important contributions. First, it projects that Sweden can afford the economic cost of another high equity premium but should remain cautious.
    [Show full text]
  • Empirical Asset Pricing with Multi-Period Disaster Risk: a Simulation-Based Approach
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Sönksen, Jantje; Grammig, Joachim Working Paper Empirical Asset Pricing with Multi-Period Disaster Risk: A Simulation-Based Approach CFR Working Paper, No. 14-06 Provided in Cooperation with: Centre for Financial Research (CFR), University of Cologne Suggested Citation: Sönksen, Jantje; Grammig, Joachim (2020) : Empirical Asset Pricing with Multi-Period Disaster Risk: A Simulation-Based Approach, CFR Working Paper, No. 14-06, University of Cologne, Centre for Financial Research (CFR), Cologne, http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3377345 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/222986 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu CFR Working Paper NO.
    [Show full text]
  • Rare Disasters and Exchange Rates∗
    RARE DISASTERS AND EXCHANGE RATES∗ Emmanuel Farhi Xavier Gabaix Harvard, CEPR and NBER NYU, CEPR and NBER August 26, 2015 Abstract We propose a new model of exchange rates, based on the hypothesis that the possibility of rare but extreme disasters is an important determinant of risk premia in asset markets. The probability of world disasters as well as each country’s exposure to these events is time-varying. This creates joint fluctuations in exchange rates, interest rates, options, and stock markets. The model accounts for a series of major puzzles in exchange rates: excess volatility and exchange rate disconnect, forward premium puzzle and large excess returns of the carry trade, and comovements between stocks and exchange rates. It also makes empirically successful signature predictions regarding the link between exchange rates and telltale signs of disaster risk in currency options. JEL codes: G12, G15. ∗[email protected], [email protected]. We are indebted to the editor and two referees for detailed and helpful suggestions. Mohsan Bilal, Igor Cesarec, Alex Chinco, Sam Fraiberger, Aaditya Iyer and Cheng Luo provided excellent research assistance. For helpful comments, we thank partici- pants at various seminars and conferences, and Fernando Alvarez, Robert Barro, Nicolas Coeurdacier, Daniel Cohen, Mariano Croce, Alex Edmans, François Gourio, Stéphane Guibaud, Hanno Lustig, Matteo Maggiori, Anna Pavlova, Ken Rogoff, José Scheinkman, John Shea, Hyun Shin, Andreas Stathopoulos, Adrien Verdelhan, Jessica Wachter. We thank the NSF (SES-0820517) for support. 1 I. Introduction We propose a new model of exchange rates, based on the hypothesis of Rietz (1988) and Barro (2006) that the possibility of rare but extreme disasters is an important determinant of risk premia in asset markets.
    [Show full text]
  • Recovery from Economic Disasters Bruno Ćorić Blanka Perić Škrabić
    Working Paper Series 676 (ISSN 1211-3298) Recovery from Economic Disasters Bruno Ćorić Blanka Perić Škrabić CERGE-EI Prague, November 2020 ISBN 978-80-7343-483-0 (Univerzita Karlova, Centrum pro ekonomický výzkum a doktorské studium) ISBN 978-80-7344-565-2 (Národohospodářský ústav AV ČR, v. v. i.) Recovery from Economic Disasters Ćorić Brunoa,b,* aUniversity of Split, Faculty of Economics, Cvite Fiskovića 5, 21000 Split, Croatia bCERGE-EI Foundation Teaching Fellow, 110 Jabez Street #1004, Newark, NJ 07105 USA (email: [email protected]) Škrabić Perić Blankac cUniversity of Split, Faculty of Economics, Cvite Fiskovića 5, 21000 Split, Croatia (email: [email protected]) November 2020 Abstract This study uses two large datasets to explore the output dynamics following economic disasters, one including 180 economic disasters across 38 countries over the last two centuries, and the other including 204 economic disasters in 182 countries since World War II. Our results suggest that extreme economic crises are associated with huge and remarkably persistent output loss. On average, output loss surges to above 26 percent in the first few years after the outbreak of an economic disaster and remains above 20 percent for as long as 20 years. It is only after more than 50 years that the loss is fully recovered. Key words: economic disaster, output loss, economic recovery. JEL: E32; N10. Number of Words: 6,658 *Corresponding author: Bruno Ćorić, University of Split, Faculty of Economics, Cvite Fiskovića 5, 21000 Split, Croatia, e-mail: [email protected], telephone: ++385914430724 1 1. Introduction Economic disasters are rare but extremely large economic crises, defined in Barro and Ursúa (2008) as a cumulative decline in output and/or consumption over one or more years of at least 10 percent.
