An Evaluation of the Dichotomy Between Structural Versus Deficient-Demand Unemployment
Total Page:16
File Type:pdf, Size:1020Kb
Load more
Recommended publications
-
(1899-1992) Born in Austria in 1899, Nobel Prize-Winning Economist Friedrich Von Hayek Was an Advocate of Free-Market Capitalism
Friedrich von Hayek 1 (1899-1992) Born in Austria in 1899, Nobel Prize-winning economist Friedrich von Hayek was an advocate of free-market capitalism. He is known for his criticism of the prevailing economic theories of the 20th century, Keynesian economic models and socialism. Excerpt from The Commanding Heights by Daniel Yergin and Joseph Stanislaw, 1998 ed., pp. 141-144. In retrospect, it was the awarding of the 1974 Nobel Prize in economics that first captured, almost by chance, the great intellectual change. The Swedish academy wanted to honor Gunnar Myrdal, distinguished Keynesian, a father of development economics, and a great figure of Swedish socialism. But the grantors, worried about the appearance of choosing so local a favorite, decided that they ought to balance the ticket with a more conservative figure, and they awarded the prize to Myrdal jointly with Friedrich von Hayek. A good part of the economics profession was scandalized by the choice of Hayek; many economists in the United States, if polled, would have hardly even considered him an economist. He was regarded as right-wing, certainly not mainstream, even something of a crank as well as a fossil from an archaic era.... Yet the award documented the beginning of a great shift in the intellectual center of gravity of the economies profession toward a restoration of confidence in markets, indeed a renewed belief in the superiority of markets over other ways of organizing economic activity. Within a decade and a half, the shift would be largely complete. And the eventual victory of this viewpoint was really a tale of two cities—Vienna and Chicago. -
Is Unemployment Structural Or Cyclical? Main Features of Job Matching in the EU After the Crisis
IZA Policy Paper No. 91 Is Unemployment Structural or Cyclical? Main Features of Job Matching in the EU after the Crisis Alfonso Arpaia Aron Kiss Alessandro Turrini P O L I C Y P A P E R S I E S P A P Y I C O L P September 2014 Forschungsinstitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit Institute for the Study of Labor Is Unemployment Structural or Cyclical? Main Features of Job Matching in the EU after the Crisis Alfonso Arpaia European Commission, DG ECFIN and IZA Aron Kiss European Commission, DG ECFIN Alessandro Turrini European Commission, DG ECFIN and IZA Policy Paper No. 91 September 2014 IZA P.O. Box 7240 53072 Bonn Germany Phone: +49-228-3894-0 Fax: +49-228-3894-180 E-mail: [email protected] The IZA Policy Paper Series publishes work by IZA staff and network members with immediate relevance for policymakers. Any opinions and views on policy expressed are those of the author(s) and not necessarily those of IZA. The papers often represent preliminary work and are circulated to encourage discussion. Citation of such a paper should account for its provisional character. A revised version may be available directly from the corresponding author. IZA Policy Paper No. 91 September 2014 ABSTRACT Is Unemployment Structural or Cyclical? * Main Features of Job Matching in the EU after the Crisis The paper sheds light on developments in labour market matching in the EU after the crisis. First, it analyses the main features of the Beveridge curve and frictional unemployment in EU countries, with a view to isolate temporary changes in the vacancy-unemployment relationship from structural shifts affecting the efficiency of labour market matching. -
Daniel K Tarullo: Unemployment, the Labor Market, and the Economy
Daniel K Tarullo: Unemployment, the labor market, and the economy Speech by Mr Daniel K Tarullo, Member of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, at the World Leaders Forum, Columbia University, New York, 20 October 2011. * * * I appreciate the opportunity to be at Columbia this evening to discuss the American economy and, in particular, the employment situation.1 Mindful of the trend of public discourse toward hyperbole, I hesitated in deciding whether to characterize that situation as a crisis. But it is hard to justify characterizing in any less urgent fashion the circumstances of the nearly 30 million Americans who are officially unemployed, out of the labor force but wanting jobs, or involuntarily working only part time. This situation reflects acute problems in labor markets, created by the financial crisis and the recession that followed. But we also confront chronic labor market problems. In my