The Credibility Effect and Rational Expectations

Total Page:16

File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb

The Credibility Effect and Rational Expectations WILLIAM FELLNER American Enterprise Institute TheCredibility Effect andRational Expectations: Implicationsof the GramlichStudy EDWARD GRAMLICH'SSTUDY in this issue raises a question by a method thathas frequentlybeen found fruitfulin scientificefforts. He presentsan interpretationof observeddata in termsof a widelyused analyticalframe- work that points to a very unfavorabledistribution of the consequences of demanddisinflation by undesirableoutput effects, on the one hand, anddesired price effects on the other.Yet he directsattention to the possi- bility that a reconstructionof the standardframework could reduce the weaknesseshe detectsin the interpretationhe presents.He does not favor the specificreinterpretation that I have suggestedin variouswritings1 and I will describebelow-indeed, he leans perhapsmore to an attitudeof doubt in this regard-but he has an open mind aboutthe methodsof im- provingthe conventionalframework. Essentially, he plays into the hands of all those of us who areeven moreskeptical than he is aboutthe conven- tional way of going about macroeconomicmodeling and who believe in the superiorityof a specificalternative. I would like to make use of the opportunityhis work provides.This is done partly with referenceto his empiricalfindings, to whichI turnin the thirdsection, afteran attemptto place the matterin perspective. The IncompleteOverlap between Two Hypotheses Conclusionsderived from analysisincorporating what may be termed the credibilityeffect overlap with conclusionsfrom analysis commonly 1. For instance, in Fellner, Towards a Reconstructionof Macroeconomics:Prob- lems of Theory and Policy (American EnterpriseInstitute, 1976). 0007-2303/79/0001-0167$00.25/0 ? Brookings Institution 168 BrookingsPapers on Economic Activity, 1:1979 associatedwith the hypothesisof rationalexpectations. Both hypotheses lead to a criticalattitude concerning essential features of the macroeco- nomic models most frequentlyused, but the two hypothesesneed to be distinguishedfrom each other.In this paperI brieflyjustify this statement and arguein favor of the hypothesisstressing the credibilityeffect. My conclusionis that once one eliminatesthe unconvincingelements from the rationalexpectations hypothesis, one is left with the credibilityhypothesis as it is here interpreted.The hypothesesunder consideration have the fol- lowingmain properties. Standardmodels-The frameworkspresently regarded as conventional explain the currentwage and price increaseof a period in large part by the precedingwage and priceincrease, though other variables such as the "slack,"usually measured by the unemploymentrate, also enter into the explanation.Expectations concerning future demand-management policy enterhere merelyimplicitly through the assumptionthat-for any chosen value of othervariables such as the slack-the pastmoney-wage and price increasesdetermine the currentwage increases by unchangingcoefficients. At the same time, in these models the currentmoney-wage increases play a very large role in determiningthe currentprice increases,also by un- changing coefficients.Thus there is no room in the standardmodels for the hypothesisthat a perceived change in the likely future conduct of demand-managementpolicies-in the consistency of those policies- would alter the effect of past wage and price increaseson the currentin- creases,or would alterthe currentincreases that become associatedwith any currentlyobserved slack. Both the credibilityhypothesis and the ra- tional expectationshypothesis are critical of the assumptionthat the money-wageand the price trend are insensitiveto the perceivedpolicy posture,except insofar as that postureexpresses itself in the currentlyob- served slack given the other variablesspecified in the standardmodels. The credibility hypothesis-The hypothesis of the credibility effect maintainsthat marketexpectations, and thus the effect of past money- wage and price increasesand of any currentlyobserved slack on current money-wageand price increases, are significantlyinfluenced by the ex- pectedfuture behavior of policymakers.Emphasis is placed on the differ- ence between states of the economy in which inconsistentpolicies lead marketparticipants to formdiffuse personal probability distributions with risk allowancesplaying a largerole in their decisionmaking,and states of the economyin whichfirm and crediblepolicies condition the public'sex- WilliamFellner 169 pectationsand lead to much more strongly peaked and widely shared personalprobability distributions concerning future events. In particular,the hypothesismaintains that standard-modelcoefficients suchas those estimatedfrom Gramlich'swage-increase equation 1' would changesignificantly