    [Show full text]
  • The Total Risk Premium Puzzle
    FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO WORKING PAPER SERIES The Total Risk Premium Puzzle Òscar Jordà Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco University of California, Davis Moritz Schularick University of Bonn CEPR Alan M. Taylor University of California, Davis NBER CEPR March 2019 Working Paper 2019-10 https://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/publications/working-papers/2019/10/ Suggested citation: Jordà, Òscar, Moritz Schularick, Alan M. Taylor. 2019. “The Total Risk Premium Puzzle,” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper 2019-10. https://doi.org/10.24148/wp2019-10 The views in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reflecting the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco or the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. The Total Risk Premium Puzzle ? Oscar` Jorda` † Moritz Schularick ‡ Alan M. Taylor § March 2019 Abstract The risk premium puzzle is worse than you think. Using a new database for the U.S. and 15 other advanced economies from 1870 to the present that includes housing as well as equity returns (to capture the full risky capital portfolio of the representative agent), standard calculations using returns to total wealth and consumption show that: housing returns in the long run are comparable to those of equities, and yet housing returns have lower volatility and lower covariance with consumption growth than equities. The same applies to a weighted total-wealth portfolio, and over a range of horizons. As a result, the implied risk aversion parameters for housing wealth and total wealth are even larger than those for equities, often by a factor of 2 or more.
    [Show full text]
  • Rare Disaster Risk and the Equity Premium Puzzle
    Rare Disaster Risk and the Equity Premium Puzzle Henk Berkmana, Ben Jacobsen b, John Lee a a University of Auckland, Auckland, New Zealand b Massey University, Auckland, New Zealand Abstract The probability of rare disasters helps to explain the longstanding equity premium puzzle. Global political instability, our proxy for rare disaster risk, is a significant determinant of the expected market risk premium based on analyst target prices. Consistent with long- run risk models, uncertainty about expected GDP growth and expected consumption growth are also significantly positively related to the expected market risk premium. We obtain similar results when we use the earning-price ratio and the dividend-price ratio as proxies for the expected market risk premium. JEL Classifications: G12; G15 Keywords: Equity Premium; Rare Disasters; Consumption Risk; International Political Crises; Market Risk Premium Corresponding author: [email protected] (H. Berkman) 1. Introduction This study provides novel evidence supporting the claim that the probability of rare disasters explains the longstanding equity premium puzzle raised in Mehra and Prescott (1985). 1 Figure 1 illustrates the main point of our paper. We plot the expected market risk premium based on estimates from analyst target prices against the expected level of global political instability based on the crisis severity index developed in Berkman, Jacobsen and Lee (2011). [Figure 1 here] The correlation between the two annual series in Figure 1 is 0.51 (p-value is 0.006; at a monthly frequency the correlation is 0.34 with a p-value of 0.0001). This highly significant correlation confirms the main prediction in time-varying disaster risk models: expected returns on stocks relative to bonds are high when the probability of disasters is high (see, e.g., Gabaix 2009, Wachter 2009, and Gourio, 2008).
    [Show full text]
  • Variable Rare Disasters: an Exactly Solved Framework for Ten Puzzles in Macro-Finance∗
    VARIABLE RARE DISASTERS: AN EXACTLY SOLVED FRAMEWORK FOR TEN PUZZLES IN MACRO-FINANCE∗ XAVIER GABAIX This article incorporates a time-varying severity of disasters into the hy- pothesis proposed by Rietz (1988) and Barro (2006) that risk premia result from the possibility of rare large disasters. During a disaster an asset’s fundamental value falls by a time-varying amount. This in turn generates time-varying risk premia and, thus, volatile asset prices and return predictability. Using Downloaded from the recent technique of linearity-generating processes, the model is tractable and all prices are exactly solved in closed form. In this article’s framework, the following empirical regularities can be understood quantitatively: (i) equity premium puzzle; (ii) risk-free rate puzzle; (iii) excess volatility puzzle; (iv) predictability of aggregate stock market returns with price-dividend ratios; (v) often greater explanatory power of characteristics than covariances for asset http://qje.oxfordjournals.org/ returns; (vi) upward-sloping nominal yield curve; (vii) predictability of future bond excess returns and long-term rates via the slope of the yield curve; (viii) corporate bond spread puzzle; (ix) high price of deep out-of-the-money puts; and (x) high put prices being followed by high stock returns. The calibration passes a variance bound test, as normal-times market volatility is consistent with the wide dispersion of disaster outcomes in the historical record. The model extends to a setting with many factors and to Epstein-Zin preferences. JEL Codes: E43, E44, G12. at New York University School of Law on May 1, 2012 I.INTRODUCTION There has been a revival of a hypothesis proposed by Rietz (1988) that the possibility of rare disasters, such as economic depressions or wars, is a major determinant of asset risk premia.
