The Interaction Between Within-Group and Neighborhood-Level Social Behavior Of
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Interaction between Within-Group and Neighborhood-Level Social Behavior of
Cooperatively Breeding Organisms
THESIS
Presented in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree Master of Science in the Graduate School of The Ohio State University
By
Benjamin James Stucke
Graduate Program in Evolution, Ecology and Organismal Biology
The Ohio State University
2018
Master's Examination Committee:
Dr. Ian Hamilton, Advisor
Dr. Jacqueline Augustine
Dr. Elizabeth Marschall
Copyrighted by
Benjamin James Stucke
2018
Abstract
For group-living animals, individual fitness can be affected by within-group interactions.
However, groups often have nearby neighbors and in these cases, groups can interact among each other. These neighborhood-level interactions allow for added fitness benefits, such as mutual between-group cooperation, selfish investment in other groups, or exploitation.
However, the payoffs to these depend on the behavior of other groups, and further, these within- group and between-group interactions are not independent of one another. Interactions at one level may affect an individual’s ability or willingness to interact at another. In chapter 2, I built a game theoretical model of dyads in a simple neighborhood (2 groups) to examine how the potential for between-group interactions can affect the willingness of individuals to cooperate with partners within their group. I modeled several scenarios in which between-group interactions can be beneficial to group-living individuals. Our scenarios included 1) mutual cooperation in which the benefit to a group is additive when each group cooperates, 2) increased additive selfish benefit to a group that cooperates 3) a synergistic benefit to mutual cooperation, and 4) increased cost of between-group cooperation. For all scenarios, I found that, if within- group cooperation was necessary for between-group cooperation, cooperative efforts were high.
However, if only one individual in a group needed to cooperate within the group to yield between group cooperation, within-group cooperation was lower but still greater than zero. In
Chapter 3, I created pairs of groups of the cichlid fish Neolamprologus pulcher in the laboratory, and manipulated conflict in one group of each pair by either removing dominant females and immediately returning them in control treatments, or removing them for an extended period of
i time and then returning them in experimental treatments. I then exposed each pair of groups to a visual predatory stimulus, acting as an assay for between-group cooperation. I predicted that groups with higher within-group conflict would exhibit less between-group cooperative efforts, while neighbors in these treatments would compensate and exhibit a greater amount of defensive behavior toward than stimuli than in control treatments. I found that experimental groups were less active over time. This suggests that avoidance may be an alternative tactic to submission for mitigating conflict within the group. Additionally, I found that experimental groups increased aggression toward the predator, in contrast with our predictions. These results, collectively, are important as they show that how an individual interacts in a complex social environment can be dynamic. Our results suggest that changes at the neighborhood level can influence within-group dynamics and these changes in the group can feedback into the neighborhood.
ii
Dedicated to my mother, grandmother, and sister
iii
Acknowledgments
Thank you for the guidance and feedback from my advisor Dr. Ian Hamilton throughout this entire process. Thank you to Antonia Tribuzzo for aiding in experimental execution and data collection. Thank you to the undergraduate volunteers and graduate/post-doctoral lab-mates in the Hamilton lab. This research was funded through a grant awarded by the National Science
Foundation (award number: 1557836).