for the better-in the directionof a muchmore rapid reductionof inflationfor any given slack-if a demand-managementpol- icy, whichwith brief interruptions was accommodativeduring a largepart of his sampleperiod, changedto a crediblepolicy of consistentdemand disinflation.This change in policies would have a major effect on price expectations,and the estimatedcoefficients would turn out to have over- stated the effect of the laggedprice and wage increaseson the currentin- creases.Allowance needs to be madefor a transitionperiod during which lags in establishingcredibility, as well as past contractsand their tempo- rary influenceon new contracts,would continueto slow the process of price deceleration.But thereafterprice decelerationwould speed up sub- stantially,the public'sobjectives being set in real terms. For analogousreasons the hypothesismaintains that coefficientssuch as those of Gramlichunderstate the currentincreases in relation to the precedingwage and price increasesfor alternativelevels of the slack if the authoritiesshift from a firm and credible anti-inflationarypolicy to one that accommodatesinflation with minor and sporadicinterruptions. Consideringthat during Gramlich'ssample period (1954-77) a pro- nouncedshift from credibilityto laxity did in fact occur in this sense, the hypothesissuggests that duringthe sampleperiod the deviationsobserved from the values predictedby the model should show a tendencyto turn fromnegative to positive.2In otherwords, along with the loss of credibility of the anti-inflationarypolicy posture,the given values of Gramlich'sex- planatoryvariables should show signsof becomingassociated with steeper cost trends. The rational expectations hypothesis-Views based on the credibility hypothesis overlap with views usually associated with the hypothesis of rationalexpectations. I amreferring to a set of viewsas beingcommonly associatedwith "rationalexpectations" because there obviouslyexists no joint declarationof authorsin such mattersand becausein some ways the views i.nquestion are still evolving.But to the extent that it is possibleto speakof jointlyheld views of authors,I do not believe that the proposi- 2. Gramlich did not correct for serial correlation, which, I am told, was not found to be significant. 170 Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1979 tions I regardas characteristicof analysisbased on the rationalexpecta- tions hypothesiswould misrepresent the views of the authorsconcerned.3 (It wouldbe far-fetchedto base an appraisalof the debateon a qualifica- tion to be describedin note 4 below.) The rationalexpectations hypothesis overlaps with that of the credi- bilityeffect, because both stressthat the publicis formingits expectations on the basis of all availableinformation, including information on the probablefuture actions of policymakers.However, there are two reasons whythe overlapis merelypartial. One reasonis that the views commonlyassociated with the rationalex- pectationshypothesis suggest that experiencehas in fact enabledthe pub- lic to detect a system by which the authoritiesexert an influence on nominaldemand, while the credibilityhypothesis suggests that the public can detect such a system only if the authoritiesplay effectivelyinto the hands of the marketparticipants by behavingconsistently in an under- standablefashion. Consider,for example, a mode of behavior of the policymakersde- scribedby the accommodationof a so-calledunderlying inflation rate in order allegedlyto stabilizethat rate, and considera policy that continues to accommodateinflation when the underlyingrate steepens(as it will in such circumstances),yet becomes temporarilyrestrictive at some rate of acceleration-not the samerate on successiveoccasions. The lattermode of behaviorillustrates game-strategy situations leading to highly volatile marketexpectations and to largerisk allowances.This descriptionfits the post-1965 policy postureof our authoritiesregrettably well. It cannotbe expectedto result in a state of the economyusefully described as one in which a system governingpolicy behaviorhas been figuredout by the public. Dependenceof the suggestedconclusions on the conditioningof market 3. For relatively recent contributionssee, for example, Thomas J. Sargent, "Ra- tional Expectations, the Real Rate of Interest, and the Natural Rate of Unemploy- ment," BPEA, 2:1973, pp. 429-80, and "'Rational Expectations': A Correction," BPEA, 3:1973, pp. 799-800; Thomas J. Sargent and Neil Wallace, "Rational Expectations and the Theory of Economic Policy," and Robert J. Barro and Stanley Fischer, "Recent Developments in Monetwy Theory," Journal of Monetary Eco- nomics, vol. 2 (April 1976), pp. 169-83 and 133-67, respectively; Robert J. Barro, "UnanticipatedMoney, Output and the Price Level in the United States,"Journal of Political Economzy,vol. 86 (August 1978), pp.