    [Show full text]
  • Rare Macroeconomic Disasters
    Rare Macroeconomic Disasters Robert J. Barro1 and José F. Ursúa2 1 Department of Economics, Harvard University, Cambridge, Massachusetts 02138; email: [email protected] 2 Department of Economics, Harvard University, Cambridge, Massachusetts 02138; email: [email protected] August 2011 Key words: national accounts, rare disasters, disaster probability, fat tails, power-law distribution, equity premium, asset-pricing puzzles. Abstract The potential for rare macroeconomic disasters may explain an array of asset-pricing puzzles. Our empirical studies of these extreme events rely on long-term data now covering 28 countries for consumption and 40 for GDP. A baseline model calibrated with observed peak-to-trough disaster sizes accords with the average equity premium with a reasonable coefficient of relative risk aversion. High stock-price volatility can be explained by incorporating time-varying long- run growth rates and disaster probabilities. Business-cycle models with shocks to disaster probability have implications for the cyclical behavior of asset returns and corporate leverage, and international versions may explain the uncovered-interest-parity puzzle. Richer models of disaster dynamics allow for transitions between normalcy and disaster, bring in post-crisis recoveries, and use the full time series on consumption. Potential future research includes applications to long-term economic growth and environmental economics and the use of stock- price options and other variables to gauge time-varying disaster probabilities. i Contents 1. INTRODUCTION 2. MEASURING EXTREME MACRO-FINANCIAL EVENTS 2.1 Recent Improvements in Data on National-Accounts Variables and Asset Returns 2.2 Statistical Properties of Macroeconomic Growth Rates and Asset Returns 2.3 Macroeconomic Disaster Events 3.
    [Show full text]
  • Macroeconomic Implications of Time-Varying Risk Premia
    WORKING PAPER SERIES NO 1463 / AUGUST 2012 MACROECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS OF TIME-VARYING RISK PREMIA François Gourio ECB LAMFALUSSY FELLOWSHIP PROGRAMME ,QDOO(&% SXEOLFDWLRQV IHDWXUHDPRWLI WDNHQIURP WKH»EDQNQRWH NOTE: This Working Paper should not be reported as representing the views of the European Central Bank (ECB). The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the ECB. Lamfalussy Fellowships This paper has been produced under the ECB Lamfalussy Fellowship programme. This programme was launched in 2003 in the con- text of the ECB-CFS Research Network on “Capital Markets and Financial Integration in Europe”. It aims at stimulating high-quality research on the structure, integration and performance of the European financial system. The Fellowship programme is named after Baron Alexandre Lamfalussy, the first President of the European Monetary Institute. Mr Lamfalussy is one of the leading central bankers of his time and one of the main supporters of a single capital market within the Eu- ropean Union. Each year the programme sponsors five young scholars conducting a research project in the priority areas of the Network. The Lamfa- lussy Fellows and their projects are chosen by a selection committee composed of Eurosystem experts and academic scholars. Further information about the Network can be found at http://www.eufinancial-system.org and about the Fellowship programme under the menu point “fellowships”. Acknowledgements This paper has been prepared by the author under the Lamfalussy Fellowship Program sponsored by the ECB. Any views expressed are only those of the author and do not necessarily represent the views of the ECB or the Eurosystem.