iv
Vita
2012...... Elyria High School
2016...... B.S. Wildlife Biology, Ohio University
Fields of Study
Major Field: Evolution, Ecology and Organismal Biology
v
Table of Contents
Abstract ...... i
Acknowledgments...... iv
Vita ...... v
List of Tables ...... viii
List of Figures ...... ix
Chapter 1: Introduction ...... 1
Chapter 2: Effects of Potential for Between-Group Cooperation on Within-Group Dynamics ..... 7
Abstract ...... 7
Introduction ...... 8
Model Description ...... 12
Results ...... 19
Discussion ...... 20
Additional Materials ...... 33
Chapter 3: The Effect of Within-Group Conflict on Between-Group Interactions in
Neolamprologus pulcher ...... 52
Abstract ...... 52
vi
Introduction ...... 53
Methods ...... 56
Results ...... 63
Discussion ...... 74
Chapter 4: Conclusion...... 87
Works Cited ...... 91
vii
List of Tables
Table 2.1 Parameters for each scenario, *denotes the model being ran for all combinations of
variables with multiple values…………………………………………………………...17
Table 2.2: Each cell of the transition matrix aij gives the probability of a neighborhood state i
becoming state j in the next time step, as follows………………………………………..33
Table 3.1 ANOVA results for models a-d, significance denoted: 0 ‘***’ 0.001 ‘**’ 0.01 ‘*’ 0.05
‘.’ 0.1 ‘ ’ 1………………………………………………………………………………..67
Table 3.2 ANOVA results for models e- f, significance denoted: 0 ‘***’ 0.001 ‘**’ 0.01 ‘*’ 0.05
‘.’ 0.1 ‘ ’ 1………………………………………………………………………………..70
Table 3.3 ANOVA outputs for models g-i, Significance denoted: 0 ‘***’ 0.001 ‘**’ 0.01 ‘*’
0.05 ‘.’ 0.1 ‘ ’ 1…………………………………………………………………………..73
viii
List of Figures
Figure 2.1 The probability that an individual cooperates after receiving cooperation (p) based on
the between-group cooperative efforts for groups in state “cc” (P) and “cd” (R) across
low, intermediate, and high values of between group efforts for groups in state “dd” (Q)
for scenario 1, Base Mutual Cooperation. Other model parameters: k = 0.05…………..25
Figure 2.2 The probability that an individual cooperates after receiving defection (q) based on
the between-group cooperative efforts for groups in state “cc” (P) and “cd” (R) across
low, intermediate, and high values of between group efforts for groups in state “dd” (Q)
for scenario 1, Base Mutual Cooperation. Other model parameters: k = 0.05…………..26
Figure 2.3 The probability that an individual cooperates after receiving cooperation (p) based on
the between-group cooperative efforts for groups in state “cc” (P) and “cd” (R) across
low, intermediate, and high values of between group efforts for groups in state “dd” (Q)
for scenario 2, Increased Selfish Benefit. Other model parameters: k = 0.05…………...27
Figure 2.4: The probability that an individual cooperates after receiving defection (q) based on
the between-group cooperative efforts for groups in state “cc” (P) and “cd” (R) across
low, intermediate, and high values of between group efforts for groups in state “dd” (Q)
for scenario 2, Increased Selfish Benefit. Other model parameters: k = 0.05…………...28
Figure 2.5: The probability that an individual cooperates after receiving cooperation (p) based on
the between-group cooperative efforts for groups in state “cc” (P) and “cd” (R) across
low, intermediate, and high values of between group efforts for groups in state “dd” (Q)
for scenario 3, Increased Synergistic Benefit. Other model parameters: k = 0.05………29
ix
Figure 2.6: The probability that an individual cooperates after receiving defection (q) based on
the between-group cooperative efforts for groups in state “cc” (P) and “cd” (R) across
low, intermediate, and high values of between group efforts for groups in state “dd” (Q)
for scenario 3, Increased Synergistic Benefit. Other model parameters: k = 0.05………30
Figure 2.7: The probability that an individual cooperates after receiving cooperation (p) based on
the between-group cooperative efforts for groups in state “cc” (P) and “cd” (R) across
low, intermediate, and high values of between group efforts for groups in state “dd” (Q)
for scenario 4, Increased Between-Group Cost. Other model parameters: k = 0.05……31
Figure 2.8: The probability that an individual cooperates after receiving defection (q) based on
the between-group cooperative efforts for groups in state “cc” (P) and “cd” (R) across
low, intermediate, and high values of between group efforts for groups in state “dd” (Q)
for scenario 4, Increased Between-Group Cost. Other model parameters: k = 0.05…….32
Figure 2.9. The difference between probability that an individual cooperates after receiving
cooperation or defection (i.e., p – q) based on the between-group cooperative efforts for
groups in state “cc” (P) and “cd” (R) across low, intermediate, and high values of