Recommended publications
  • A Study of Paul A. Samuelson's Economics
    Copyright is owned by the Author of the thesis. Permission is given for a copy to be downloaded by an individual for the purpose of research and private study only. The thesis may not be reproduced elsewhere without the permission of the Author. A Study of Paul A. Samuelson's Econol11ics: Making Economics Accessible to Students A thesis presented in partial fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy in Economics at Massey University Palmerston North, New Zealand. Leanne Marie Smith July 2000 Abstract Paul A. Samuelson is the founder of the modem introductory economics textbook. His textbook Economics has become a classic, and the yardstick of introductory economics textbooks. What is said to distinguish economics from the other social sciences is the development of a textbook tradition. The textbook presents the fundamental paradigms of the discipline, these gradually evolve over time as puzzles emerge, and solutions are found or suggested. The textbook is central to the dissemination of the principles of a discipline. Economics has, and does contribute to the education of students, and advances economic literacy and understanding in society. It provided a common economic language for students. Systematic analysis and research into introductory textbooks is relatively recent. The contribution that textbooks play in portraying a discipline and its evolution has been undervalued and under-researched. Specifically, applying bibliographical and textual analysis to textbook writing in economics, examining a single introductory economics textbook and its successive editions through time is new. When it is considered that an economics textbook is more than a disseminator of information, but a physical object with specific content, presented in a particular way, it changes the way a researcher looks at that textbook.
    [Show full text]
  • Does It Hold Water?
    Does it Hold Water? Summary Investigate logical fallacies to see the flaws in arguments and learn to read between the lines and discern obscure and misleading statements from the truth. Workplace Readiness Skills Primary: Information Literacy Secondary: Critical Thinking and Problem Solving Secondary: Reading and Writing Secondary: Integrity Workplace Readiness Definition: Information Literacy • defining information literacy • locating and evaluating credible and relevant sources of information • using information effectively to accomplish work-related tasks. Vocabulary • Critical Thinking • Trustworthy • Aristotle, Plato, • Inductive Reasoning • Logic Socrates • Deductive Reasoning • Logical fallacy • Systems thinking • Cause-Effect • Process • Argument • Analysis • Propaganda • Rhetorical • Credible/non- • Infer vs. Imply credible Context Questions • How can information literacy set you apart from your peers or coworkers? • How can you demonstrate your ability with information literacy skills in a job interview? • How does information literacy and critical thinking interrelate? How do they differ? • How is good citizenship tied in with being a critical thinker? • How have you used information literacy skills in the past? • What are some common ways that information literacy skills are used in the workplace? • What news and information sources do you trust? What makes them trustworthy? • What is the difference between news shows and hard news? • Why is it important to be able to discern fact from opinion? • Why is it important to determine a credible from a non-credible source? • What are the characteristics of a credible/non-credible source? • What is a primary, secondary, and tertiary source? • What is a website domain, and what can it tell you about a site's potential credibility? Objective: To teach you how to determine whether media messages are factual and provable or whether those messages are misleading or somehow flawed.