remarks this evening, I will outline both sets of problems. In my observations on policy responses, however, I will concentrate on the acute problems – in part to join the debate on their origins, in part because they call for the most immediate response, and in part because they are most relevant to my monetary policy responsibilities as a member of the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) of the Federal Reserve. That said, I hope you will not think the chronic problems any less important for the briefer treatment they receive tonight. Most of what I have to say can be summarized in three points. First, the acute problems are largely, though not completely, the result of a shortfall of aggregate demand following the financial crisis and recession. -
Structural Unemployment in Selected Countries
A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Alatalo, Johanna et al. Research Report Structural unemployment in selected countries Aktuelle Berichte, No. 4/2015 Provided in Cooperation with: Institute for Employment Research (IAB) Suggested Citation: Alatalo, Johanna et al. (2015) : Structural unemployment in selected countries, Aktuelle Berichte, No. 4/2015, Institut für Arbeitsmarkt- und Berufsforschung (IAB), Nürnberg This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/161693 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. www.econstor.eu Current reports Structural Unemployment in Selected Countries 4/2015 What to expect / In aller Kürze This report introduces basics on structural unemployment in some member countries of the International Labour Market Forecasting Network. -
Nicholas Kaldor
PROFILES OF WORLD ECONOMISTS 26 NICHOLAS KALDOR NICHOLAS KALDOR – ONE OF THE FIRST CRITICS OF MONETARISM doc. Ing. Ján Iša, DrSc. Known in economic circles as one of the thought in several fields, but it was his work founders of Post-Keynesianism, Nicholas on the theory of distribution and economic Kaldor (1908–1986) ranks among the worl- growth that stirred the greatest reaction. d's foremost economists of the second half Less well-known, however, is Kaldor's con- of the 20th century. Kaldor contributed to tribution to monetary theory, which has long the development of modern economic been standing quietly in the background. Nicholas Kaldor was born in Budapest on 12 May 1908. rous Third World countries, as well as an advisor to central His father was a lawyer and his mother came from wealthy banks and to the United Nations Economic Commission for business family. Although his father had wanted him to Latin America. Most significant, however, was his role as an study law, Kaldor opted for economics. He began his studi- advisor to Labour finance ministers from 1964 to 1968 and es at the University of Berlin in 1925 and then after two 1974 to 1976. After completing his two-year mission in years moved to the London School of Economics (LSE), Geneva in 1949, Kaldor began to work at Cambridge Uni- from which he graduated in 1930. He remained at the LSE versity and became, as John Maynard Keynes had been, a as lecturer until 1947, during which time his colleagues inc- fellow of King's College, Cambridge. -
Myrdal Revisited May 2011
1 GUNNAR MYRDAL REVISITED: CUMULATIVE CAUSATION, ACCUMULATION AND LEGITIMISATION The aim of this paper is to provide a reconstruction of Myrdal’s analysis of the factors determining the path of accumulation, in view of the pivotal role played by political institutions in promoting it. It will be shown that Myrdal’s theory of cumulative causation, combined with his idea that consensus on the existing social order is a “created harmony”, is a powerful analytical tool in understanding a key contradiction of capitalist reproduction (particularly in a neo-liberal regime): namely the trade-off between accumulation and legitimisation. Keywords: Gunnar Myrdal, accumulation, welfare state, political institutions JEL: B25, H11, E25 by Guglielmo Forges Davanzati* 1 - Introduction Gunnar Myrdal’s contribution can be regarded as diametrically opposed to the Walrasian picture of the functioning of market economies on two main grounds. First, the idea that the economic process does not develop in equilibrium conditions, and that – by contrast – disequilibrium is the normal outcome of the dynamics of deregulated market economies. Second, the conviction that the power factor – in market relations as well in socio-political arena - plays a crucial role in economic theory (cf. Dostaler, Ethier, Lepage, eds., 1992; Applequist and Andersson, eds., 2004). In the Walrasian world, the absence of different degrees of bargaining power among agents is justified on the grounds that markets are in equilibrium, so that – as Samuelson (1957, p.894) maintained - “in -