between group efforts for groups in state “dd” (Q) for scenario 1, Base Mutual
Cooperation. Other model parameters: k = 0.05………………………………………..48
Figure 2.10: The difference between the probabilities that an individual cooperates after
receiving cooperation (p) and defection (q) based on the between-group cooperative
efforts for groups in state “cc” (P) and “cd” (R) across low, intermediate, and high values
of between group efforts for groups in state “dd” (Q) for scenario 2, Increased Selfish
Benefit. Other model parameters: k = 0.05……………………………………………49
x
Figure 2.11: The difference between the probability that an individual cooperates after receiving
cooperation (p) ore defection (q) based on the between-group cooperative efforts for
groups in state “cc” (P) and “cd” (R) across low, intermediate, and high values of
between group efforts for groups in state “dd” (Q) for scenario 3, Increased Synergistic
Benefit. Other model parameters: k = 0.05……………………………………………..50
Figure 2.12: The difference between the probability that an individual cooperates after receiving
cooperation (p) ore defection (q) based on the between-group cooperative efforts for
groups in state “cc” (P) and “cd” (R) across low, intermediate, and high values of
between group efforts for groups in state “dd” (Q) for scenario 4, Increased Between-
Group Cost. Other model parameters: k = 0.05………………………………………….51
Figure 3.1 experimental treatment involving the 2 hour removal of a dominant female from a
focal group and a control treatment involving the sham removal of a dominant female
from a focal group………………………………………………………………………..79
Figure 3.2 A flowchart of the experimental design. The experiment was broken down into 4
rounds, each including 2 parts…………………………………………………………...80
xi
Figure 3.3 Least Square Means of Counts of aggressive behaviors from individuals (model a)
over 15 minute observation periods from focal individuals pre-removal, post-removal,
post-removal and post-predator assay across all treatments involving the long-term
removal and reintroduction of a dominant female (experimental) or the removal and
immediate return of a dominant female (control). Significant differences were found
between experimental treatments pre-removal and experimental treatments post-removal,
experimental treatments post-removal and post-predator assay, and control treatments
post-removal……………………………………………………………………………..81
Figure 3.4 Least-square means counts of aggression by actor status for individuals in focal
groups during all observation times: pre-removal, post-removal, post-removal and post-
predator assay across across all treatments involving the long-term removal and
reintroduction of a dominant female (experimental) or the removal and immediate return
of a dominant female(control). Actor status is abbreivated as dominant male (DM),
dominant female (DF), large subordinate male (LSM), large suboridnate female (LSF).82
Figure 3.5 least-square means counts of total group aggression (model b) over 15 minute
observations for each period (pre-removal, post-removal, post-removal and post-predator
assay) across treatment and actor location. Experimental treatments involved the long-
term removal and reintroduction of a dominant female (experimental) or the removal and
immediate return of a dominant femal (control)………………………………………83
Figure 3.6 Least Square Means counts of affiliative behaviors (model c) over 15 minute
observation periods for focal individuals pre-removal, post-removal, post-removal and
post-predator assay across all treatments involving the long-term removal and
reintroduction of a dominant female (experimental) or the removal and immediate return
xii
of a dominant femal (control). Significant differences (p < 0.05 in post hoc tests) were
found between experimental treatments pre-removal and experimental treatments post-
removal, experimental treatments psot-removal and post-predator assay, and control
treatments post-removal………………………………………………………………84
Figure 3.7 Total counts of aggression toward the predator for neighbor groups plotted
againsttotal counts of aggression toward the predator for focal groups………………85
Figure 3.8 Least Square Means total counts of aggression behaviors toward the predator (model
f) over a 15 minute observation periods for focal and neighbor groups across all
treatments involving the long-term removal and reintroduction of a dominant female
(experimental) or the removal and immediate return of a dominant female (control).
Significant negative effects were found for control treatments and neighboring groups in
both treatments………………………………………………………………………….86
xiii
Chapter 1: Introduction
Living in groups can increase fitness benefits compared to solitary living (Bilde et al.