    [Show full text]
  • Conservatism and Pragmatism in Law, Politics and Ethics
    TOWARDS PRAGMATIC CONSERVATISM: A REVIEW OF SETH VANNATTA’S CONSERVATISM AND PRAGMATISM IN LAW, POLITICS, AND ETHICS Allen Mendenhall* At some point all writers come across a book they wish they had written. Several such books line my bookcases; the latest of which is Seth Vannatta’s Conservativism and Pragmatism in Law, Politics, and Ethics.1 The two words conservatism and pragmatism circulate widely and with apparent ease, as if their import were immediately clear and uncontroversial. But if you press strangers for concise definitions, you will likely find that the signification of these words differs from person to person.2 Maybe it’s not just that people are unwilling to update their understanding of conservatism and pragmatism—maybe it’s that they cling passionately to their understanding (or misunderstanding), fearing that their operative paradigms and working notions of 20th century history and philosophy will collapse if conservatism and pragmatism differ from some developed expectation or ingrained supposition. I began to immerse myself in pragmatism in graduate school when I discovered that its central tenets aligned rather cleanly with those of Edmund Burke, David Hume, F. A. Hayek, Michael Oakeshott, and Russell Kirk, men widely considered to be on the right end of the political spectrum even if their ideas diverge in key areas.3 In fact, I came to believe that pragmatism reconciled these thinkers, that whatever their marked intellectual differences, these men believed certain things that could be synthesized and organized in terms of pragmatism.4 I reached this conclusion from the same premise adopted by Vannatta: “Conservatism and pragmatism[] .
    [Show full text]
  • Rolling the DICE: William Nordhaus's Dubious Case for a Carbon
    SUBSCRIBE NOW AND RECEIVE CRISIS AND LEVIATHAN* FREE! “The Independent Review does not accept “The Independent Review is pronouncements of government officials nor the excellent.” conventional wisdom at face value.” —GARY BECKER, Noble Laureate —JOHN R. MACARTHUR, Publisher, Harper’s in Economic Sciences Subscribe to The Independent Review and receive a free book of your choice* such as the 25th Anniversary Edition of Crisis and Leviathan: Critical Episodes in the Growth of American Government, by Founding Editor Robert Higgs. This quarterly journal, guided by co-editors Christopher J. Coyne, and Michael C. Munger, and Robert M. Whaples offers leading-edge insights on today’s most critical issues in economics, healthcare, education, law, history, political science, philosophy, and sociology. Thought-provoking and educational, The Independent Review is blazing the way toward informed debate! Student? Educator? Journalist? Business or civic leader? Engaged citizen? This journal is for YOU! *Order today for more FREE book options Perfect for students or anyone on the go! The Independent Review is available on mobile devices or tablets: iOS devices, Amazon Kindle Fire, or Android through Magzter. INDEPENDENT INSTITUTE, 100 SWAN WAY, OAKLAND, CA 94621 • 800-927-8733 • [email protected] PROMO CODE IRA1703 Rolling the DICE William Nordhaus’s Dubious Case for a Carbon Tax F ROBERT P. M URPHY he 2007 Nobel Peace Prize awarded to Al Gore and the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) underscores the public’s growing aware- T ness of and concern about anthropogenic (man-made) global warming. Many climatologists and other relevant scientists claim that emissions of greenhouse gases (GHGs) from human activity will lead to increases in the earth’s temperature, which in turn will spell potentially catastrophic hardship for future generations.