Has the Great Recession Raised U S Structural Unemployment? U.S
Has the Great Recession Raised U. S. Structural Unemployment? MllEtãMarcello Estevão International Monetary Fund November, 2011 Views expressed are those of the authors alone and should not be reportedihffiiliifhIilMFdd as representing the official position of the International Monetary Fund. A unique recession … Financial crisis coupled with a housing collapse. Unemployment rate reached a 27 -year high in late 2009 Second highest rate on record. A record 5 .5 million jobs lost in 2009 . Historically high unemployment rates for youth and men. 1 in 6 people in the labor force with no high school diploma unemployed. 1 in 10 pppeople in the labor force with hi ghh--schoolschool diploma unemployed. Historically high unemployment duration All labor underutilization measures reached historic highs. 1 … with regional and sectoral flavors Large regional disparities in Unemployment rates: North Dakota , 3 .9 percent in 2010 . Nevada, 14.9 percent in 2010. Housing market performance Sectoral shocks: Ohio and Michigan (manufacturing) New York and Delaware (financial services) Hawaii (tourism) 2 Signs that structural unemployment has gone up Job Vacancies and Unemployment 4 4 2000-07 2008-10 2011 e; percent) cc 3 3 Beveridge Curve estimated over 2002-11 nings/labor for ee 2 2 acancy rate (op acancy rate vv Job Job Beveridge Curve estimated over 2002-07 1 1 357911 Unemployment rate (percent) 3 The paper Investigate the impact of housing/housing/sectoralsectoralshocks on “structural” or “noncyclical” unemployment Construct Skills Mismatch Index for 50 states & DC. Invest igate t he ro le o f s kills mi smatch es an d hous ing market conditions in explaining statestate--levellevel unemployment rates after controlling for cyclical and other effects. -
Myrdal's Circular Cumulative Causation Theory
Myrdal’s Circular Cumulative Causation Theory Definition: Circular cumulative causation is a theory developed by Swedish economist Gunnar Myrdal in the year 1956. It is a multi-causal approach where the core variables and their linkages are delineated. The idea behind it is that a change in one form of an institution will lead to successive changes in other institutions. These changes are circular in that they continue in a cycle, many times in a negative way, in which there is no end, and cumulative in that they persist in each round. The change does not occur all at once as that would lead to chaos, rather the changes occur gradually. To put Myrdal’s view in a better perspective let us see what he has to say on the subject. According to Myrdal,- “if things were left to market forces unhampered by any policy interferences, industrial production, commerce, banking, insurance, shipping and indeed almost all those economic activities which in developing economy tend to give a bigger than average return and, in addition, science, art, literature, educational higher culture generally – would cluster in certain localities and regions, leaving the rest of the country more or less in a backwater”. By whatever factors-natural, manmade, or historical space growth gets started in a particular regions and meets with initial success, all sorts of economic and non-economic activities start concentrating there. This happens because of ever increasing internal and external economies – interpreted in the widest sense of the word to include, for instance, a working of population trained in a various crafts, easy communications, the feeling of growth and elbow room and the spirit of new enterprise”. -
Minimum Level of Unemployment and Public Policy
Upjohn Press Upjohn Research home page 1-1-1980 Minimum Level of Unemployment and Public Policy Frank Cook Pierson Swarthmore College Follow this and additional works at: https://research.upjohn.org/up_press Part of the Labor Economics Commons, and the Public Policy Commons Citation Pierson, Frank C. 1980. Minimum Level of Unemployment and Public Policy. Kalamazoo, MI: W.E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research. https://doi.org/10.17848/9780880995832 This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-Noncommercial-Share Alike 4.0 License. This title is brought to you by the Upjohn Institute. For more information, please contact [email protected]. Theo o _ _ LevdLof Unemployment and Riblic Iblicy Frank C» Herson The©O O _ TLeveLof Unemployment and ftibliclbliey Frank C. Pierson Swarthmore College THE W.E. UPJOHN INSTITUTE FOR EMPLOYMENT RESEARCH Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication Data Pierson, Frank Cook, 1911- The minimum level of unemployment and public policy. 1. Unemployment United States. 2. United States Full employment policies. I. Title. HD5724.P475 339.5©0973 80-26536 ISBN 0-911558-76-4 ISBN 0-911558-75-6 (pbk.) Copyright 1980 by the W. E. UPJOHN INSTITUTE FOR EMPLOYMENT RESEARCH 300 South Westnedge Ave. Kalamazoo, Michigan 49007 THE INSTITUTE, a nonprofit research organization, was established on July 1, 1945. It is an activity of the W. E. Upjohn Unemployment Trustee Corporation, which was formed in 1932 to administer a fund set aside by the late Dr. W. E. Upjohn for the purpose of carrying on "research into the causes and effects of unemployment and measures for the alleviation of unemployment." The Board of Trustees of the W. -