2007, Schradin et al. 2010, reviewed in rodents: Ebensperger 1999). For individuals that live in groups, fitness is not only influenced by an individual’s own behavior (Rhoades and Blumstein
2007), but also by the behavior of its group-mates (Warner 1995, Trillmich et al. 2004). The actions of an individual within a group can also be influenced by group membership (Conradt and Roper 2005), position in a group (spatial position: Blanco and Hirsch 2006, social rank:
Barta and Giraldeau 1998), or through the behaviors of other group members ( King et al. 2008,
Ostner et al. 2008). Interactions among group-mates can be cooperative (Eliassen and Joergenson
2014) as well as aggressive (Saito et al. 1998). Aggressive interactions within a group can be a result of conflict that has arisen within groups, such as during dominance hierarchy re- establishment (Wong and Balshine 2010, Wong et al. 2016). Within-group conflict can change the net benefits for individuals to cooperate with others within the group (Hannon et al. 1985,
Sheppard et al. 2018), and if escalated can result in the dissolution of the group altogether
(Aureli et al. 2002).
In addition, individual behavior and fitness can be influenced by the presence and behavior of other groups (Harris 2006, Cheney and Seyfarth 1982). The presence of other groups allows for between-group interactions, or neighborhood-level interactions (Cheney and Seyfarth
1987). These interactions can be cooperative (Krams et al. 2010, Gilby et al. 2012) or exploitative (Kitchen and Beehner 2007) and can increase the fitness of individuals who participate (reviewed by Clutton-Brock 2009). Cooperative interactions may occur because members of both groups receive a mutual benefit (Blumestein et al. 1997), such as joint defense of territories from predators (Micheletta 2012, Jungwirth et al. 2015). Exploitative interactions
1 with individuals in other groups may include opportunities for between-group mating; these interactions may be exploitative of same-sex members in neighboring group (Hughes et al. 2003,
Young et al. 2005).
There can be feedbacks among within-group and between-group levels. In other words, how an individual behaves within its group depends on the neighborhood context but the interactions of neighboring groups reflect, in part, the collective outcome of within-group behaviors. Tradeoffs between within- and between-group interactions can be present (Young et al. 2005), and can shift temporally with the strength of selection within- and between-groups for group beneficial traits (Dugatkin et al. 2003). Between-group interactions have been shown to be affected by within-group cooperation (Schradin and Pillay 2004) and conflict (Crofoot and Gilby
2012). Conversely, the presence of neighbors has shown to influence dynamics within a group
(Hellmann and Hamilton 2014), including whether individuals within the same group engage in aggressive conflict with one another (Hellmann and Hamilton 2018).
However, the interaction between the group-level social context and how the broader social context of between-group interactions emerges is poorly explored. It has previously been shown that the presence of neighbors can have an effect on the behavior of individuals
(Hellmann et al. 2014, Hellmann and Hamilton 2018, Maklakov et al. 2012). However, little work has been done taking into account the decisions of those neighbors and the effect that their behavior, instead of just their presence, has on the behavior of an individuals in both their direct social context (within-group) and broader social context (between groups). By using a game theoretical model, the payoffs for an individual in the model depend on their interactions with individuals both within- and between-groups, but also change based on how individuals in other groups interact with each other.
2
Game theoretical models, first utilized in behavioral ecology by Smith and Price (1973) allow us to model the evolution of cooperation between individuals (or groups of individuals) based on costs and benefits. We then are able to utilize games previously established (e.g. in this model, prisoner’s dilemma and hawk-dove) to reflect the pay-offs and costs for players to cooperate with one another in a given situation. We used the prisoner’s dilemma as in the game natural selection favors defection (unless the game is repeated sufficiently many times), even though the highest payoff for all players is mutual cooperation (Dawes 1980). The Hawk-Dove game looks at the role of aggression in social interactions, where the best strategy is to play
“Hawk” or aggressiveness toward unaggressive players, but not towards others when they are also aggressive (Maynard-Smith and Price 1973). In all of our scenarios we look at how conflict within groups and cooperation within groups can be modulated by between-group cooperation, and also how within-group dynamics can be influenced by between-group cooperation.
Cooperatively breeding species, in which individuals aggregate into groups with alloparental care, are found in a multitude of different taxa (canines: Creel et al. 1997, primates:
Terborgh and Goldizen 1985, rodents: Young et al. 2006, fish: Balshine et al. 1998).
Cooperatively breeding species are useful systems for studying both within-group cooperation and conflict (Blumstein et al. 1997, Bergmueller et al. 2007, Wong et al. 2016, Hannon et al.