    [Show full text]
  • How the Rational Expectations Revolution Has Enriched
    How the Rational Expectations Revolution Has Changed Macroeconomic Policy Research by John B. Taylor STANFORD UNIVERSITY Revised Draft: February 29, 2000 Written versions of lecture presented at the 12th World Congress of the International Economic Association, Buenos Aires, Argentina, August 24, 1999. I am grateful to Jacques Dreze for helpful comments on an earlier draft. The rational expectations hypothesis is by far the most common expectations assumption used in macroeconomic research today. This hypothesis, which simply states that people's expectations are the same as the forecasts of the model being used to describe those people, was first put forth and used in models of competitive product markets by John Muth in the 1960s. But it was not until the early 1970s that Robert Lucas (1972, 1976) incorporated the rational expectations assumption into macroeconomics and showed how to make it operational mathematically. The “rational expectations revolution” is now as old as the Keynesian revolution was when Robert Lucas first brought rational expectations to macroeconomics. This rational expectations revolution has led to many different schools of macroeconomic research. The new classical economics school, the real business cycle school, the new Keynesian economics school, the new political macroeconomics school, and more recently the new neoclassical synthesis (Goodfriend and King (1997)) can all be traced to the introduction of rational expectations into macroeconomics in the early 1970s (see the discussion by Snowden and Vane (1999), pp. 30-50). In this lecture, which is part of the theme on "The Current State of Macroeconomics" at the 12th World Congress of the International Economic Association, I address a question that I am frequently asked by students and by "non-macroeconomist" colleagues, and that I suspect may be on many people's minds.
    [Show full text]
  • Argument, Structure, and Credibility in Public Health Writing Donald Halstead Instructor and Director of Writing Programs Harvard TH Chan School of Public Heath
    Argument, Structure, and Credibility in Public Health Writing Donald Halstead Instructor and Director of Writing Programs Harvard TH Chan School of Public Heath Some of the most important questions we face in public health include what policies we should follow, which programs and research should we fund, how and where we should intervene, and what our priorities should be in the face of overwhelming needs and scarce resources. These questions, like many others, are best decided on the basis of arguments, a word that has its roots in the Latin arguere, to make clear. Yet arguments themselves vary greatly in terms of their strength, accuracy, and validity. Furthermore, public health experts often disagree on matters of research, policy and practice, citing conflicting evidence and arriving at conflicting conclusions. As a result, critical readers, such as researchers, policymakers, journal editors and reviewers, approach arguments with considerable skepticism. After all, they are not going to change their programs, priorities, practices, research agendas or budgets without very solid evidence that it is necessary, feasible, and beneficial. This raises an important challenge for public health writers: How can you best make your case, in the face of so much conflicting evidence? To illustrate, let’s assume that you’ve been researching mother-to-child transmission (MTCT) of HIV in a sub-Saharan African country and have concluded that (claim) the country’s maternal programs for HIV counseling and infant nutrition should be integrated because (reasons) this would be more efficient in decreasing MTCT, improving child nutrition, and using scant resources efficiently. The evidence to back up your claim might consist of original research you have conducted that included program assessments and interviews with health workers in the field, your assessment of the other relevant research, the experiences of programs in other countries, and new WHO guidelines.
    [Show full text]
  • From Designers to Doctrinaires: Staff Research and Fiscal Policy Change at the Imf
    FROM DESIGNERS TO DOCTRINAIRES: STAFF RESEARCH AND FISCAL POLICY CHANGE AT THE IMF Cornel Ban ABSTRACT Soon after the Lehman crisis, the International Monetary Fund (IMF) surprised its critics with a reconsideration of its research and advice on fiscal policy. The paper traces the influence that the Fund’s senior man- agement and research elite has had on the recalibration of the IMF’s doctrine on fiscal policy. The findings suggest that overall there has been some selective incorporation of unorthodox ideas in the Fund’s fis- cal doctrine, while the strong thesis that austerity has expansionary effects has been rejected. Indeed, the Fund’s new orthodoxy is con- cerned with the recessionary effects of fiscal consolidation and, more recently, endorses calls for a more progressive adjustment of the costs of fiscal sustainability. These changes notwithstanding, the IMF’s adaptive incremental transformation on fiscal policy issues falls short Elites on Trial Research in the Sociology of Organizations, Volume 43, 337 369 À Copyright r 2015 by Emerald Group Publishing Limited All rights of reproduction in any form reserved ISSN: 0733-558X/doi:10.1108/S0733-558X20150000043024 337 338 CORNEL BAN of a paradigm shift and is best conceived of as an important recalibra- tion of the precrisis status quo. Keywords: IMF; staff research; Keynesian; New Consensus Macroeconomics; austerity FROM GREAT EXPECTATIONS TO MODEST RECALIBRATIONS In 2008, many expected that the widespread outrage and economic hard- ship caused by the financial crisis would lead to the replacement of the neo- liberal policy paradigm. The rediscovery of Keynesian macroeconomics in 2008 2009 by the lea- ders of the G20 seemed to indicate that change was imminent.À Indeed, mainstream macroeconomic and finance economics seemed on their way to a historical trial.