Nine Lives of Neoliberalism
A Service of Leibniz-Informationszentrum econstor Wirtschaft Leibniz Information Centre Make Your Publications Visible. zbw for Economics Plehwe, Dieter (Ed.); Slobodian, Quinn (Ed.); Mirowski, Philip (Ed.) Book — Published Version Nine Lives of Neoliberalism Provided in Cooperation with: WZB Berlin Social Science Center Suggested Citation: Plehwe, Dieter (Ed.); Slobodian, Quinn (Ed.); Mirowski, Philip (Ed.) (2020) : Nine Lives of Neoliberalism, ISBN 978-1-78873-255-0, Verso, London, New York, NY, https://www.versobooks.com/books/3075-nine-lives-of-neoliberalism This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/215796 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative -
ΒΙΒΛΙΟΓ ΡΑΦΙΑ Bibliography
Τεύχος 53, Οκτώβριος-Δεκέμβριος 2019 | Issue 53, October-December 2019 ΒΙΒΛΙΟΓ ΡΑΦΙΑ Bibliography Βραβείο Νόμπελ στην Οικονομική Επιστήμη Nobel Prize in Economics Τα τεύχη δημοσιεύονται στον ιστοχώρο της All issues are published online at the Bank’s website Τράπεζας: address: https://www.bankofgreece.gr/trapeza/kepoe https://www.bankofgreece.gr/en/the- t/h-vivliothhkh-ths-tte/e-ekdoseis-kai- bank/culture/library/e-publications-and- anakoinwseis announcements Τράπεζα της Ελλάδος. Κέντρο Πολιτισμού, Bank of Greece. Centre for Culture, Research and Έρευνας και Τεκμηρίωσης, Τμήμα Documentation, Library Section Βιβλιοθήκης Ελ. Βενιζέλου 21, 102 50 Αθήνα, 21 El. Venizelos Ave., 102 50 Athens, [email protected] Τηλ. 210-3202446, [email protected], Tel. +30-210-3202446, 3202396, 3203129 3202396, 3203129 Βιβλιογραφία, τεύχος 53, Οκτ.-Δεκ. 2019, Bibliography, issue 53, Oct.-Dec. 2019, Nobel Prize Βραβείο Νόμπελ στην Οικονομική Επιστήμη in Economics Συντελεστές: Α. Ναδάλη, Ε. Σεμερτζάκη, Γ. Contributors: A. Nadali, E. Semertzaki, G. Tsouri Τσούρη Βιβλιογραφία, αρ.53 (Οκτ.-Δεκ. 2019), Βραβείο Nobel στην Οικονομική Επιστήμη 1 Bibliography, no. 53, (Oct.-Dec. 2019), Nobel Prize in Economics Πίνακας περιεχομένων Εισαγωγή / Introduction 6 2019: Abhijit Banerjee, Esther Duflo and Michael Kremer 7 Μονογραφίες / Monographs ................................................................................................... 7 Δοκίμια Εργασίας / Working papers ...................................................................................... -
Human Rights and the End of the Age of Keynes
HUMAN RIGHTS AND THE END OF THE AGE OF KEYNES © Howard Richards, 2008 http://howardrichards.org/peace/content/view/87/120/ The purpose of this paper is to argue that learning how to establish social democracy should be a goal of peace research regarded as including human rights research. This paper is not mainly a report on research that has already been done. It is mainly about why research on social democracy should be done by peace and human rights researchers. I shall be claiming that to a great extent because of the influence of Keynesian and related forms of economics, which are associated with a middle path between state planned economies and market economies, the economic context for human rights was more favorable in the three decades immediately after World War II than it is now. Today anti- social democratic trends; also known as neoliberalism, conservatism, and neo- conservatism; have become globally dominant. I shall be claiming that even though the proponents of these anti social-democratic trends are often also proponents of human rights, the current eclipse of Keynes poses obstacles for making human rights real. If we consider the excuses most commonly given for the frequent and massive violations of the solemn commitments of nations to honor human rights, we will find, I suggest in brief shorthand, two major types of excuse: the emergency excuses, and the impossibility excuses. "Emergency" is shorthand for excusing the violations of rights during periods of civil war and whenever civil order is threatened or said to be threatened by people who are said to be so dangerous that extreme measures are required to subdue them .