1985). There is also substantial support through both empirical and theoretical works for how individuals in these groups make decisions on cooperation, competition, and exploitation (King and Cowlishaw 2007, Stueckle and Zinner 2008, Arnott and Elwood 2008). Further, many breeding groups interact with neighbors (Yeager 1992, Cheney 1981). Within these groups, conflict among individuals is a common phenomenon (Aureli et al. 2002). Conflict may place new social or energetic impositions on individuals (Aureli and Schaffner 2007), creating
3 limitations on how an individual can interact with their immediate social group or with others in the broader social context. By looking at social interactions in the broader context and also taking into account the dynamics within a group, a more accurate analysis of the social environment can be taken. By having this better-rounded approach, I can garner a better understanding of the interactions between cooperation in the broader social context and an individual’s behavior, reproductive success, and survival.
Here, I examine the effects that within-group conflict and between-group cooperation have on one another. I use a game theoretical model, in which the pay-offs to an individual cooperating in their group depends on the state of the overall neighborhood, inherently making dynamics within a group dependent on the dynamics between groups to explore how within- group dynamics of different groups interact with one another. Additionally, I used a cooperatively breeding cichlid fish, Neolamprologus pulcher, to examine how within-group conflict influences between-group cooperative interactions. These two projects, in combination with one another, give a better insight to the inter-relationship between within-group dynamics and between-group dynamics.
In chapter 2, I built a game theoretical model that elucidates the role that the potential for between-group cooperation has on within-group cooperation. The model included two groups, each containing two players. Using an invasion analysis, I looked at how strategies of within- group cooperation or defection can arise under different scenarios of between-group cooperation by varying the relative pay-offs for individuals for different neighborhood states. The scenarios I looked at in the model include 1) the highest pay-off for an individual arose when both groups cooperated with one another 2) the highest pay-off for an individual arose when their group attempted to cooperate with another group (investing in another group) 3) the highest pay-off for
4 an individual arose when their group defected on another group that is investing in cooperation
(exploitation of another group).
I found that if within-group cooperation was necessary for between-group cooperation, cooperative efforts were high. However, if only one individual in a group needed to cooperate within the group to yield between group cooperation, within-group cooperation was lower but still greater than zero. Our model shows that the potential benefits of between-group interactions can have a strong influence on an individual’s behavior and that the benefits of interacting in a neighborhood-level can be a potential predictor of within-group dynamics.
In chapter 3, I examined how within-group conflict affects the between-group cooperative efforts of a group, using groups of N. pulcher in the laboratory. In nature, breeding groups of these fish occupy permanent territories (Taborksy 1984), which are clustered in close proximity to one another creating a neighborhood-level interactive environment for individuals
(Striver et al. 2004). Within this neighborhood, between-group cooperation in the form of joint defense against predators may arise (Jungwirth et al. 2015). I paired cooperatively breeding groups together in one tank and separated them with a transparent barrier. To look at how within- group conflict can affect between-group cooperation I exposed one group in each pair to either a control treatment or an experimental treatment with the aim to increase conflict within the group.
The experimental treatment was an extended removal of the dominant female from the breeding group causing a social perturbation to the dominance hierarchy, where as the control treatment involved the removal and immediate return of a dominant female from a breeding group. After receiving the treatment, each pair were exposed to a visual predatory stimulus to examine the between-group cooperative effort of each group.
5
I found that all groups reduced activity after removal, but that experimental groups exposed to the longer removal had a longer overall suppression in within-group activity compared to control groups. I also found groups in experimental treatments were more aggressive toward the predator compared to control groups and compared to neighbors. These results show that avoidance may be an alternate tactic to mitigating conflict within-groups and that conflict within a group may prime that group to be more aggressive in other contexts, or present greater temporal opportunity for individuals in that group to act in other contexts. These results are important as they suggest that the within-group context can play either a direct role on the ability of an individual to participate in the broader social context in terms of available energy or time, or that within-group dynamics may shift the nature of an individual’s interactions in other contexts.