    [Show full text]
  • Das Maynard Keynes Problem: Rethinking Rationality
    Das Maynard Keynes Problem: Rethinking Rationality Ailian Gan Abstract As with Adam Smith in Das Adam Smith Problem, critics have observed that, across the large body of work produced in John Maynard Keynes’s lifetime, Keynes displays a shifting or even inconsistent view of rationality. In the Treatise on Probability, Keynes argues that economic actors use all available information to make rational decisions. In The General Theory, however, Keynes argues that people are irrational and are highly susceptible to psychological forces. This paper seeks to reconcile both views by arguing that, if one allows economic actors to display a range of rationality, Keynes’s work is wholly consistent. I. Introduction For any great intellectual who produces an enormous body of work, tracing his philosophical foundations and precise intentions is a valuable but daunting task. For Adam Smith, critics were intrigued by the transformations and inconsistencies in arguments of his two most prominent works. In The Theory of Moral Sentiments, Smith was an advocate of sympathy for our fellow human being. In The Wealth of Nations, however, he became a strong advocate of self-interest, arguing that it was the primary motive behind economic behavior and the driving force of the economy. This selfless/selfish mismatch has led many economists following in Smith’s footsteps to question which stance he truly intended and whether the two can be reconciled. Either reading of his intentions can lead to vastly different interpretations of his theories and his legacy. Such was the nature of das Adam Smith problem. For John Maynard Keynes, interpreters of his work face a similar problem.
    [Show full text]
  • The Retreat of the State from Entrepreneurial Activities: an Extended Survey
    A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Etling, Andreas; Mause, Karsten; Obinger, Herbert; Schmitt, Carina; Schreeb, Katharina Working Paper The retreat of the state from entrepreneurial activities: an extended survey TranState Working Papers, No. 107 Provided in Cooperation with: University of Bremen, Collaborative Research Center 597: Transformations of the State Suggested Citation: Etling, Andreas; Mause, Karsten; Obinger, Herbert; Schmitt, Carina; Schreeb, Katharina (2009) : The retreat of the state from entrepreneurial activities: an extended survey, TranState Working Papers, No. 107, Universität Bremen, Collaborative Research Center 597 - Transformations of the State, Bremen This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/29688 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen
    [Show full text]
  • Biases in Research: Risk Factors for Non-Replicability in Psychotherapy and Pharmacotherapy Research
    Psychological Medicine, Page 1 of 12. © Cambridge University Press 2016 REVIEW ARTICLE doi:10.1017/S003329171600324X Biases in research: risk factors for non-replicability in psychotherapy and pharmacotherapy research F. Leichsenring1*†, A. Abbass2, M. J. Hilsenroth3, F. Leweke1, P. Luyten4,5, J. R. Keefe6, N. Midgley7,8, S. Rabung9,10, S. Salzer11,12 and C. Steinert1 1 Department of Psychosomatics and Psychotherapy, Justus-Liebig-University Giessen, Giessen, Germany; 2 Department of Psychiatry, Dalhousie University, Centre for Emotions and Health, Halifax, NS, Canada; 3 The Derner Institute of Advanced Psychological Studies, Adelphi University, NY, USA; 4 Faculty of Psychology and Educational Sciences, University of Leuven, Klinische Psychologie (OE), Leuven, Belgium; 5 Research Department of Clinical, Educational and Health Psychology, University College London, London, UK; 6 Department of Psychology, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, PA, USA; 7 The Anna Freud Centre, London, UK; 8 Research Department of Clinical, Educational and Health Psychology, UCL, London, UK; 9 Department of Psychology, Alpen-Adria-Universität Klagenfurt, Universitätsstr, Klagenfurt, Austria; 10 Department of Medical Psychology, University Medical Center Hamburg-Eppendorf, Hamburg, Germany; 11 Clinic of Psychosomatic Medicine and Psychotherapy, Georg-August-Universität Goettingen, Göttingen, Germany; 12 International Psychoanalytic University (IPU), Berlin, Germany Replicability of findings is an essential prerequisite of research. For both basic and clinical research, however, low rep- licability of findings has recently been reported. Replicability may be affected by research biases not sufficiently con- trolled for by the existing research standards. Several biases such as researcher allegiance or selective reporting are well-known for affecting results. For psychotherapy and pharmacotherapy research, specific additional biases may affect outcome (e.g.