    [Show full text]
  • Rare Disasters, Financial Development, and Sovereign Debt∗
    Rare Disasters, Financial Development, and Sovereign Debt∗ Sergio Rebelo† Neng Wang‡ Jinqiang Yang§ February 3, 2021 Abstract We propose a model of sovereign debt in which countries vary in their level of finan- cial development, defined as the extent to which they can issue debt denominated in domestic currency in international capital markets. We show that low levels of financial development generate the \debt intolerance" phenomenon that plagues emerging mar- kets: it reduces overall debt capacity, increases credit spreads, and limits the country's ability to smooth consumption. JEL Classification: F34 ∗We thank two anonymous referees and an associate editor, as well as Gideon Bornstein, Satyajit Chatter- jee, Dirk Krueger, Peter DeMarzo, Wenxin Du, Brett Green, Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti, Zhiguo He, Matteo Maggiori, Tom Sargent, Jesse Schreger, and Wei Xiong for their helpful comments. †Northwestern University and NBER. Email: [email protected]. ‡Columbia Business School and NBER. Email: [email protected]. §Shanghai University of Finance and Economics (SUFE). Email: [email protected]. 1 Introduction One intriguing fact about sovereign debt markets is that emerging economies pay high credit spreads on their sovereign debt, despite generally having much lower debt-output ratios than developed countries. Reinhart, Rogoff, and Savastano (2003) call this phenomenon \debt intolerance." In this paper, we propose a model of sovereign debt in which countries vary in their level of financial development. By “financial development," we mean the extent to which a country can issue debt denominated in domestic currency in international capital markets.1 We show that low levels of financial development generate debt intolerance.
    [Show full text]
  • Greening Monetary Policy: Climate Change Expectations and the Natural Rate
    Greening Monetary Policy: Climate Change Expectations and the Natural Rate Alexander M. Dietrich, Gernot J. M¨ullerand Raphael S. Schoenle∗ December 9, 2020 Abstract Using a representative consumer survey in the U.S., we elicit beliefs about the economic impact of climate change. Respondents perceive a high probability of costly, rare disasters due to climate change, but not much of an impact on GDP growth. Salience of rare disasters through media coverage increases the probability by up to 10 percentage points. Increasing expectations about climate-change related disasters matter for monetary policy because they lower the natural rate of interest. We quantify this effect in a standard New Keynesian model and find that the natural rate drops by about 70 basis points. If monetary policy fails to accommodate this drop, inflation and output decline by about 0.5 percent. Keywords: Climate change, Disasters, Households Expectations, Survey, Media focus, Monetary policy, Natural rate of interest, Paradox of Communication JEL-Codes: E43,E52,E58 ∗Dietrich: University of T¨ubingen,Email: [email protected]; M¨uller:University of T¨ubin- gen, CEPR and CESifo, [email protected]; Schoenle: Brandeis University and Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, CEPR and CESifo, Email: [email protected]. The views stated in this paper are those of the authors and are not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. We are grateful to Harald Uhlig for an insightful discussion which helped us to get this project started. \I want to explore every avenue available in order to combat climate change." | Christine Lagarde - ECB, July 8, 2020 \[...] it is vital for monetary policymakers to understand the nature of climate disturbances to the economy, as well as their likely persistence and breadth, in order to respond effectively." | Lael Brainard - FED, November 8, 2019 1 Introduction Climate change is a hotly debated topic and as such it presents a rising, complex challenge for policymakers.
    [Show full text]
  • Rare Disasters, Regional Banks, and Recovery Lending∗
    Borrowers Under Water! Rare Disasters, Regional Banks, and Recovery Lending∗ Michael Koetter (Deutsche Bundesbank, IWH, Otto-von-Guericke-University)y Felix Noth (IWH, Otto-von-Guericke-University) Oliver Rehbein (IWH) Abstract We test if and how banks adjust their lending in response to disaster risk in the form of a natural catastrophe striking its customers: the 2013 Elbe flooding. The flood affected firms in East and South Germany and we identify shocked banks based on bank-firm relationships gathered for more than a million firms. Banks with relationships to flooded firms lend 13-23% more than banks without such customers compared to the pre-flooding period. This lending hike is associated with higher profitability and reduced risk. Our results suggest that local banks are an effective mechanism to mitigate rare disaster shocks faced especially by small and medium firms. JEL classification: G21, G29, O16, Q54 Keywords: Disaster risk, credit demand, natural disaster, relationship lenders ∗We thank Reint Gropp, Lars Norden, and Steven Ongena for valuable comments and suggestions. We are grateful for feedback from participants at the Ph.D. seminar series at the IWH, the 9th RGS Conference in Bochum, the 2016 EEA conference in Geneva, and the 2016 German Finance Association meeting in Bonn. Support from the German Association of Insurances in terms of claim rates data due to natural disasters is highly appreciated. The opinions expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of any of the associated institutions. All errors are our own. yCorresponding author. Leibniz-Institute for Economic Research (IWH), Kleine M¨arkerstraße 8, G-06108 Halle (Saale).
    [Show full text]