6
Chapter 2: Effects of Potential for Between-Group Cooperation on Within-Group Dynamics
Benjamin J. Stucke and Dr. Ian M. Hamilton
Abstract
For group-living animals, individual fitness can be affected by within-group interactions.
However, groups often have nearby neighbors and in these cases, groups can interact among each other. These neighborhood-level interactions allow for the added fitness benefits, such as mutual between-group cooperation, selfish investment in other groups, or exploitation.
However, the payoffs to these depend on the behavior of other groups, and further, these within- group and between-group interactions are not independent of one another. Interactions at one level may affect an individual’s ability or willingness to interact at another. I built a game theoretical model of dyads in a simple neighborhood (2 groups) to examine how the potential for between-group interactions can affect the willingness of individuals to cooperate with partners within their group. I modeled several scenarios in which between-group interactions can be beneficial to group-living individuals. Our scenarios included 1) mutual cooperation in which the benefit to a group is additive when each group cooperates, 2) increased additive selfish benefit to a group that cooperates 3) a synergistic benefit to mutual cooperation, and 4) increased cost of between-group cooperation. For all scenarios, I found that, if within-group cooperation was necessary for between-group cooperation, cooperative efforts were high. However, if only one individual in a group needed to cooperate within the group to yield between group cooperation, within-group cooperation was lower but still greater than zero. Increasing the selfish or synergistic benefit to a group increased an individual’s willingness to cooperate within their group, while increasing the cost of between-group cooperation decreased an individual’s
7 willingness to cooperate within their group. Our model shows that the potential benefits of between-group interactions can have a strong influence on an individual’s behavior and that the benefits of interacting in a neighborhood-level can be a potential predictor of within-group dynamics.
Keywords: Game theory, Neighborhood, Intergroup Cooperation
Introduction
For group-living organisms, the social landscape can include nearby individuals outside of their immediate social group. This broader social context, or neighborhood, creates a population-level social environment which in turn can influence selection on behaviors at the individual level (Krause, Lusseau, and James 2009). The nature of between-group interactions can be exploitative (Young et al. 2007), aggressive (Saito et al. 1998, Schuerch et al. 2010), or cooperative (Eliassen and Joergenson 2014). Exploitative neighborhood level interactions include extra-group copulations (Lazaro-Perea 2001). Aggressive encounters include resource competition between groups (Dow 1977, Cheney 1992, Harris 2006) or territoriality (Scradin and
Pillay 2004, Lazaro-Perea 2001, Peres 1989). Cooperative neighborhood interactions include information transmission for foraging (Whiten et al. 2007), or mutually benefiting by-products such as increased cooperative vigilance (Campobello et al. 2012). Individuals that extend interactions to the broader social landscape can gain added fitness benefits compared with those that limit their interactions to exclusively within their group (Gilby et al. 2012).
Cooperation among neighboring groups can arise because of a mutual benefit to each cooperating group (Strassman 1989, reviewed by Clutton-Brock 2009). For example, in pied
8 flycatchers (Ficedula hypoleuca) mobbing behavior of individuals was influenced by the presence of other mobbing conspecifics, resulting in overall increased defense against nest predators (Krams et al 2009). Similarly, in Neolamprologus pulcher, a cooperatively breeding cichlid, groups in close proximity to one another mutually defend against predators. Each group individually puts forth less defense than if they were defending solitarily; however, the total amount of defensive effort was comparable to a single group defending on its own (Jungwirth et al. 2015). These cooperative neighborhood interactions can lower the energy expenditure of all individuals involved while still facilitating success of both groups (Jungwirth et al 2015).
Bonobos (Pan paniscus) demonstrate xenophilia or prosociality toward neighboring individuals, which is suggested to facilitate cooperation between groups for access to resources (Tan et al
2015). Tan et al. (2015) suggest that the benefit of forming between-group cooperative bonds is much greater than the costs in bonobos. Pro-social signaling is therefore a benefit awarded to a group of extending cooperation regardless of the actions of the receiving group.
The interaction between within-group dynamics and between-group cooperation is poorly explored and, where it has been studied, is highly variable. Tradeoffs or synergies between within- and between-group interactions can be present (Mares et al. 2012, Young et al. 2005).