    [Show full text]
  • The Alleged Necessity of Microfoundations*
    CORE Metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk Provided by Erasmus University Digital Repository MAARTEN C. W. JANSSEN Erasmus University Rotterdam Rotterdam, The Netherlands The Alleged Necessity of Microfoundations* It is often said that models in the microfoundations literature derive macroeconomic results from the theory of individual behavior only. This paper examines two of the assumptions that are usually made in these models: market clearing and rational expectations. In the context of simple models it is shown that only in some special cases these assumptions can be derived from the fundamental notion that individ- uals behave rationally. Thus, the usual rationale for the microfoundations literature is challenged. The paper concludes with a more modest rationale for the "necessity" of microfoundations. 1. Introduction Macroeconomics is in need of a microeconomic foundation. Nowadays, this is a widely accepted doctrine in the economics profession. Most economists take the necessity for a microeconomic foundation for granted. If arguments in favor of the necessity for microfoundations are cited, they often are of the following reduc- tionist form. Society consists of individuals who are the only sub- jects that make economic decisions. So, in order to explain what is going on in the economy as a whole--for example, unemployment, inflation, business cycles--we have to understand the individual de- cisions from which a particular situation originates. I think that this "'reductionist credo" itself is largely correct. However, if it is used as an argument in favor of the necessity for microeconomic foun- dations it is presupposed either that microeconomics is only con- cerned with individual behavior or that all microeconomic propo- sitions can be derived from statements concerning individual decision *This paper was written while I was visiting Duke University.
    [Show full text]
  • Paul Samuelson and Global Public Goods
    Paul Samuelson and Global Public Goods William D. Nordhaus Yale University1 May 5, 2005 A commemorative essay for Paul Samuelson ________________________________________________________ It is both easy and hard to write an essay commemorating Paul Samuelson’s contributions to economics. Easy, because he has created so much of modern economics that you could write on virtually anything – stabilization policy, economic growth, international trade, welfare economics, or just about any topic that caught your fancy. Hard, because, like Buridan’s ass, you could easily procrastinate forever in deciding which of the many treasures of his ideas to draw from. In the end, I chose to draw from Paul’s writings on public goods. In two and one-half pages, he reshaped the way economists and political philosophers think about the distinction between private goods and public goods.2 Once those concepts are learned, we can never again forget why the allocational questions for bread are fundamentally different from those of lighthouses. I will focus on an important example of this topic, and one that poses particularly thorny practical 1 The author is Sterling Professor of Economics at Yale University. 2 Paul Samuelson, “The Pure Theory of Public Expenditure,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 36, No. 4, Nov. 1954, pp. 387-389. - 1 - issues, which is the case of global public goods. A brief intellectual history of the concepts is appended. What great blessings or scourges have befallen humanity? Consider issues as disparate as greenhouse warming and ozone depletion, the Internet and William Shakespeare, terrorism and money laundering, the discovery of antibiotics and nuclear proliferation.
    [Show full text]