Within-group cooperation affects between-group interactions in the context of between-group competition or territoriality (Schradin and Pillay 2004). In vervet monkeys, Chlorocebus pygerythrus, which individuals one directs affiliative behaviors toward within the group can vary greatly between individuals, but the group will act cohesively in competition against other groups (Cheney 1992). In meerkats, Suricata suricatta, grooming behavior has been shown to play a role in group cohesion with dominant individuals within a group grooming subordinate males longer than females; this is suggested to be linked to subordinate males playing a larger
9 role in territory defense from extra-group males (Kutsukake and Clutton-Brock 2010). Similarly, the presence of an out-group threat from conspecifics leads to an increase in within-group affiliation in N. pulcher (Bruintjes et al. 2015). In this case, mutual cooperation within a group might be necessary to prevent exploitation by members of other groups.
On the other hand, all behaviors have costs and benefits associated with them, which can vary with differing social contexts (Parker and Stuart 1976) and the ability to participate in each of these behaviors may be limited as different types of behaviors can be differentially costly
(Grantner and Taborsky 1998). Therefore, it is expected that there can be tradeoffs between investing in within-group interactions and investment in between-group interactions. There is some evidence for such tradeoffs. The reforming of social ties within groups after conflict can cause limitations on a group’s ability to cooperate with others (Crofoot and Gilby 2012).
Finally, between-group cooperation might have little to do with within-group interactions. In other words, how groups of individuals interact with other groups can be independent of how individuals within groups interact with each other. For example, in the Arabian babbler
(Turdoides squamiceps), subordinate individuals participate in predator-directed mobbing behavior cooperatively between groups to advertise their quality for the formation of dispersal coalitions and not for the benefit of the group in which they are currently a member (Maklakov
2002).
Previous theoretical models have shown that neighbors play an important role in influencing within-group dynamics (Hellmann and Hamilton 2018a, Cant and Johnstone 2009).
Similarly, previous empirical studies have also shown the importance of neighbors on within- group conflict (Hamilton and Hellman 2018b), predator defense (Jungwirth et al. 2015,
Hellmann et al. 2014), and group membership (Hellmann et al. 2015, Bergmueller et al. 2005).
10
However, these previous approaches that have shown that neighbors play a key role on within- group dynamics rarely consider that neighbors themselves are also making within-group decisions. Our model expands on these previous works by incorporating neighboring group dynamics into our model. By incorporating neighboring group dynamics into our model, they too can influence the state of the neighborhood allowing us to garner a more realistic representation how groups of individuals might all have important but different influences in the broader cooperative social network.
The purpose of this model is to examine how the behavior of an individual within a group is influenced by the fitness effects of neighboring groups and the effects of within-group interactions on between-group interactions. Specifically, I test four scenarios of cooperation. In the first scenario, individuals receive the same benefit if either their group or the other group cooperates; if both cooperate, they receive twice the benefit. In the second scenario, individuals receive a greater benefit from their group cooperating than from their neighbor cooperating.
Again, if both cooperate, benefits are additive. In the third scenario, individuals receive a synergistic benefit if both groups cooperate. Finally, in the fourth scenario, there is again an additive benefit to mutual cooperation, but if only one group cooperates, individuals gain more from their neighbor cooperating than if their group cooperates. To test these four scenarios, I extended models of iterated pair-wise cooperation to incorporate conflict or cooperation between groups as well as cooperation or defection within groups. I built a model of a simple neighborhood (two groups, each containing two individuals and with symmetrical payoffs). This model was used to ask questions about the inter-play between inter-group and within-group cooperation of group-living animals. As both between-group and within-group cooperation can yield fitness benefits to an individual understanding when either form of cooperation is most
11 beneficial to an individual can help predict when either form of cooperation will arise in the social landscape.
Model Description
The model consists of two groups G = {F,N}, where F is the focal group and N is its neighbor. Each group in the model is comprised of two individuals for a total of four individuals in the game B = {F1, F2, N1, N2}. The strategy profile of a player consists of some probability of cooperating if its partner cooperated in a previous round ∈ (pi) and some probability of cooperating if its partner defected (qi). At any time, t, a pair, , consisting of individual i